Page v. Webster , 15 Me. 249 ( 1839 )


Menu:
  • *253The case was continued for advisemenl, and the opinion of the Court was subsequently drawn up by

    Shepley J.

    The note was made payable “at either of the banks in Portland and the question arises under the first request, whether it was the duty of the plaintiff, before the note became due, to give notice to the makers, in what bank it might be found when due. The intention of the parties to the contract, if it can be ascertained, is to be carried into effect. Obligations are not to be imposed upon the holder, nor liabilities upon the indorser, which were never designed. This form of a note has been introduced into this part of the country within a few years ; and it may aid in determining the rights and duties of the parties to inquire at whose instance the note must have been so formed. It is not easy to perceive what benefit the maker wrould derive from a note in that form, unless it wore made by a banker or hanking house, in which case there might ho hope of advantage from an increased circulation. While the maker ordinarily could derive no advantage from such a form, he might justly apprehend some inconvenience in looking up the note to pay it. For as it regards him it is quite clear, that the holder by the law in this, and most of the other States, is not obliged to have it at the place where payable. A readiness to pay at the appointed place is matter in defence only. Bacon v. Dyer, 3 Fairf. 19, and cases cited in Bayley on Bids, 203, note 15. It is not therefore probable, that it was so formed for his interest or accommodation. To the payee it might be of advantage. He might be desirous of making use of the note in the market, or at a banking house to obtain the money before it became due. It would be convenient to have it payable at a bank to save the risk and trouble of a presentment to the maker. And if made payable at a particular bank it would not be so readily received at other banks, because it would subject, them to the risk and trouble of being watchful for the day of payment, and of sending it to the bank where payable for presentment. It would bo natural for business men to endeavor to obviate this difficulty so as to enable them the most readily to obtain cash for the note at any bank, not being limited to one, where funds were to be loaned. A note payable at any bank in a place would therefore be desirable to the payee, and it is but reasonable to conclude, that sucb a form was introduced for his *254convenience and interest. And if so, does it not shew, that the intention of the parties was to relieve the payee or holder from risks and troubles to which he might be subjected, if made payable at any one bank only ? And if such were the intentions of the parties, they can only be carried into effect by requiring the maker to look for his note at all the places where he promises to pay it. For to require the holder to give the previous notice now insisted upon would not only defeat the object of relieving from trouble and risk, but would subject to much greater, than if made payable at one bank only. The maker’s express promise to pay at any one of several places would indicate to a common mind the duty to act according to what is supposed to have been the intention of the parties, and to look at all the places for it, or have funds there when it became due. And as respects his own liabilities, it has already been seen, that he must do it to relieve himself from the danger of costs, or at least must shew in defence a readiness at some place named. The payee never could have designed by receiving a note in that form to have incurred the responsibilities now supposed to attach to it, yet if there is any rule of law so clearly settled and well established as to decide the legal construction, which ought to be given to a contract in that form, the parties must be supposed to intend to conform to it.

    Pothier discusses the duties of debtor and creditor when payment is to be made at a certain place, as a town or city, and the creditor has no domicil there; and decides, that the creditor must notify the debtor, where he will receive payment before he can put him in fault. And if he does not, and the debtor wishes to pay, he should assign or require him to do it, and upon his refusal the debtor will be allowed to appoint the place. He then says, it remains to be observed, that if the agreement contains two different places for payment, and they are connected by a conjunctive particle, the payment ought to be made by a moiety in each place.” “ If by a disjunctive the payment ought to be made altogether, in either, at the election of the debtor ; generaliter definit Scaevola petitorem habere electionem ubi petat, reum ubi sohat scilicit ante peiitionem.” Pothier, part 2, ch. 3, art. 4. § 241. Where payment is to be made at either of several places, according to the Jloman lawyer Scaevola, as quoted with approbation by Pothier, *255Hie debtor may before demand, pay at either of the places; if he Roes not, and demand is to be made, the creditor may make it at Either place. No intimation is made of a duty on the part of the proditor to notify before it becomes due, where the debtor may may; and the duty required of the debtor before that time to elect [his place of payment would not be consistent with such a requisition. And Gibbs C. J. seems so to have understood the creditor’s rights, where he says, “ Í am of opinion as the note was payable at two places, that the plaintiffs had an option to present it at either.” Beeching v. Gower, 1 Holt, 317. And that was a case to charge an indorser. This is adopted by Mr. Justice Bay ley in his treatise on Bills, 232.

    The case of the North Bank v. Abbott, 13 Pick. 465, is relied upon as requiring the creditor to give such a notice. Having the highest respect for that court, if a decision to that effect had been made, it would necessarily have had much weight. The Chief Justice, speaking of such a note, says, it would seem to follow from other established rules, that in such case the holder should give notice to the promisor, where the note is. But it is not necessary to give any opinion in the present case.” This cannot be regarded as settling the law in that State. And even if it were so settled, when a note is payable in cities so large, that there might be difficulty in ascertaining the number and place of business of the banks within the business hours of the day, there is no necessity for adopting such a rule in this State where all the banks in any one place can bo visited in ten or fifteen minutes.

    The next request relates to the neglect to enter and prosecute the suit commenced against the principals, or makers of the note. The plaintiff does not appear to have made any such contract for delay as precluded him from immediately commencing another suit; but it is said, that the effect must necessarily have been to delay. Mere delay after the indorser is once charged does not discharge him. It is only by such a contract for delay as binds the holder and disables him from proceeding, that the indorser is discharged. In the case of the Bank of the United States v. Hatch, 6 Peters, 250, which is relied upon by the counsel, this doctrine is clearly stated ; and the decision in that case was not based upon the mere fact of the continuance, but upon the agreement made, by which *256he disabled himself from commencing again until the nest termj The true inquiry is stated to be “ whether the parties did or did noil intend a surceasing of all legal proceedings during that period1 and the conclusion was, that the agreement suspended the right tc| recover the debt until the next term. And it appears from tin! reasoning, that if the right to commence anew had remained, thc-í plaintiff might have recovered. '

    In the case of Lenox v. Prout, 3 Wheat. 520, it was decided that an indorser was not discharged by a countermanding by the holder of an execution, on which the debt might have been collected of the maker, when the indorser offered to point out property to the officer and to indemnify him for selling it.

    And in the case of Fulton v. Matthews, 15 Johns. R. 433, it was decided, that a discontinuance of a suit against the principal, without consent of the surety did not discharge him.

    Another part of the request relates to the neglect of the plaintiff to commence suits against the makers as requested by the defendant. This doctrine may be said to have had its origin in the case of Pain v. Packard, 13 Johns. R. 174, where it appears to have been admitted, because it was supposed to have been the doctrine of chancery, as it would seem from the remarks of Spencer C. J. when giving his opinion in the case of King v. Baldwin, 17 Johns. R. 384, where he continues to adhere to it upon that ground. He says, “ the doctrine is, that it is inequitable and unjust for the creditor, by delaying to sue, to expose the surety to the hazards arising from a prolongation of the credit, and that the surety has an equity sufficient to invoke the interposition of the powers of a Court of Chancery for his protection.” Here the ground of interposition is said to be in chancery, the exposing of the surety to the hazard arising from a prolongation of the credit. And yet there is no point more perfectly settled, than that mere delay is not a cause of complaint. It is believed, that upon an examination of all the cases, it will be found, that chancery had never admitted any such principle, as was supposed. It is not upon a request simply without an offer of indemnity against the risk, delay and expense, that the holder is required to proceed against the principal to the exclusion of the surety. Wright v. Simpson, 6 Ves. 734; Mayes v. Ward, 4 Johns. Ch. R. 123. The rule in equity commends itself *257lo tbe judgment as reasonable and just. But to hold, that the payee or indorsee must proceed on request against the principal at whatever risk of loss by a change in the responsibility of the surety or indorser, and at expense, delay, and risk in endeavoring to obtain payment from him or from his property, the title to which may prove to be doubtful, is allowing the surety to throw upon the holder much of the risk and trouble, which by the contract he assumes and engages to free the holder from. Hence it was, that in chancery the doctrine of Pain v. Packard was repudiated, as setting up a rule unknown to it. And the Chancellor says, “ there is no case, however, in the English law in which the personal application of the surety to the creditor was held to be compulsory on tbe Creditor, at tbe hazard of discharging tiro surety.” King v. Baldwin, 2 Johns. Ch. R. 554. It is true, that tbe Chancellor’s decision was reversed in the Court of Errors by a casting vote ; but instead of adding strength to the former decision, it exhibited a part of the same Judges as satisfied, that it was erroneous. And whatever of authority existed in those cases may be regarded as destroyed by the case of Warner v. Beardsley, 8 Wend. 194, whore the cases in accordance with and opposed to it are referred to, and the doctrine of chancery is again stated, requiring in such case an indemnity from the surety. In Massachusetts the doctrine of Pain v. Packard, seemed to find some countenance in the case of Hunt v. Bridgham, as well as in this State, in Kennebec Bank v. Tuckerman, 5 Greenl. 130. It was doubted in Crane v. Newhall, 2 Pick. 612, and in Frye v. Barker, it is said never to have been adopted there. And in the case of the Freeman’s Bank v. Rollins, 13 Maine R. 202, it is left in this State, as an undecided question. Upon examining the origin of the doctrine, and the opinions of eminent Judges in various cases, since decided, tbe impression is left, that the doctrine arose out of a misconception of the true rule in chancery ; that the reasons upon which it rests are unsound ; and that it places the rights of the parties to the contract upon a basis never contemplated or designed by them, and that it ought not to be received as a rule of law in this State.

    Another point made in the defence was, that property attached was released, and that the principals have since conveyed.

    *258Where the creditor has available property of the principal in his hands, from which without loss, expense, or injury to himself, he can obtain the debt, it is his duty to do so. And when he has collateral security, he should not surrender it to the principal without the consent of the surety who has an equitable right of substitution, that upon payment he may have the like advantage of such collateral or additional security. And it may he, that by giving a bond of indemnity without going into chancery, he may require the creditor to sell any property attached, and make the money out of it. But a creditor cannot be expected at his own expense and risk to prosecute a suit to judgment, and upon the execution take either personal or real estate, the title to which may be doubtful, for the sake of relieving a surety, who instead of doing his own duty by paying the debt, stands by and assumes no risk to save himself from the consequences, which are the result of his contract.

    This is the doctrine of the cases of best authority, and it is not at variance with that of the case of Baker v. Briggs. In that case, the instruction was predicated ujdoh the position, that the plaintiff had personal property of the principal in his hands, as security for the debt, and delivered it back without the consent of the surety. But the debtor has no just cause of complaint, when the property is not in his own hands, that the creditor prefers looking to his surety in preference to taking upon himself the risk of endeavoring to obtain payment from property, over which he has no more control, than the debtor might have by paying the debt and commencing a suit in his own behalf.

    Exceptions overruled.

Document Info

Citation Numbers: 15 Me. 249

Judges: Shepley

Filed Date: 4/15/1839

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 11/10/2024