Fidelity Trust Co. v. Clerk of Supreme Court , 36 Vroom 495 ( 1900 )


Menu:
  • The opinion of the court was delivered by

    Garrison, J.

    The question to be determined upon this application is whether the clerk of the Supreme Court should be commanded to permit the Fidelity Trust Company to examine the “patent or short form of indices” described in the fifth section of the “agreed state of facts.” And this, in turn, depends upon whether the relator has a clear legal right to the inspection demanded in its behalf. The leading case in this state upon this general subject is Lum v. McCarty, 10 Vroom 287. In that ease the Court of Errors held that county clerks are not entitled to demand fees for searches of the records in their offices made by an attorney for his client. The ratio decidendi of this case as to the records of conveyances and mortgages was that the right of public-access to them was conferred by pertinent statutes, and that as to the records of judgments, they likewise were free to the-public, because they were “public records and were public property, kept in a public place, at the public expense, for *498the public benefit.” With respect to indices of judgments, the opinion said that “for the convenience of the public in examining these (judgments) the law provides for the making of proper indexes of their contents.” Nix. Dig., tit. “Practice Act,” § 77. This statutory regulation is that county clerks shall enter complete records of judgments “in a separate book to be kept for that purpose, with a complete alphabetical index to the same.” Lum v. McCarty is, therefore, an authority for the rule that a member of the general public may, without payment of a fee, search for judgment records in the public office in which they are by law required to be entered, and to that end have a right of access to the books required to be kept for that purpose, with an alphabetical index to the same. This decision is, by the facts of the case, limited to the indices of the separate books in which judgments were directed to be entered, and by the reasoning of the case it is confined to the indices that the clerk is by law required to keep. It is not, therefore, an authority with respect to the patent indices with which we are concerned, which are of a different character and are not required by any law to be kept. It is not an authority for the broad doctrine contended for, that whatever the public pays for it may lawfully demand the right to use. There is a sense, however, in which this doctrine is illustrated in the present case, although not in the manner for which contention is made.

    By the act of March 5th, 1896 (Pamph. L., ¶. 50), the clerk of the Supreme Court was placed upon a salary and the gross receipts of the office were turned into the state treasury. The effect of this legislation was that thenceforward the clerk must serve two publics—one the comparatively small public composed of those who malee a personal use of the office; the other, the larger public, comprising all the citizens of the state, into whose treasury the earnings of the office go. This double trust furnishes, I think, the key to the situation before us. Eor back of each of these trusts there is a legislative policy—one respecting the use of the office, the other respecting its earnings. The two are mutually exclusive, but are not necessarily' conflicting. Upon the one hand, it is plainly *499the legislative policy that certain things are to be furnished by the state free of charge; on the other, it is clearly the legislative policy that the office shall produce an incqme to the state. In a given case the question is that of ascertaining which of these is the legislative will.

    In the present case there are several considerations that lead me to the conclusion that the intended beneficiary of the legislature in maintaining at public cost these “patent in-dices” is the citizen public that is interested in the state treasury, rather than the smaller public that makes actual use of the office.

    In the first place, these “patent indices” are not required by law to be kept, and the separate indices that are so required are kept and are open to the relator as one of the public.

    Second, these patent indices are not required to be kept at all. They might at any moment be discontinued without violence to the clerk’s official bond or to the written or unwritten law of his office.

    Third, in Lum v. McCarty the indices declared to be public were those that were required by law to be kept, and in the case of Barber v. Title Co., 8 Dick. Ch. Rep. 158, it was said, in the opinion of the Court of Errors and Appeals, that “the case of Lum v. McCarty carries the right of the public to its extreme limit.”

    Fourth, under the fee system, these patent indices were used solely for the emolument of the clerk. The change by which that official was placed upon a salary and the gross receipts of his office declared to be “for the sole use of the State of New Jersey” (Pamph. L. 1896, p. 50) did not enlarge the right of special access of the public to the contents of the office; it simply placed the state in the clerk’s stead with respect to the earnings. What before was accessible remained accessible, and what before was inaccessible remained so. In view of this legislative programme, the fact that these indices are kept up at public expense is entirely consistent with their inaccessibility to the' public—it is the opposite course that would be inconsistent with this policy of the law.

    *500As the result of these considerations, my conclusion is that (to put it no stronger than is necessary) the relator has not that “clear legal right” to inspect the indices in question which is essential to the exercise of the discretion appealed to by this application. The rule to show cause should be discharged.

Document Info

Citation Numbers: 65 N.J.L. 495, 36 Vroom 495, 47 A. 451, 1900 N.J. Sup. Ct. LEXIS 48

Judges: Garrison

Filed Date: 11/12/1900

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 11/11/2024