Guaranty Trust Co. v. Henwood , 59 S. Ct. 847 ( 1939 )


Menu:
  • Mr. Justice Stone,

    dissenting.

    Without considering the question whether the bondholders in these cases have properly exercised their options, I cannot agree that the Joint Resolution of Congress of. June 5, 1933, has set- at naught the promise of the bonds to pay guilders to the holders at their election.

    In each case the' bonds contain alternative and mutually exclusive undertakings. The holder could if he wished demand payment in United States gold dollars of a fixed, standard or their equivalent in United States currency. The alternative promise is for payment abroad of specified amounts of any one of several foreign currencies, without reference to their gold value at the time of payment. Its performance is as independent of gold or gold value as if it had called for the delivery of a specified amount of wheat, sugar or coffee, or the performance of specified services.

    Any construction of the gold clause resolution which would in the circumstances of the present case preclude payment in foreign money would equally forbid performance of- an alternative promise calling for the delivery of a commodity or the rendition of services. Hence the decisive question is whether the resolution admits of a construction which would compel one whose contract stipulates for delivery at his option of a cargo of sugar to accept instead payment of a specified amount in legal tender dollars, merely because by the terms of his contract he might have demanded, though he did not, an equal number of gold dollars.

    *261When the Joint Resolution was adopted there were many obligations of American citizens payable abroad exclusively in foreign currency, and the attendant devaluation of the dollar greatly increased the burden of performance of such contracts through the necessity of purchasing with depreciated dollars the foreign exchange required for their fulfillment. But it must be conceded that Congress did not undertake to relieve any American citizen of that burden, and it is not contended that the Joint Resolution provided for the discharge of any obligations payable in foreign currency, not measured in gold, except in the case where the promise to pay in foreign money is an alternative for the promise to pay in dollars. After devaluation of the dollar the burden on American citizens of meeting obligations abroad by payment in foreign currencies may well have been as great whether the undertaking was unconditional or to pay upon a condition which had happened, or whether the obligation was to pay in a foreign currency or to supply goods which must be acquired by the expenditure of depreciated dollars.

    We can find nothing in the legislative history of the Joint Resolution or its language to suggest any Congressional policy to relieve from the one form of obligation more than another, or to indicate that the resolution was aimed at anything other than provisions calling for payment in gold value or gold dollars or their equivalent, which Congress explicitly named and described as the evil to be remedied, both in the Joint Resolution itself and in the committee reports attending its adoption. See Sen. Rep. No. 99, 73d Cong., 1st Sess.; H. R. Rep. No. 169, 73d Cong., 1st Sess.

    The Joint Resolution of Congress and the committee reports make no mention of obligations dischargeable in foreign currencies or by delivery of commodities or performance of services. If- it was the purpose of Congress *262to control such obligations through the exercise of its power to regulate the value of money, that fact must be discoverable from the language of the resolution or from some underlying public policy, .to which its words and the records of Congress give no clue. Shortly before the adoption of the resolution, Congress had authorized the President to devalue the dollar. By appropriate legislation and executive action, gold payments by the Tréasury had been suspended, the hoarding of gold and its exportation had been prohibited, and all persons had been required to deliver gold owned by them to the Treasury. See Norman v. Baltimore & Ohio R. Co., 294 U. S. 240, 295 et seq. It was obvious that these measures, aimed at the suppression of the use of gold as a standard of currency value, would fail of their purpose unless all payments in gold of the established standard or its equivalent were outlawed. The reports of the Congressional committees recommending the adoption of the resolution indicate clearly enough that such was its purpose. They give no hint that more was intended! $ee Sen. Rep. No. 99, 73d Cong., 1st Sess.; H. R. Rep. No. 169, 73d Cong., 1st Sess.

    The recitals of the Joint Resolution declare that it is aimed at “the holding of or dealing in gold” and the “provisions of obligations which purport to give the obligee a right to require payment in gold or a particular kind of coin or currency of the United States, or in an amount in money of the United States measured thereby.” No other purpose is suggested. The enacting part of the resolution proscribes “every provision . . . which purports to give the obligee a right to require payment in gold or a particular kind of coin or currency, or in an amount in money of the United States measured thereby,” and declares “Every obligation, heretofore or hereafter incurred, whether or not any such provision is contained therein or made with respect thereto, shall be *263discharged upon payment, dollar for dollar, in any coin or currency which at the time of payment is legal tender . . “Obligation,” it states,' “means an obligation . . . payable in money of the United States.” Thus the resolution proclaims that it is aimed at gold clauses and declares, if language is to be taken in its plain and most obvious sense, that provisions requiring payment in gold dollars or, measured hy gold are illegal and that every promise or obligation “payable in money of the United States” (not in guilders) shall be discharged “dollar for dollar” in legal tender currency.

    To arrive at the conclusion that the resolution compels the present bondholders to accept dollars instead of the guilders for which they have contracted, it is necessary to say that “obligation,” which the Joint Resolution defines as obligation “payable in money of the United States” and requires to be discharged “dollar for dollar” in legal tender, includes the obligation payable in guilders. This difficulty is bridged by recourse to a major operation of statutory reconstruction. It is said that “obligation” means, not the- obligation or promise which is defined by the resolution as that “payable in money of the United States” and in which the gold clause provision is “contained” and “with respect” to which the provision is “made,” but includes all obligations, although not dis-chargeable in money of the .United ^States or in gold, which may be written into the instrument or document containing alternative promises, one of which is to pay in dollars. The “obligation” of the resolution “with respect” to which the gold clause is “made” is thus treated as synonymous with the instrument containing the multiple obligations, and all the provisions in it (not alone the promise to pay dollars) are now held to be dischargeable in dollars merely because one of the alternative promises “contained” a provision payable in “money of the United States,” although the bondholder is entitled by his contract to demand performance of a promise to pay guild*264ers not measured by gold. Thus, starting with a resolution avowedly directed at gold clauses, we are brought to the extraordinary conclusion that a promise to pay foreign currency is void if expressed in an instrument containing an alternative promise to pay in money of the United States whether of gold standard or not.

    The argument is not persuasive, because it rests both upon a strained and unnatural construction of the resolution and upon an assumption that there was a Congressional policy to strike down provisions for the alternative discharge of dollar obligations by payment in foreign currency not tied to gold, which finds no support in the language of the Joint Resolution or its legislative history. It seems fair to suppose that if Congress proposed to end all possibility of creating an international market for bonds payable-in dollars or alternatively abroad in foreign currencies, both without gold value, it would have given some more explicit indication of that purpose than is exhibited by the Joint Resolution. Even if we assume that Congress would have struck down such alternative currency clauses had it considered the m'atter, we are not free to do what Congress might have done but did not, or what we may think it ought to have done to lessen the rigors of our own currency devaluation for those who had made contracts for payment abroad in foreign currency without gold value.

    In any case it seems plain that if Congress had made the attempt it would not have chosen to do so in terms which, if the Court’s construction of the Joint Resolution be accepted, are broad enough to strike down every conceivable provision for payment in foreign currency, delivery of commodities, or performance of services as an alternative for a promise to pay dollars, whether of gold standard or not.

    The Chief Justice, MR. Justice McReynolds and Mr. Justice Butler concur in this opinion.

Document Info

Docket Number: Nos. 384, 495

Citation Numbers: 307 U.S. 247, 59 S. Ct. 847, 83 L. Ed. 1266, 1939 U.S. LEXIS 1071

Judges: Black, Stone, McReynolds, Butler

Filed Date: 5/22/1939

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 11/15/2024