Ganson Jr. v. City of Marathon , 2016 Fla. App. LEXIS 13802 ( 2016 )


Menu:
  •        Third District Court of Appeal
    State of Florida
    Opinion filed September 14, 2016.
    ________________
    No. 3D12-777
    Lower Tribunal No. 05-313-M
    ________________
    Charles N. Ganson, Jr., as Personal Representative
    of the Estate of Molly Beyer,
    Appellant,
    vs.
    City of Marathon, Florida,
    and the State of Florida,
    Appellees.
    An Appeal from the Circuit Court for Monroe County, Ruth Becker, Judge.
    James S. Mattson; Andrew M. Tobin; Pacific Legal Foundation and Mark
    Miller and Christina M. Martin (Palm Beach Gardens), for appellant.
    GrayRobinson, P.A., and John R. Herin, Jr., and Jeffrey T. Kuntz (Fort
    Lauderdale), for the City of Marathon; Pamela Jo Bondi, Attorney General, and
    Jonathan A. Glogau (Tallahassee), Special Counsel Chief, for the State of Florida.
    Before SUAREZ, C.J., and WELLS and LAGOA, JJ.
    ON MOTION FOR REHEARING
    PER CURIAM.
    Denied.
    SUAREZ, C.J., and WELLS, J., concur.
    LAGOA, J., would grant rehearing.
    Before SUAREZ, C.J., and WELLS, SHEPHERD, ROTHENBERG, LAGOA,
    SALTER, EMAS, FERNANDEZ, and LOGUE, JJ.
    ON MOTION FOR REHEARING EN BANC
    PER CURIAM.
    Denied.
    SUAREZ, C.J., and WELLS, ROTHENBERG, SALTER, FERNANDEZ,
    and LOGUE, JJ., concur.
    SHEPHERD, J., dissenting.
    This is a significant regulatory takings case, the holding of which is that a
    local government can regulate private property to an extent that is functionally
    comparable to the classic physical taking—without paying just compensation—so
    long as it does so incrementally over a period of time. This cannot be, and indeed
    is not, the law. I respectfully dissent from the denial of the Beyers’ motion for
    rehearing en banc, and write to explain my disagreement with this Court’s
    willingness to dispense with applicable Takings Clause precedent to reach a result
    that is contrary to the constitutional principle that excessive economic injuries
    caused by government action be compensated.
    2
    BACKGROUND
    The following is a chronology of the salient facts:
     1970: Gordon and Molly Beyer purchased an undeveloped island in Monroe
    County (the “County”) for $70,000. At the time of purchase, the island was
    zoned “General Use,” which allowed one single-family home per acre. The
    property is just under nine acres.
     1986: The County adopted a Comprehensive Land Use Plan (the “1986
    Plan”) that downzoned the Beyers’ property to “Offshore Island,” allowing a
    new development density of one unit per ten acres. Since the Beyers’
    property is less than ten acres, this 1986 Plan essentially eliminated their
    development                                                     possibilities.
    The 1986 Plan included an administrative process known as a
    “Beneficial Use Determination.” This process provided landowners with a
    means of challenging the Plan’s unconstitutional effects on property, but the
    administrative remedy was problematic because it only allowed for the
    minimum necessary relief to raise the value of the property to forty percent
    of its pre-regulation value. See Monroe Cty. v. Gonzalez, 
    593 So. 2d 1143
    ,
    1144 (Fla. 3d DCA 1992) (affirming the circuit court’s finding that the 1986
    Plan’s beneficial use determination was not an adequate remedy because it
    did not provide for just compensation as required by the Fifth Amendment to
    3
    the United States Constitution and Article X, section 6 of the Florida
    Constitution).   Further, the beneficial use provisions required property
    owners to attempt to sell their property for forty percent of its pre-regulation
    value before being eligible to apply for relief.       
    Id. The Beyers
    never
    challenged the 1986 regulations under this flawed beneficial use
    determination process.
     1996: The County adopted a revised plan—the Year 2010 Comprehensive
    Plan (the “2010 Plan”). Under this Plan, the Beyers’ property is classified as
    a “bird rookery.” Under this classification, the only permitted use of the
    property is “temporary primitive camping by the owner, in which no land
    clearing or other alteration of the island occurs[.]” Monroe Cty. Year 2010
    Comprehensive Plan, Policy 102.7.2.
    Revised beneficial use procedures allow property owners to “apply for
    relief from the literal application of applicable land use regulations or of this
    plan when such application would have the effect of denying all
    economically reasonable use of [their] property[.]” 
    Id., Policy 101.18.5.
    “The relief granted shall be the minimum necessary to avoid a ‘taking’ of the
    property under state and federal law.” 
    Id.  1997:
    The Beyers submitted a beneficial use application along with the
    applicable fee to the County.
    4
     1999: The City of Marathon (the “City”) was incorporated, and the Beyers’
    property became part of the City. As a condition of incorporation, the City
    adopted the County’s 2010 Plan. Up to this point, the County had taken no
    action on the Beyers’ beneficial use application.
     2002: The Beyers submitted a new application and paid another application
    fee ($3,000) because the City refused to process the pending County
    application.
     2005: The Beyers’ cause was finally heard by a Beneficial Use Special
    Master, nearly nine years after the application was first submitted. The
    Special Master found that “[o]ther than the Applicant being allowed to enter
    onto the property to camp, there is absolutely no allowable use of the
    property” under the 2010 Plan. The Special Master also found that the
    permitted camping “would not constitute reasonable economic value to the
    Applicant in light of their investment in the property.” In spite of these
    findings, however, the Special Master recommended denying the Beyers’
    application because “[t]he Applicant has been adequately compensated by
    the issuance of 16 ROGO[1] points[.]” The City Council adopted these
    findings and recommendations.
    1 ROGO (Rate of Growth Ordinance) establishes rules and procedures for the
    process of receiving building permits in Monroe County. This process controls
    growth with a competitive point system that allocates the limited number of
    development permits available annually. See generally, Monroe Cty., Fl. Land.
    5
    The Beyers, having exhausted their administrative remedy, brought an
    inverse condemnation action against the City, alleging that they “have been
    deprived of all or substantially all, reasonable economic use of the subject
    property.”
     2008: The circuit court grants final summary judgment in favor of the City
    (and the State of Florida, a third party defendant) concluding that the statute
    of limitations had run on the Beyers’ taking claim. The Beyers appealed.
     2010: We reversed and remanded, finding that the Beyers did not bring a
    facial taking challenge but rather an as-applied taking challenge for which
    the statute of limitations had not run. Beyer v. City of Marathon, 
    37 So. 3d 932
    (Fla. 3d DCA 2010) (“Beyer I”).
     2012: On remand, the circuit court again granted summary judgment in
    favor of the City and State on the ground that the Beyers failed to establish
    reasonable investment-backed expectations and, alternatively, under the
    laches doctrine. The Beyers again appealed.
       2013: We concluded that the laches doctrine did not bar the Beyers’ claim,
    but we nevertheless affirm summary judgment on the basis that the Beyers
    failed to establish reasonable investment-backed expectations. Beyer v. City
    Dev. Code ch. 138.
    6
    of Marathon, 38 Fla. L. Weekly D2286 (Fla. 3d DCA Nov. 6, 2013) (“Beyer
    II”). The Beyers filed a timely motion for rehearing en banc.
    ANALYSIS
    The Takings Clause is clear and concise: “nor shall private property be taken
    for public use, without just compensation.” U.S. Const. amend. V. Regrettably,
    regulatory takings jurisprudence is cryptic and convoluted. The United States
    Supreme Court, in an effort to clarify its first regulatory takings test—outlined in
    Penn Central Transportation Co. v. City of New York, 
    438 U.S. 104
    (1978)—has
    left in its wake a collection of incongruous and inadequate takings inquiries. It is
    no wonder, then, that this Court’s brief Beyer II opinion flounders, but in its
    struggle for coherence, Beyer II further muddies the already murky waters. I write
    this dissent from the denial of the motion for rehearing en banc in the hopes that at
    some point in the not too distant future this court will embrace a less turbid, and
    more constitutionally sound, regulatory takings framework.
    Categories of Takings Challenges
    Before engaging in a taking analysis, it is useful to determine the category of
    the challenge to the regulatory action.        There are three2 main categories of
    2  A fourth category involves “special application of the ‘doctrine of
    unconstitutional conditions,’ which provides that ‘the government may not require
    a person to give up a constitutional right . . . in exchange for a discretionary benefit
    conferred by the government where the benefit has little or no relationship to the
    property.’” 
    Lingle, 544 U.S. at 547
    (quoting Dolan v. City of Tigard, 
    512 U.S. 374
    , 385 (1994)); see also Nollan v. Cal. Coastal Com’n, 
    483 U.S. 825
    (1987).
    7
    regulatory takings challenges. Lingle v. Chevron U.S.A. Inc., 
    544 U.S. 528
    , 538
    (2005). Two categories of regulatory action impose such a severe burden on
    private property rights that they are generally deemed per se takings (also referred
    to as categorical takings). 
    Id. The first
    occurs when a regulation “requires an
    owner to suffer a permanent physical invasion of her property.” Id.; see also
    Loretto v. Teleprompter Manhattan CATV Corp., 
    458 U.S. 419
    (1982).              The
    second type of per se taking “applies to regulations that completely deprive an
    owner of ‘all economically beneficial us[e]’ of her property.” 
    Lingle, 544 U.S. at 538
    (alteration in original) (quoting Lucas v. S. Carolina Coastal Council, 
    505 U.S. 1003
    (1992)). “Outside these two relatively narrow categories . . . regulatory
    takings challenges are governed by the standards set forth in [Penn Central].” 
    Id. The Beyers
    brought a per se/categorical taking challenge alleging a
    deprivation of all, or substantially all, economic use of their land (a Lucas-type
    total regulatory taking claim). See Lucas, 
    505 U.S. 1003
    . In Beyer I this court
    erroneously conflated the Beyers’ per se/categorical challenge with something else
    entirely—a facial taking 
    challenge. 37 So. 3d at 934
    . Under the mistaken belief
    that a per se/categorical taking was equivalent to a facial taking, Beyer I reframed
    the Beyers’ claim, presumably as one governed by Penn Central,3 to overcome the
    3 Beyer I never mentions Penn Central, but the opinion seems to suggest that the
    court considered the Beyers’ reframed “as-applied taking” challenge equivalent to
    a Penn Central taking challenge. On remand, the circuit court recognized that the
    Beyers had alleged a Lucas-type taking, but based on Beyer I’s holding, the court
    8
    statute of limitations that would have precluded the Beyers from bringing a facial
    taking challenge. In effect, Beyer I held that the Beyers were not permitted to
    allege a deprivation of all economic use because such a challenge would be
    precluded by the statute of limitations. Beyer II perpetuates this misconception.4
    ostensibly analyzed the Beyers’ claim under Penn Central. On appeal, Beyer II
    likewise recognized that the Beyers’ “complaint asserted that they have been
    deprived of all or substantially all reasonable economic use of the property[,]” but
    while the opinion briefly mentions Penn Central, the analysis seems rooted in the
    vested rights doctrine, which is distinct from a Takings Clause analysis under Penn
    Central.
    4 This confusion likely stems in large part from the United States Supreme Court’s
    now repudiated reliance on due process precedents in Takings Clause cases. In
    Agins v. City of Tiburon, 
    447 U.S. 255
    (1980), abrogated by Lingle, 
    544 U.S. 528
    ,
    the Court held that “[t]he application of a general zoning law to particular property
    effects a taking if the ordinance does not substantially advance legitimate state
    interests[.]” Under this framework, a regulation could effect a taking by its mere
    enactment if it did not substantially advance a legitimate state interest; its effects
    on the property would be immaterial. Facial taking challenges were brought under
    Agins’ formula since the “substantially advances” inquiry was thought to be
    separate from Penn Central or any of the other tests outlined above, which often
    require an inquiry into the actual burden imposed on property rights. See Lingle,
    
    544 U.S. 528
    . In Lingle, a unanimous Court held that the “substantially advances”
    formula was “doctrinally untenable” and “is not a valid method of discerning
    whether private property has been ‘taken’ for the purposes of the Fifth
    Amendment.” 
    Id. at 542.
    This is because “the ‘substantially advances’ inquiry
    reveals nothing about the magnitude or character of the burden a particular
    regulation imposes upon private property rights. Nor does it provide any
    information about how any regulatory burden is distributed among property
    owners. In consequence, this test does not help to identify those regulations whose
    effects are functionally comparable to government appropriation or invasion of
    private property; it is tethered neither to the text of the Takings Clause nor to the
    basic justification for allowing regulatory actions to be challenged under the
    Clause.” 
    Id. Since this
    suggests most takings claims under the Takings Clause
    involve an inquiry into the actual effects of the regulation (as-applied), it is unclear
    what role facial takings challenges have after Lingle.
    9
    That Beyer I and Beyer II are mistaken on this point is clear from Lucas,
    which is the leading per se/categorical “total regulatory takings” case. In Lucas,
    the property owner brought an as-applied challenge, not a facial taking challenge,
    under the theory that he had been deprived of all economically viable use of his
    
    property. 505 U.S. at 1042
    n.4 (“Here, of course, Lucas has brought an as-applied
    challenge.”). Similarly, the Beyers allege that the 2010 Plan—as applied to their
    property—effects a per se/categorical taking because it deprives them of all
    economic use of their land.
    Had the Beyers brought a facial taking challenge, there would have been no
    need for them to waste their time and money on a beneficial use determination
    because a facial taking claim alleges that the mere enactment of a regulation effects
    a taking regardless of any determination as to the regulation’s actual impact on the
    property in question. See Suitum v. Tahoe Reg’l Planning Agency, 
    520 U.S. 725
    ,
    736 (1997) (“Such ‘facial’ challenges to regulation are generally ripe the moment
    the challenged regulation or ordinance is passed, but face an ‘uphill battle,’ since it
    is difficult to demonstrate that ‘mere enactment’ of a piece of legislation ‘deprived
    [the owner] of economically viable use of [his] property.’” (citations omitted));
    Hodel v. Virginia Surface Min. & Reclamation Ass’n, Inc., 
    452 U.S. 264
    , 295
    (1981) (“Because appellees’ taking claim arose in the context of a facial challenge,
    it presented no concrete controversy concerning either application of the Act to
    10
    particular surface mining operations or its effect on specific parcels of land. Thus,
    the only issue properly before the District Court and, in turn, this Court, is whether
    the ‘mere enactment’ of the Surface Mining Act constitutes a taking.”). This
    fundamental misunderstanding of the distinction between a facial taking and a
    Lucas-type total regulatory taking has unfortunately engendered a confused and
    tortured analysis of the Beyers’ taking claim.
    The Beyers’ Taking Claim
    It is important to recognize at the outset that although the various takings
    tests outlined above are not particularly coherent, they share a common purpose:
    “to identify regulatory actions that are functionally equivalent to the classic taking
    in which government directly appropriates private property or ousts the owner
    from his domain.” 
    Lingle, 544 U.S. at 539
    ; see also Penn 
    Cent., 438 U.S. at 124
    (“[T]his Court, quite simply, has been unable to develop any ‘set formula’ for
    determining when ‘justice and fairness’ require that economic injuries caused by
    public action be compensated by the government, rather than remain
    disproportionately concentrated on a few persons.”). In its attempt to make sense
    of a genuinely enigmatic regulatory takings jurisprudence, Beyer II appears to have
    lost sight of this overarching purpose. In short, Beyer II fails to see the proverbial
    forest for the trees.
    11
    Although the Beyers brought a Lucas-type challenge alleging the deprivation
    of all economic use of their land, Beyer I went to great lengths to transform the
    Beyers’ categorical challenge into one controlled by the ad hoc, factual inquiry set
    forth Penn Central.5 This was unnecessary since the Beyers’ as-applied categorical
    challenge was not yet barred by the statute of limitations. Altering the Beyers’
    claim resulted in a refusal to adequately consider the economic impact of the
    regulation by both the circuit court on remand and this court in Beyer II. Further,
    even if the regulation’s economic impact were not sufficiently burdensome to give
    rise to a total regulatory taking claim, both Penn Central analyses are deeply
    flawed and ignore applicable Supreme Court precedent for irrelevant case law.
    1. The Total Taking Inquiry (Lucas)
    In Lucas, a property owner purchased two residential beachfront lots that
    were subsequently rendered undevelopable by the state’s enactment of the
    “Beachfront Management 
    Act.” 505 U.S. at 1006
    . As in this case, the owner did
    not challenge the validity of the Act as a lawful exercise of the state’s police
    power, “but contended that the Act’s complete extinguishment of his property’s
    value entitled him to compensation.” 
    Id. at 1009.
    Relying, in part, on Justice
    Holmes’s “oft-cited maxim” in Pennsylvania Coal Co. v. Mahon, 
    260 U.S. 393
    ,
    415 (1922), that “[t]he general rule at least is that while property may be regulated
    5   See supra note 3.
    12
    to a certain extent, if regulation goes too far it will be recognized as a taking,” the
    Supreme Court formulated a new categorical rule: “when the owner of real
    property has been called upon to sacrifice all economically beneficial uses in the
    name of the common good, that is, to leave his property economically idle, he has
    suffered a taking.” 
    Lucas, 505 U.S. at 1019
    . Although it is clear that the focus of
    this “total taking” inquiry is on the economic impact of the regulation, this
    potentially determinative factor seems to have been overlooked by the circuit court
    and Beyer II.
    Since the Beyers obtained a beneficial use determination that specifically
    considered the permitted economic uses of their property under the 2010 Plan,
    inquiry into the economic impact is rather straightforward.         According to the
    Special Master, “[o]ther than the Applicant being allowed to enter into the property
    to camp, there is absolutely no allowable use of the property under the City of
    Marathon Land Development Regulations.” In essence, the Beyers are required
    to leave their property in its natural state. Cf. 
    Lucas 505 U.S. at 1018
    (explaining
    “that regulations that leave the owner of land without economically beneficial or
    productive options for its use—typically, as here, [require] land to be left
    substantially in its natural state”). This is no different from the beachfront property
    in Lucas, which was found to have been deprived of all economically beneficial
    use.6 
    Id. at 1020.
    Indeed, the Beyers’ only allowable use for “temporary primitive
    13
    camping by the owner, in which no land clearing or other alteration of the island
    occurs” actually leaves them worse off than the property owner in Lucas because
    the Beyers would not even be permitted to stay permanently on their island, let
    alone live in a moveable trailer.     See 
    id. at 1044
    (Blackmun, J., dissenting)
    (“Petitioner can picnic, swim, camp in a tent, or live on the property in a movable
    trailer.”).
    Unfortunately, despite the unmistakable parallels between the economic
    impact in Lucas and the economic impact on the Beyers’ property, the Beyers’
    challenge was never considered under Lucas’s total regulatory takings framework.
    To add insult to injury, although the economic impact here is tremendously
    burdensome, it does not appear to have been considered in the context of the Penn
    Central analysis either. Even assuming for the sake of argument that the 2010 Plan
    did not give rise to a Lucas-type total regulatory taking because it did not deprive
    the Beyers of all or substantially all7 economically beneficial use, the regulation’s
    economic impact would still be a necessary factor in the Penn Central inquiry. As
    Justice Scalia, writing for the majority in Lucas, explained:
    6 This was based on an unreviewed state trial court finding.
    7  In Florida, the “substantially all” language is often added to the Lucas
    formulation. See, e.g., Tampa-Hillsborough Cty. Expressway Auth. v. A.G.W.S.
    Corp., 
    640 So. 2d 54
    , 58 (Fla. 1994), as clarified (June 23, 1994) (“A taking occurs
    where regulation denies substantially all economically beneficial or productive use
    of land.”). This suggests a slightly less demanding standard in Florida than the one
    in Lucas.
    14
    Justice STEVENS criticizes the “deprivation of all
    economically beneficial use” rule as “wholly arbitrary,”
    in that “[the] landowner whose property is diminished in
    value 95%[8] recovers nothing,” while the landowner who
    suffers a complete elimination of value “recovers the
    land’s full value.” This analysis errs in its assumption
    that the landowner whose deprivation is one step
    short of complete is not entitled to compensation.
    Such an owner might not be able to claim the benefit
    of our categorical formulation, but, as we have
    acknowledged time and again, “[t]he economic impact
    of the regulation on the claimant and . . . the extent to
    which the regulation has interfered with distinct
    investment-backed expectations” are keenly relevant
    to takings analysis 
    generally. 505 U.S. at 1019
    n.8 (emphasis added) (citing Penn 
    Cent., 483 U.S. at 124
    ).
    2. The Ad Hoc, Factual Inquiry (Penn Central)
    In Penn Central, the United States Supreme Court identified several factors
    that “have served as the principal guidelines for resolving regulatory takings claims
    that do not fall within the . . . Lucas rules.” 
    Lingle, 544 U.S. at 539
    . As the
    Supreme Court has explained:
    Where a regulation places limitations on land that fall
    short of eliminating all economically beneficial use, a
    taking nonetheless may have occurred, depending on a
    complex of factors including the regulation's economic
    effect on the landowner, the extent to which the
    8 If a 95% diminution in value is considered “one step short of complete,” the
    Beyers are about as close as one could possibly get to complete since their property
    has diminished in value by at least 98.7%. In 1970, the Beyers purchased their
    property for $70,000. As a result of the various regulations, the appraisal value of
    the Beyers’ land has plummeted to a mere $900, which is only about 1.3 percent of
    the original purchase price.
    15
    regulation interferes with reasonable investment-backed
    expectations, and the character of the government action.
    Palazzolo v. Rhode Island, 
    533 U.S. 606
    , 617 (2001) (citing Penn 
    Cent., 483 U.S. at 124
    ).
    Both the circuit court and Beyer II claim to evaluate the Beyers’ taking
    challenge under Penn Central. Yet, despite the Supreme Court’s insistence that no
    individual Penn Central factor be singled out as determinative, the circuit court and
    Beyer II did just that, brushing aside the undoubtedly relevant economic impact
    factor and focusing solely on “reasonable investment-backed expectations.” See
    
    Palazzolo, 533 U.S. at 634
    (O’Connor, J., concurring) (“The court erred in
    elevating what it believed to be ‘[petitioner’s] lack of reasonable investment-
    backed expectations’ to ‘dispositive’ status.       Investment-backed expectations,
    though important, are not talismanic under Penn Central. Evaluation of the degree
    of interference with investment-backed expectations instead is one factor that
    points toward the answer to the question whether the application of a particular
    regulation to particular property ‘goes too far.’” (citation omitted) (alteration in
    original)); 
    Lingle, 544 U.S. at 540
    (“And the Penn Central inquiry turns in large
    part, albeit not exclusively, upon the magnitude of a regulation’s economic impact
    and the degree to which it interferes with legitimate property interests.”).
    To further complicate matters, the cursory analyses of “reasonable
    investment-backed expectations” are confused and fundamentally flawed. Both
    16
    the circuit court’s and Beyer II’s findings that the 2010 Plan did not interfere with
    the Beyers’ reasonable investment-backed expectations are based on two unsound
    arguments. First, the Beyers waited too long to assert their constitutional rights in
    the face of ever tightening restrictions thereby forfeiting any expectations to
    develop their land. And second, the Beyers failed to produce any evidence of their
    subjective expectations. A third perplexing justification is raised only in Beyer II:
    that the award of ROGO points satisfied the Beyers’ investment-backed
    expectations. These three arguments are treated in turn.
    a. Prolonged Inaction
    The prolonged inaction argument is based on the misunderstanding that
    regulations passed after the acquisition of property, if not challenged quickly
    enough, diminish a property owner’s expectations so as to extinguish
    constitutionally protected property rights. The argument ignores the “investment-
    backed” qualifier and looks to a property owner’s non-investment-backed
    expectations at an unspecified point in time within a post-acquisition regulatory
    regime. Cf. Daniel R. Mandelker, Investment-Backed Expectations in Taking
    Law, 27 Urb. Law. 215, 235-36 (1995) (“Investment-backed expectations held by
    property owners arise at the time of purchase and the information they have then
    about their property gives them meaning.”). This, of course, creates uncertainty
    since expectations could be widely variable and without the “investment-backed”
    17
    requirement, there is nothing that dictates when a property owner’s expectations
    ought to be evaluated. Although the precise meaning of the reasonable investment-
    backed expectations factor is hardly clear,9 it is not quite as nebulous as this
    “prolonged inaction” theory would suggest.
    At its core, the theory is predicated on the mistaken belief that notice of
    post-acquisition regulations is a relevant indicium of investment-backed
    expectations. This approach is not supported by federal takings jurisprudence, and
    it is undermined by Supreme Court precedent. For example, in Palazzolo, the
    Supreme Court held that even regulations passed before the acquisition of property
    do not necessarily have a detrimental impact on the reasonable investment-backed
    expectations of subsequent owners who take title with notice of the regulations:
    The Takings Clause . . . in certain circumstances allows a
    landowner to assert that a particular exercise of the
    State’s regulatory power is so unreasonable or onerous as
    to compel compensation. Just as a prospective enactment,
    such as a new zoning ordinance, can limit the value of
    land without effecting a taking because it can be
    understood as reasonable by all concerned, other
    enactments are unreasonable and do not become less
    so through passage of time or title. Were we to accept
    9  See J. David Breemer & R. S. Radford, The (Less?) Murky Doctrine of
    Investment-Backed Expectations After Palazzolo, and the Lower Courts’
    Disturbing Insistence on Wallowing in the Pre-Palazzolo Muck, 34 Sw. U.L. Rev.
    351, 352 (2005) (“The Supreme Court’s regulatory takings jurisprudence is one of
    the most heatedly divisive topics in contemporary constitutional law. One point, on
    which all sides agree, however, is that the meaning and significance of
    ‘investment-backed expectations’ is among the most baffling elements of this
    confusing and seemingly schizophrenic doctrine.” (citations omitted)).
    18
    the State’s rule, the postenactment transfer of title would
    absolve the State of its obligation to defend any action
    restricting land use, no matter how extreme or
    unreasonable. A State would be allowed, in effect, to
    put an expiration date on the Takings Clause. This
    ought not to be the rule. Future generations, too, have a
    right to challenge unreasonable limitations on the use and
    value of 
    land. 533 U.S. at 627
    (emphasis added). This being the case, the Beyers, who were not
    on notice of the regulations now being challenged at the time of acquisition, a
    fortiori, have a right to challenge the alleged unreasonable limitation on the use
    and value of their land. Notice of regulations passed after the acquisition of
    property does not intrude on this right.
    Since the “prolonged inaction” argument finds no basis in federal takings
    jurisprudence, it should come as no surprise that the case cited in support of this
    approach by both the circuit court10 and Beyer II is not a regulatory takings case
    but a vested rights case.11 See Monroe Cty. v. Ambrose, 
    866 So. 2d 707
    (Fla. 3d
    10 The circuit court also cites a federal takings case, Good v. United States, 
    189 F.3d 1355
    (Fed. Cir. 1999), for the proposition that a property owner who waited
    “seven years, watching as the applicable regulations got more stringent” lacked
    reasonable investment-backed expectations based on such “prolonged inaction.”
    The court’s reliance on Good, however, is misplaced. Good, a pre-Palazzolo case,
    is quite clear that it was not the seven year delay that had a detrimental effect on
    the property owner’s “reasonable investment-backed expectations” but, rather, the
    regulatory environment that existed at the time the land was acquired. 
    Id. at 1363
    (“While Appellant’s prolonged inaction does not bar his takings claim, it
    reduces his ability to fairly claim surprise when his permit application was denied.
    Appellant was aware at the time of purchase of the need for regulatory approval
    to develop his land.” (emphasis added)).
    11 Ordinarily, once a vested right has been established, it is protected not by the
    19
    DCA 2003). It is true, as both the circuit court and Beyer II assert, that landowners
    cannot establish a vested right without taking steps to develop their land. See 
    id. at 711
    (“If the Landowners did not start development prior to the enactment of these
    land regulations, they acted at their own peril in relying on the absence of zoning
    ordinances.”). But the Beyers are not bringing a claim or seeking a remedy under
    the vested rights doctrine, nor do they need to. Vested rights are conceptually
    distinct from the property rights at issue in this case.12 It is therefore perplexing
    that both the circuit court and Beyer II rely on such an incongruous framework to
    find that the Beyers lacked reasonable investment-backed expectations.
    In a nutshell, the vested rights doctrine is a creature of state law13 that
    prevents the government from interfering with a landowner’s right to complete
    Takings Clause, but by the Due Process Clause. See Maronda Homes, Inc. v.
    Lakeview Reserve Homeowners Ass’n, Inc., 
    127 So. 3d 1258
    , 1272 (Fla. 2013)
    (“These constitutional due process rights protect individuals from the retroactive
    application of a substantive law that adversely affects or destroys a vested right;
    imposes or creates a new obligation or duty in connection with a previous
    transaction or consideration; or imposes new penalties.”).
    12 “While vested rights may be a clear way for property owners to obtain
    enforceable expectations, see [Mandelker, supra p. 16, at 237-38], a rule that
    equates the two doctrines is too narrow and would result in insufficient protection
    of property interests.” Robert M. Washburn, “Reasonable Investment-Backed
    Expectations” As A Factor in Defining Property Interest, 49 Wash. U.J. Urb. &
    Contemp. L. 63, 96 (1996); see also Breemer, supra note 9, at 396 (“[I]t is unfair to
    hinge reasonable expectations on the commencement of development before
    regulation because this effectively requires federal takings claimants to establish
    vested rights under state law . . . . But no federal court has ever held that state law
    vested rights are a necessary condition for acquisition of federal reasonable
    expectations.”).
    13 Vested rights are created by common law, statute, or contract. See 10A Fla. Jur
    20
    development of property when there has been sufficient reliance on the regulatory
    climate in existence at the time development began. See 
    Ambrose, 866 So. 2d at 710
    (outlining the common law vested rights test).            In contrast, the Beyers’
    constitutionally protected property rights at issue here are distinct from any
    governmental benefit granted by the state. See 
    Nollan, 483 U.S. at 833
    (“But the
    right to build on one’s own property-even though its exercise can be subjected to
    legitimate   permitting   requirements-cannot      remotely     be   described   as   a
    ‘governmental benefit.’”); Andrea L. Peterson, The Takings Clause: In Search of
    Underlying Principles Part II Takings As Intentional Deprivations of Property
    Without Moral Justification, 
    78 Cal. L
    . Rev. 53, 61 (1990) (explaining that
    constitutionally protected property “includes the freedom to pursue economically
    advantageous activities even when no law affirmatively grants such a right.”).
    The fact that these are distinct rights is recognized by the primary case cited
    by both the circuit court and Beyer II.      14   See 
    Ambrose, 866 So. 2d at 712
    (explaining that although subsequently enacted regulations apply to landowners
    who do not have vested rights, “to the extent that these regulations render any of
    the Landowners’ property practically useless, the Landowners are entitled to
    2d Constitutional Law § 378.
    14 The regulations under which the Beyers’ beneficial use determination was made
    also distinguish between a vested rights determination (Policy 101-18.2) and a
    beneficial use procedure for total regulatory takings (Policy 101.18.5.1). See also
    Marathon, Fla., Code of Ordinances art. 18 (2015) (“Beneficial Use
    Determinations”); 
    id. art. 19
    (2015) (“Vested Rights Determinations”).
    21
    compensation”); see also § 380.08, Fla. Stat. (“Nothing in this chapter authorizes
    any governmental agency to adopt a rule or regulation or issue any order that is
    unduly restrictive or constitutes a taking of property without the payment of full
    compensation, in violation of the constitutions of this state or of the United
    States.”).   As these are distinct property interests, the Beyers do not need to
    establish a vested right for there to be a taking that requires “full compensation.”
    b. Lack of Evidence
    The second argument advanced by the circuit court and Beyer II is that the
    Beyers’ failure to provide evidence of their particular investment-backed
    expectations makes summary judgment in favor the City appropriate. This narrow
    emphasis on subjective expectations is misplaced.             The requirement that
    “investment-backed expectations” be reasonable requires an objective evaluation.
    See 
    Lucas, 505 U.S. at 1035
    (“The expectations protected by the Constitution are
    based on objective rules and customs that can be understood as reasonable by all
    parties involved.”); Res. Investments, Inc. v. United States, 
    85 Fed. Cl. 447
    , 511
    (2009) (“The investment-backed expectations prong requires ‘an objective, but
    fact-specific inquiry into what, under all the circumstances, the [landowner] should
    have anticipated.’ . . . ‘[A] party’s subjective expectation is irrelevant to whether
    that expectation is reasonable.’” (quoting Cienega Gardens v. United States, 
    331 F.3d 1319
    , 1346 (Fed. Cir. 2003))).
    22
    Although the Supreme Court has provided sparse guidance as to the
    application of the expectations factor, one significant objective criterion that
    shapes a property owner’s expectations is “the regulatory regime in place at the
    time the claimant acquires the property at issue.” 
    Palazzolo, 533 U.S. at 633
    (O’Connor, J., concurring). On this point, it is undisputed that when the Beyers
    purchased their property, it was zoned “General Use,” which allowed one single
    family home per acre. In contrast, under the 2010 Plan, the Beyers are not allowed
    to alter the island from its natural state whatsoever. This is one major objective
    fact that helps establish the Beyers’ “reasonable investment-backed expectations,”
    and it is undoubtedly sufficient for the Beyers’ claim to survive summary
    judgment.
    It is therefore inaccurate to assert, as do the circuit court and Beyer II, that
    there is no evidence of investment-backed expectations. Indeed, both the circuit
    court and Beyer II recognize that expectations can be shaped by a regulatory
    regime since both conclude that the Beyers did not have reasonable expectations
    due, at least in part, to the ever-tightening restrictions on their land.15 It is more
    than a little perplexing that the circuit court and Beyer II seem to have no trouble
    concluding that the Beyers’ expectations were defined by post-acquisition
    15 As has been already been explained, this approach errs in its timing, but it is
    correct in its observation that expectations can be informed by the regulatory
    climate.
    23
    regulations, but they are at a complete loss when it comes to determining the
    Beyers’ investment-backed expectations in light of the lack of restrictions that
    were in place when the Beyers purchased their property—i.e. at the time of
    investment.
    c. ROGO Points
    Almost as an afterthought, Beyer II concludes that the City’s award of
    ROGO points “reasonably meets the Beyers’ economic expectations[.]” This is a
    puzzling assertion since it seems to undermine the opinion’s findings elsewhere
    that the Beyers did not have reasonable investment-backed expectations. After all,
    how could an award of ROGO points meet non-existent expectations? In any
    event, Beyer II appears to rely on the Special Master’s finding that the Beyers have
    “been adequately compensated by the issuance of 16 ROGO points.” Although it
    is not clear what the Special Master considered the points compensation for, if they
    are compensation in the takings context, the Constitution requires not that the
    compensation merely be adequate, but that the compensation be “just.”           See
    
    Palazzolo, 533 U.S. at 631
    (2001) (“Assuming a taking is otherwise established, a
    State may not evade the duty to compensate on the premise that the landowner is
    left with a token interest.”).
    Moreover, bearing in mind that Beyer II affirms the circuit court’s grant of
    summary judgment, there is a much more profound problem with Beyer II’s
    24
    cursory reliance on ROGO points: this justification was never raised in the City’s
    motion for summary judgment or in any of the briefs on appeal, and it is plainly a
    contested fact. Indeed, the evidence for a ROGO points valuation in the record
    would be woefully inadequate to find no genuine issue as to this material fact.16
    The only evidence in the record is from the beneficial use hearing. There, the
    Assistant City Attorney testified that a “two point ROGO dedication lot can
    generate anywhere from 25 to $40,000” but conceded that he was not a real estate
    expert and that this figure was arrived at anecdotally and not derived from any
    economic analysis of the current marketplace.         Further, the Special Master
    sustained the Beyers’ objection to this testimony as improper hearsay evidence.
    Since Beyer II improperly relied on this disputed issue of fact, the Beyers
    were caught by surprise and only able to address the issue in their motion for
    rehearing, where they argue that ROGO points have no market value. This is
    problematic because the record is insufficient to make a determination one way or
    the other. Consequently, the ROGO points valuation is not a fact upon which
    summary judgment ought to be based, and it is an improper justification for
    affirmance.
    16 This is particularly true under Florida’s summary judgment standard, which is
    more demanding than its federal counterpart. See, e.g., Piedra v. City of N. Bay
    Vill., 41 Fla. L. Weekly D1087 (Fla. 3d DCA May 4, 2016) (“If the record on
    appeal reveals the merest possibility of genuine issues of material fact, or even the
    slightest doubt in this respect, the summary judgment must be reversed.”).
    25
    CONCLUSION
    Although the intricacies of the various takings inquiries are without a doubt
    complicated and imprecise, one thing is certain: the Beyers have been singled out
    to suffer significant economic injuries in the name of the public good. They
    purchased an island zoned for residential development that the government
    transformed into a “bird rookery.” The only allowable use now is temporary,
    primitive camping (provided, incidentally, that no land clearing or alteration of the
    island occurs). If this is not a situation where justice and fairness require that
    economic injuries caused by public action be compensated by the government, I do
    not know what is. The decision of this Court that the Beyers have no constitutional
    taking claim against the City for what are indisputably excessive economic injuries
    is, well, for the birds. I hope that someday in the near future, this court reaffirms
    the notion that citizens have rights too. Accordingly, I respectfully dissent from
    the denial of the motion for rehearing en banc.
    LAGOA and EMAS, JJ., concur.
    26