Lehigh Valley Cooperative Farmers, Inc. v. United States , 82 S. Ct. 1168 ( 1962 )


Menu:
  • Mr. Justice Harlan

    delivered the opinion of the Court.

    Petitioners, operating milk processing plants in Pennsylvania, challenge the validity of certain “compensatory payment” provisions included in milk marketing orders affecting the New York-New Jersey area, which were promulgated by the Secretary of Agriculture under the authority granted him by § 8c of the Agricultural Marketing Agreement Act of 1937, 7 U. S. C. § 608c. That section permits the Secretary to issue regional regulations governing, in various enumerated respects, the marketing of certain agricultural commodities, among which is milk. This provision in question requires those who buy milk elsewhere and bring it into the region for sale as fluid milk to pay to the farmers who supply the region a fixed amount as a “compensatory payment.” This amount is measured by the difference between the minimum price set by the Market Administrator for fluid milk and the minimum price for surplus milk. The judgment of the Court of Appeals for the Third Circuit, 287 F. 2d 726, upholding the validity of the “compensatory payment” provision here under attack,1 conflicted with an earlier *78decision rendered by the Court of Appeals for the Second Circuit, Kass v. Brannan, 196 F. 2d 791. To resolve this conflict we granted certiorari. 366 U. S. 957.

    I.

    The General Scheme of Milk Regulation.

    The order around which the present controversy centers, now titled Milk Marketing Order No. 2, 7 CFR §§ 1002.1 et seq.,2 though somewhat more complex than others, is in its general outline representative of the pattern of regulation established by the Secretary for the promotion of orderly marketing conditions in the milk industry and the preservation of minimum prices for farmers. Pursuant to the authority granted by § 8c (5) (A),3 the Order classifies milk that is sold within *79the New York-New Jersey marketing area “in accordance with the form in which or the purpose for which it is used.” Milk that contains 3% to 5% butterfat — the usual proportion in ordinary liquid milk — and is sold for fluid consumption is assigned to Class I. Milk that is used for cream (sweet and sour), half and half, or milk drinks containing less than 3% or more than 5% butterfat is classified in Class II. The remainder — milk that is to be stored for a substantial period and used for dairy products such as butter and cheese — is grouped in Class III. 7 CFR § 1002.37.

    This classification reflects the relative prices usually commanded by the different forms of milk. Thus, highest prices are paid for milk used for fluid consumption, and the lowest for milk which is to be processed into butter and cheese. Since the supply of milk is always greater than the demands of the fluid-milk market, the excess must be channeled to the less desirable, lower-priced outlets. It is in order to avoid destructive competition among milk producers for the premium outlets that the statute authorizes the Secretary to devise a method whereby uniform prices are paid by milk handlers to producers for all milk received, regardless of the form in which *80it leaves the plant and its ultimate use. Adjustments are then made among the handlers so that each eventually pays out-of-pocket an amount equal to the actual utilization value of the milk he has bought.

    Under the Marketing Order here in question it is primarily the handlers whose plants are located within the marketing area and who regularly supply that area with fluid milk who are regulated. All handlers who receive or distribute milk within the area are required to submit monthly reports to the Market Administrator, listing the quantity of milk they have handled and the use for which it was sold. But only the handlers operating “pool plants” — i. e., plants which meet certain standards set out in 7 CFR §§ 1002.25-1002.29 4 — must pay the producers from whom they buy the uniform price set by the Administrator. This price is calculated each month on the basis of the reports that are submitted. After determining the minimum prices for each use classification pursuant to formulas set out in 7 CFR § 1002.40, the Administrator computes an average price for the “pool” milk handled during that month. This figure is reached by first multiplying the “pool” milk disposed of in each class by the established minimum price for that class, and then adding the products to the “compensatory payments” made for nonpool milk. After certain minor adjustments are made, this sum is divided by the total quantity of “pool” milk sold in the market during the month. The quotient is a “blend price.” With some adjustments to reflect transportation expenses, this uniform price must be paid to producers by all handlers maintaining “pool” plants. 7 CFR § 1002.66.

    *81Adjustments among handlers are made by way of a “Producer Settlement Fund,” into which each handler contributes the excess of his “use value” 5 over the uniform price paid by him to his producer. Handlers whose “use value” of the milk they purchase is less than the “blend price” they are required to pay may withdraw the difference from the fund. The net effect is that each handler pays for his milk at the price he would have paid had it been earmarked at the outset for the use to which it was ultimately put. But the farmer who produces the milk is protected from the effects of competition for premium outlets since he is automatically allotted a proportional share of each of the different “use” markets.

    HH PH

    The CompensatoRy Payment Provision.

    It will thus be seen that this system of regulation contemplates economic controls only over “pool-handler” plants since only such handlers are required to pay the “blend price” to their producers and to account to the Producer Settlement Fund. If limited to the provisions recounted above, the regulatory scheme would not affect milk brought into the New York-New Jersey marketing area by handlers who are primarily engaged in supplying some other market and whose producers are not located within the New York-New Jersey area. Some of the regional orders now in effect do not undertake any economic regulation of “outside” or “other source” milk.6 But it is quite obvious that under certain circumstances some regulation of such milk may be necessary. Accord*82ingly, § 8c (7) (D) of the Act, 7 IT. S. C. § 608c (7)(D), authorizes the Secretary to include in his regulating orders conditions that are incidental to terms expressly authorized by the statute, and that are “necessary to effectuate the other provisions of such order.”

    A handler who brings outside milk into a marketing area may disrupt the regulatory scheme in at least two respects:

    (1) Pool handlers in the marketing area who are required to pay the minimum class prices for their milk may find their selling prices undercut by those of nonpool handlers dealing in outside milk purchased at an unregulated price.
    (2) Producers in the marketing area, whose “blend price” depends on how much of the relatively constant fluid-milk demand they supply in a given month, may find the outside milk occupying a portion of the premium market, thus displacing the “pool” milk and forcing it into the less rewarding surplus uses, with the ultimate effect of diminishing the “blend price” payable to producers.

    In an effort to cope with these disruptive economic forces, the Secretary devised his “compensatory payment” plan. In essence the plan imposes special monetary exactions on handlers introducing “outside” milk for fluid consumption into a marketing area in months when there is a substantial surplus of milk on the market.7

    Of the 68 regional milk orders which establish market-wide pools,8 64 contain “compensatory payment” provi*83sions of one kind or another. The Order now before us is typical of 23 of these orders.9 The Order provides that a handler who brings “outside” milk into the New York-New Jersey area and sells it for fluid use must pay to the pool’s producers, through the Producer Settlement Fund, an amount equal to the difference between the minimum prices for the highest and for the lowest use classifications prevailing in that area. In other words, for each hundredweight of nonpool milk sold for Class I use in the New York-New Jersey area, a payment equal to the difference between Class I and Class III prices must be made by the seller to the Producer Settlement Fund.

    III.

    The Purpose and Effect of the Compensatory Payment.

    After the Court of Appeals for the Second Circuit had held the compensatory payment requirement in the New York-Newr Jersey Milk Marketing Order (then Order No. 27) to be a “penalty,” Kass v. Brannan, 196 F. 2d *84791, 795, the Secretary of Agriculture conducted extensive hearings to determine whether it should be retained. His findings, which appear at 18 Fed. Reg. 8444-8454, explain this requirement as the most satisfactory means of imposing "a suitable charge on such unpriced milk in an amount sufficient to neutralize, compensate for and eliminate the artificial economic advantage for non-pool milk which necessarily is created by the classified pricing and pooling of pool milk under the order.” Id,., at 8448. There seems little doubt that an assessment equal to the Class I-Class III differential would, in all but rare instances, nullify any competitive advantage that non-pool milk could have: only if the sum of the purchase price of the outside milk and the cost of its transportation to market were less than the Class III price would a handler find it profitable to bring such milk into the marketing area. But it must be obvious that this payment is wholly or partially “compensatory” — i. e., puts pool and nonpool milk “on substantially similar competitive positions at source” (ibid.) — only if the milk has been purchased at not more than the Class III price. If the purchase price of the nonpool milk exceeds the Class III price within the area, the effect of the fixed compensatory payment is to make it economically unfeasible for a handler to bring such milk into the marketing area.

    The Secretary of Agriculture’s determination that the Class I-Class III differential was the most suitable compensatory figure rested upon what was, in effect, an irrebuttable presumption that the nonpool milk was purchased at a rate commensurate with the value of “surplus” (Class III) milk. See 18 Fed. Reg., at 8448.10 *85That presumption was based in turn on the supposition that the nonpool milk could not have been worth more than the Class III price where purchased since it could not be shipped elsewhere for Class I use. But it must *86be apparent that it is only if the milk is denied access to other marketing areas or if a prohibitive payment is assessed on its use elsewhere that it will depreciate in value to Class III levels. For if the milk can be freely shipped elsewhere for fluid use or if it is purchased in an area where prices paid to producers are regulated, it will command a higher price.

    Indeed, the facts of the case now before us demonstrate the shortcomings of the Secretary’s reasoning. One of the petitioners, Suncrest Farms, Inc., purchases its milk in Pennsylvania under regulations established by the Pennsylvania Milk Control Commission. In September 1957, which was one of the months during which it sought to sell its milk in the New York-New Jersey Marketing Area, Suncrest was required to pay $6.40 per cwt. for the milk it purchased from dairy farmers in Pennsylvania. The Class I-Class III differential in the New York-New Jersey Marketing Area during that month was $2.78 per cwt. Thus, if the “compensatory payment” were assessed, Suncrest would actually be forced to pay $9.18 per cwt. for fluid milk sold in the area, while the handlers maintaining pool plants in the area would pay only the Class I price, which was $6.23 in August 1957,11

    If competitive parity among handlers of pool and nonpool milk were the only objective of the Secretary’s “compensatory” regulation, other marketing orders of the Secretary show that this result has been achieved without imposing unnecessary hardships, virtually “trade *87barriers” as in the instance just given,12 on the nonpool milk.13

    It is in considering the effect of the present compensatory payment provision on the pool producers, however, *88that the principal concern of the Secretary becomes quite apparent. As has been noted (p. 82, supra), the sale for fluid use of nonpoól milk in the marketing area displaces pool milk that might otherwise be used for this premium outlet. Since the market area’s “blend price” is computed only with reference to the pool milk, the effect of the entry of nonpool milk is to drive down the price that *89is paid to producers in the area. A close examination of the workings of the present compensatory payment provision reveals that its effect is to preserve for the benefit of the area’s producers the blend price that they would receive if all outside milk were physically excluded and they alone would supply the fluid-milk needs of the area. For every cwt. of pool milk that is forced into “surplus” use by the entry of nonpool milk, the handler introducing the outside milk is required to pay for the benefit of the area’s producers the difference between the value the pool milk would have had if the nonpool milk had never entered and the value it has once the nonpool milk is sold for fluid use.14 In effect, therefore, the nonpool milk is *90forced to subsidize the pool milk and insulate the pool milk from the competitive impact caused by the entry of outside milk. This was recognized by the Court of Appeals which held that such a compensatory payment *91was "designed to compensate the pool for the loss of the Class I fluid milk utilization and . . . protect the uniform blend price in the marketing area.” 287 F. 2d, at 730. It is only if the Secretary has been authorized by the statute to impose such economic trade barriers on the entry of milk into an area so as to protect the prices received by the pool producers that the present compensatory payment plan can be sustained as “necessary to effectuate” the expressly authorized provisions of this Order.

    IV.

    Section 8c (5) (G).

    Section 8c (5)(G) of the Act, however, taken in light of its legislative history, indicates that the regulation here imposed by the Secretary was of the sort that Congress intended to forbid. Section 8c (5) (G) provides:

    “No marketing agreement or order applicable to milk and its products in any marketing area shall prohibit or in any manner limit, in the case of the products of milk, the marketing in that area of any milk or product thereof produced in any production area in the United States.”

    This provision was first enacted into law as part of the Agricultural Adjustment Act of 1935, 49 Stat. 750, amending the Agricultural Adjustment Act of 1933, 48 Stat. 31. It was re-enacted as part of the Agricultural Marketing Agreement Act of 1937, 50 Stat. 246, which reaffirmed the marketing order provisions of the 1935 Act after the processing tax had been struck down as unconstitutional in United States v. Butler, 297 U. S. 1.

    Along with enumerating the powers granted to the Secretary of Agriculture so as to avoid the “delegation” problems brought to light by the then recent decision in Schechter v. United States, 295 U. S. 495, the Congress *92sought in 1935 to limit the Secretary’s powers so as to prevent him from establishing “trade barriers.” Midwestern legislators were particularly concerned over this possibility. When the reported bill which contained no provision like the present § 8c (5)(G) came to the floor of the House of Representatives, Representative Andre-sen of Minnesota suggested that the Secretary might use his powers to “stop the free flow in commerce ... of dairy products.” He received an assurance from Representative Jones, the Chairman of the House Committee on Agriculture, that the Secretary was not authorized to require anything more of milk coming into a marketing area than that it “comply with the same conditions which the farmers and distributors comply with in that region.” 79 Cong. Rec. 9462.15 An amendment to the bill clarifying this position was then offered by Representative *93Sauthoff of Wisconsin, 79 Cong. Rec. 9493,16 but no action Avas taken on that proposal.

    On the next day, Representative Andresen proposed from the floor of the House the forerunner to the present § 8c (5) (G). 79 Cong. Rec. 9572. His amendment took the folloAving form:

    “(g) No marketing agreement or order applicable to milk and its products in any marketing area shall prohibit the marketing in that area of any milk or product thereof produced in any production area in the United States.”

    There. Avas no objection to the addition of this language, Representative Jones remarking that “[i]t is simply clarifying.” Ibid. But Avhen Representative Sauthoff sought to change the amendment by substituting the Avords “limit or tend to limit” for “prohibit,” Representative Jones objected on the ground that necessary milk classification and minimum pricing for the protection of outside milk producers regularly supplying their OAvn marketing area Avould “tend to limit” the introduction of their milk into other areas.17 Ibid.

    *94The House bill, with the language added by Representative Andresen’s amendment, went to the Senate. Accompanying the bill to the floor was S. Rep. No. 1011, 74th Cong., 1st Sess., which stated, at p. 11:

    “To prevent assaults upon the price structure by the sporadic importation of milk from new producing areas, while permitting the orderly and natural expansion of the area supplying any market by the introduction of new producers or new producing areas, orders may provide that for the first 3 months *95of regular delivery, payments shall be made to producers not theretofore selling milk in the area covered by the order at the price fixed for the lowest use classification. This is the only limitation upon the entry of new producers — wherever located — into a market, and it can remain effective only for the specified 8-month period.” (Emphasis added.) 18

    In the Senate §8c(5)(G) was amended, without objection, 79 Cong. Rec. 11655, to read:

    “(G) No marketing agreement or order applicable to milk and its products in any marketing area shall prohibit or in any manner limit, except as provided for milk only in subsection (d), the marketing in that area of any milk or product thereof produced in any production area in the United States.” 19

    Section 8c (5)(G) emerged from conference in its present form. The conference report explained how the differences between the House and Senate versions were resolved (H. R. Rep. No. 1757, 74th Cong., 1st Sess. 21):

    “. . . The conference agreement retains the House provision with respect to prohibitions on marketing of both milk and products of milk. The conference agreement also denies the authority to limit in any manner the marketing in any area of milk products (butter, cheese, cream, etc.) produced anywhere in the United States. The language adopted by the conference agreement does not refer to milk, and so does not negative the applicability to milk, for use in fluid form or for manufacturing purposes, of the pro*96visions of the bill relating to milk, such as the provisions on price fixing, price adjustment, payments for milk, etc.”

    When the conference agreement came to the floor of the House, Representative Jones again explained what §8c(5)(G), when taken together with §8c(5)(D), meant (79 Cong. Rec. 13022):

    “Mr. SNELL. ... I do not understand exactly what this means, 'No marketing agreement or order applicable to milk and its products/ and so forth.
    “Mr. JONES. That simply applies to fluid milk. You cannot make any limitation at all on the amount of butter or cheese or milk products that are shipped from any one area to another, and the limitation that may be applied on milk is only such limitation as puts each area on an equality with the other areas after a certain period of about 2-1/2 months.
    “Mr. SNELL. How does that change the situation from the present law?
    “Mr. JONES. The provisions of this particular bill would enable that area to be protected from being swamped with fluid milk from the outside, bought at any old price. For instance, if you do not have the protection of this bill they would run into the same trouble they ran into in the New York milk cases, where they went into New Hampshire and bought milk at a lower price and came in and broke down your milk agreements. Under the provisions of this bill if a price were fixed in this particular area in New York, then if anyone bought milk from an outside area and brought it in he would be compelled to pay the producer the same price that was being paid the producers within the area and comply with *97all regulations and requirements of that area. For the first 2 months he would be required to take the manufacturer’s price.” (Emphasis added.)

    This history discloses that rather than being confined, as Judge Learned Hand suggested in Kass v. Brannan, 196 F. 2d, at 800, to practices aimed at the exclusion of cheese and other milk products from eastern markets, § 8c (5)(G) was compendiously intended to prevent the Secretary from setting up, under the guise of price-fixing regulation, any kind of economic trade barriers, whether relating to milk or its products. Whenever there was an attempt to broaden the language of subsection (G) to encompass “limitations” as well as “prohibitions,” those opposing it pointed only to the fact that “limit” might be read as including the type of price fixing covered by subsection (D) — i. e., allowing new pool producers only manufacturing-use prices for a limited period — or other attempts to put outside milk on an equal footing with pool milk. Although the words of § 8c (5)(G), “in any manner limit,” must be taken, in the context of their legislative history, as referring only to milk products, that history likewise makes it clear that as regards milk the word “prohibit” refers not merely to absolute or quota physical restrictions, but also encompasses economic trade barriers of the kind effected by the subsidies called for by this “compensatory payment” provision.

    V.

    The Invalidity op the PRESENT Compensatory Payment Provision.

    In light of the legislative history of § 8c (5)(G) we conclude that the compensatory payment provision of the New York-New Jersey Milk Marketing Order must fall as inconsistent with the policy expressed by Congress in *98that section.20 Because it conflicts with § 8c (5) (G), the payment provision cannot be justified under the general terms of § 8c (7) (D), which prevents the inclusion of conditions that are inconsistent with express statutory provisions. Nor is the compensatory payment clause saved by the circumstance that in some instances it may also fortuitously operate to put the handlers of pool and non-pool milk on a competitive par. As has been pointed out (note 13, supra), there are other means available to the Secretary for achieving this result, while affording protection to pool producers, without imposing almost insuperable trade restrictions on the entry of nonpooi milk into a marketing area.

    The Government contends that the effect of § 8c (5) (G) may not be considered by this Court since that provision was not cited by the petitioners in the administrative proceeding in the Department of Agriculture. But even on the Government’s premise that an unauthorized regulation should be upheld by this Court merely because the provision prohibiting it was not cited in the administrative proceeding in which it was attacked, this case presents no such instance. The administrative petition filed with the Department of Agriculture alleged that the effect of the compensatory payment clause amounted “to establishing tariffs or barriers interfering with the free flow of milk across state lines,” an obvious reference to the prohibition of § 8c (5)(G).

    In addition, the Government contends that the petitioners had the choice of joining the market-wide pool, in which case they would not have been subject to the compensatory payment provisions. Their election to stay *99out of the pool, it is argued, bars any attack on the consequences of their choice. However, such an “election” is surely illusory. The consequences of joining the pool would have been that petitioners would have been forced to pay the “blend price” to all their producers wherever located and account to the Producer Settlement Fund for all milk wherever sold. In these circumstances the election was not voluntary as in Booth Fisheries v. Industrial Comm’n, 271 U. S. 208, 211. It was coercive and, indeed, no election at all.

    Whether full regulation of the petitioners would be permissible under the Act is a question which we need not reach in this case. If the Secretary chooses to impose such regulation as a consequence of a handler’s introducing any milk into a marketing area, the validity of such a provision would involve considerations different from those now before us. With respect to these petitioners, however, and with regard to the regulation here in issue, we conclude that the action of the Secretary of Agriculture exceeded the powers entrusted to him by Congress.

    The Secretary of course remains free to protect, in any manner consistent with the provisions of the statute, the “blend price” in this or any other marketing area against economic consequences resulting from the introduction of outside milk. We do not now decide whether or not any new regulation directed to that end could be made to apply retrospectively, or whether, if it could be validly so applied, the presently impounded funds could be resorted to pro tanto in its effectuation. Cf. United States v. Morgan, 307 U. S. 183. “What further proceedings the Secretary may see fit to take in the light of our decision, or what determinations may be made by the District Court in relation to any such proceedings, are not matters which we should attempt to forecast or hypothetically to decide.” Morgan v. United States, 304 U. S. 1, 23, 26.

    *100The judgment of the Court of Appeals is reversed and the case is remanded to the District Court for further proceedings consistent with this opinion.

    It is so ordered.

    Mr. Justice Frankfurter took no part in the decision of this case. Mr. Justice White took no part in the consideration or decision of this case.

    The petitioners instituted this action challenging the validity of the compensatory payment provision by filing administrative petitions with the Secretary of Agriculture pursuant to § 8c (15) (A) of the Agricultural Marketing Agreement Act of 1937, 7 U. S. C. § 608c (15) (A). The Hearing Examiner sustained the petitioners’ *78contentions on the authority of Kass v. Brannan, 196 F. 2d 791, but the Judicial Officer, acting on behalf of the Secretary of Agriculture, dismissed the petitions.

    Petitioners then sought review of the Secretary's ruling in the District Court under § 8c (15) (B) of the Act. The review proceedings were consolidated with enforcement actions brought by the Government pursuant to § 8a (6) of the Act. The District Court, relying on Kass v. Brannan, supra, held that the payment provision was invalid. 183 F. Supp. 80. It was this decision that was reversed by the Court of Appeals. 287 F. 2d 726.

    A general reorganization of Chapter IX of Title 7 of the Code of Federal Regulations during the past year has resulted in redesignation of most of the milk marketing orders. The New York-New Jersey Order had previously been designated as Milk Marketing Order No. 27 and had been found at 7 CFR § 927. The section references and the contents of the regulations as quoted throughout this opinion are as they were in effect on January 1, 1962.

    Section 8c (5) (A), provides:

    “(5) Milk and its products; terms and conditions of orders.
    “In the case of milk and its products, orders issued pursuant to this section shall contain one or more of the following terms and condi*79tions, and (except as provided in subsection (7) of this section) no others:
    “(A) Classifying milk in accordance with the form in which or the purpose for which it is used, and fixing, or providing a method for fixing, minimum prices for each such use classification which all handlers shall pay, and the time when payments shall be made, for milk purchased from producers or associations of producers. Such prices shall be uniform as to all handlers, subject only to adjustments for (1) volume, market, and production differentials customarily applied by the handlers subject to such order, (2) the grade or quality of the milk purchased, and (3) the locations at which delivery of such milk, or any use classification thereof, is made to such handlers.” 7 U. S. C. § 608c (5) (A).

    These provisions establish certain performance requirements aimed at insuring that the plant continues to provide fluid milk to the marketing area even in periods of short supply. Thus, it is primarily the handlers whose main concern is the marketing area who qualify for the “pool.”

    “Use value” is the price the handler would have had to pay, at prevailing minimum rates, had he purchased his milk at a price reflecting its ultimate disposition.

    See 7 CFR §§ 1034 (Dayton-Springfield), 1037 (North Central Ohio), 1038 (Rockford-Freeport), 1074 (Southwest Kansas).

    The payment provision of 7 CFR § 1002.83 applies only in those months when the volume of milk sold for Class III use exceeds 15% of the total pool milk reported in the marketing area.

    The Act authorizes the establishment of either marketwide pools or individual handler pools. Since the latter require only that each handler pay uniform prices to all the producers from which he buys, but does not impose a uniformity requirement among the various *83handlers, there is no need for adjustments among handlers. Consequently, no compensatory payment provision is included in orders establishing individual handler pools. See 7 CFR §§ 1004 (Philadelphia), 1005 (Tri-State), 1010 (Wilmington), 1039 (Milwaukee), 1041 (Toledo), 1044 (Michigan Upper Peninsula), 1078 (North Central Iowa), 1096 (Northern Louisiana), 1097 (Memphis), 1102 (Fort Smith), 1129 (Austin-Waco), 1130 (Corpus Christi), 1134 (Western Colorado).

    Compare 7 CFR §§ 1001.65 (Greater Boston), 1003.62 (Washington, D. C.), 1006.65 (Springfield, Mass.), 1007.65 (Worcester), 1008.54 (Wheeling), 1009.54 (Clarksburg, W. Va.), 1011.62 (Appalachian), 1014.46 (Southeastern New England), 1015.46 (Connecticut), 1016.62 (Upper Chesapeake Bay), 1030.61 (Chicago), 1031.70 (b) (South Bend-La Porte-Elkhart), 1036.84 (b) (Northeastern Ohio), 1048.54 (Greater Youngstown-Warren), 1061.54 (St. Joseph), 1068.70 (b) (Minneapolis-St. Paul), 1071.62 (b) (Neosho Valley), 1072.55 (Sioux Falls-Mitchell), 1106.55 (Oklahoma), 1125.70 (Puget Sound), 1126.70 (d) (North Texas), 1133.70 (b) (Inland Empire).

    “As stated earlier herein, all milk which is established to be primarily associated with the New York milk marketing area under the standards prescribed by the order is included in the New York pool. Conversely, the non-pool milk which enters the marketing area for fluid use originates from plants which are not sufficiently associated *85with the New York market to have their milk in the pool. Such plants have their primary interests in other fluid markets or specialized manufacturing uses and frequently have more milk than is required for these primary purposes. It is this surplus milk at non-pool plants which can be 'dumped' into the New York market for fluid use, provided only that the plant and the milk [have] marketing area health approval. The operator of such a non-pool plant has a choice of using the excess milk for surplus uses (ordinarily in the manufacture of various milk products) or of sending it to the New York marketing area for fluid uses. In making this decision he will compare the respective net returns to him for this surplus milk and will naturally select the fluid alternative, for it will yield the greater return. In the absence of classified pricing, his cost, at source, for the excess milk remains exaetty the same whether he uses it for surplus disposition or for fluid use. The pool plant operator on the other hand has no such advantage for he pays a higher classified price, at source, if he sells the milk in the market area for fluid use (Class I-A or II) than if he disposes of it for surplus manufacturing uses (Class III).

    “If this artificial advantage in favor of surplus non-pool milk at the plant of origin is to be effectively removed, as it must be, the milk must be treated and evaluated for what it actually is, namely surplus milk in the milkshed. If New York marketing area disposition were not available for this surplus, the non-pool handler could derive from it only its surplus value. This surplus value is its true value or 'opportunity cost’ and such surplus value should be used as the subtrahend in the formula for compensation payments on non-pool milk from plants not subject to a Federal order.

    “The Class III price under the New York order is the class price which is payable, at source, for pool milk under the New York order when used for most surplus uses. It is expressly designed to fix a proper classified value, at source, for surplus milk. The Class III price closely approximates the amount paid in the Northeast to farmers not under the New York order for so much of their milk as is used for general manufacture.

    “It is therefore a dependable indicator of the value of surplus milk at source. If a non-pool handler, for his own reasons, chooses to pay *86more than its true market value, at source, for surplus milk which he sends to the New York area, the pool should not underwrite this unnecessary cost, particularly since the premium can be used to outbid pool handlers for milk, as previously shown.”

    The fact that petitioners were paying more for their milk than the Class I price in the New York-New Jersey Marketing Area leaves no room for any suggestion that they will be receiving a “windfall” if it is ultimately adjudged that they are entitled to have returned the full amount of their compensatory payments.

    The total amount of the compensatory payments involved in this litigation, embracing a period of approximately four years, was some $617,000 as to Lehigh Valley and $108,000 as to Suncrest.

    Several of the marketing orders make the compensatory payment, equal the difference between the Class I price in the marketing area and the actual cost of the nonpool milk. See 7 CFR §§ 1042.60 (Muskegon), 1128.62 (b) (Central West Texas). In some marketing areas the handler who deals in nonpool milk is permitted to elect each month between paying the fluid milk-surplus use differential and paying the difference between his actual cost and the minimum regional price for Class I milk. See 7 CFR §§ 1013.62 (Southeastern Florida), 1033.61 (Greater Cincinnati), 1035.63 (Columbus, Ohio), 1040.66 (Southern Michigan), 1043.84 (Upstate Michigan), 1045.83 (Northeastern Wisconsin), 1047.62 (Fort Wayne), 1064.61 (Greater Kansas City), 1065.62 (Nebraska-Western Iowa), 1067.61 (Ozarks), 1069.62 (Duluth-Superior), 1073.62 (Wichita), 1094.62 (New Orleans), 1098.92 (Nashville), 1103.62 (Central Mississippi), 1105.62 (Mississippi Delta), 1107.61 (Mississippi Gulf Coast), 1131.62 (Central Arizona), 1135.62 (Colorado Springs-Pueblo), 1136.62 (Great Basin), 1137.62 (Eastern Colorado).

    Other marketing orders, applicable in some areas, assess a compensatory payment equal to the difference between the “blend price” paid in the area for pool milk and the Class I price, thus treating the handler of nonpool milk as if he were a member of the pool with respect to such milk as he introduced into the marketing area.

    Where this differential is accepted as the measure of the compensatory payment it is done only in those months when the surplus is lowest. In the spring and summer months the fluid milk-surplus use differential is exacted. See 7 CFR §§ 1032.55 (b) (Suburban St. Louis, August-February), 1046.55 (b) (Ohio Valley, August-March), 1049.55 (b) (Indianapolis, August-March), 1062.55 (b) (St. Louis, August-February), 1063.63 (b) (Quad Cities-Dubuque, July-November), 1066.57 (a) (Sioux City, August-February), 1070.63 (b) (Cedar Rapids-Iowa City, July-November), 1075.63 (b) (Black Hills, July-March), 1076.63 (b) (Eastern South Dakota, July-February), 1079.63 (b) (Des Moines, July-March), 1090.54 (b) (Chattanooga, August-February), 1095.70 (e) (2) (Louisville-Lexington, October-De*88cember), 1099.62 (a) (Paducah, August-March), 1101.93 (b) (Knoxville, August-February), 1104.53 (b) (Red River Valley, August-January), 1108.54 (b) (Central Arkansas, August-February), 1127.65 (b) (San Antonio, January and August), 1132.63 (b) (Texas Panhandle, July-February).

    The latter method treats the handler of nonpool milk who buys at a price in excess of the blend price as if he were a member of the pool since a handler in the pool may, if he chooses, pay his producer more than the “blend price” set by the Market Administrator, see Stark v. Wickard, 321 U. S: 288, 291, but must still account to the Producer Settlement Fund as if he had paid only the “blend price.” By treating nonpool milk in the same manner, the Secretary might be able to justify a compensatory payment equal to the difference between the nonpool milk's “use value” and the “blend price,” though we do not decide the question. See generally Hutt, Restrictions on the Free Movement of Fluid Milk Under Federal Milk Marketing Orders, 37 U. Det. L. J. 525, 564-577 (1960).

    The suggestion that a nonpool handler would be given-a competitive advantage under either of these methods because, in the words of the Judicial Officer, he does not have “to equalize his utilization” as do pool handlers is demonstrably unsound. Insofar as the handlers’ sale of milk is concerned, neither pool nor nonpool handlers are required to share or “equalize” their proceeds with others. To the extent that this contention relates to the handlers’ 'purchase of milk and is meant to suggest that nonpool handlers will find it easier to buy milk because they will be able to pay higher prices to their producers, the exaction of a Class I-blend price payment would effectively discourage purchases in excess of the blend price (which is what the pool’s producers are paid). And the assertion that the pool “carries the surplus burden for outside handlers” is based on the same mistaken reasoning as underlies the Secretary’s determination to retain the Class I-Class III payment after Kass v. Brannan, supra. See pp. 84-86, supra.

    A highly simplified illustration serves to clarify this effect: If the Class I price on a given date is $6 per cwt. and the Class III price is $3 per cwt., and if 2,000 cwt. are consumed as fluid milk and another 2,000 cwt. are produced by the dairy farmers in the area and utilized for surplus uses, the computation of the blend price would be as follows:

    Table A.
    Class 1. 2,000 x 6.00 equals 12,000
    Class III. 2,000 x 3.00 equals 6,000
    Totals. 4,000 at 18,000
    Blend Price. $4.50

    If 500 cwt. are then brought in from the outside as nonpool milk and sold for Class I use, 500 cwt. of the pool milk will drop into Class III (since the fluid milk demand remains relatively constant):

    Table B.
    Class 1. 1,500 x 6.00 equals 9,000
    Class III. 2,500 x 3.00 equals 7,500
    Totals. 4,000 at 16,500
    Blend Price. $4,125

    The producers in the pool would thereby be receiving $.375 less per cwt. than had the nonpool milk stayed out altogether. By distributing to them (through the exaction made of nonpool handlers) the difference between Class I and Class III prices multiplied by the *90amount of nonpool milk sold in the area as Class I, that deficit is restored. Thus,

    Table C.
    (Nonpool milk sold as Class I) x (Class I minus Class III) equals
    (Loss to pool by displacement of Class I outlet) or
    500 x 3.00 equals 1,500
    1,500 divided by 4,000 ewt. equals .375 per ewt.

    The Secretary’s formula, therefore, precisely accomplishes the restoring to the pool’s producers whatever they have lost by reason of the occupation of their Class I outlet by the nonpool milk.

    It should be noted that the actual computation of the blend price, as set out in 7 CFR § 1002.66, achieves this same result in an indirect fashion. Instead of computing the blend price without reference to any nonpool milk, the Secretary’s formula includes the compensatory payments within the list of minimum-price obligations that are added in determining the total proceeds for milk sold within the area. 7 CFR § 1002.66 (c). But the blend price is then computed by dividing this sum by the amount of “milk delivered by producers,” i. e., pool milk. Consequently, the actual computation of the uniform price under the above illustration would be as follows:

    Table D.
    Class 1. 1,500 x 6.00 equals 9,000
    Class III. 2,500 x 3.00 equals 7,500
    Compensatory payments (non-pool milk). 500 x 3.00 equals 1,500
    Totals (pool milk). 4,000 at 18,000
    Blend Price. $4.50

    The funds paid into the Producer Settlement Fund by the handlers dealing in nonpool milk are then available to the pool handlers, whose credits from the Fund will be larger to the extent that they have been forced to pay a higher blend price.

    “Mr. ANDRESEN. Is there anything in the milk section of the bill which gives the Secretary authority to set up trade barriers and stop the free flow in commerce throughout the United States of dairy products?

    “Mr. JONES. No. There is nothing in the bill that would authorize that. The Secretary may require that in crossing from one region to another that they comply with the same conditions which the farmers and distributors comply with in that region.

    “Mr. ANDRESEN. That is, sanitary regulations?

    “Mr. JONES. Sanitary and other uniform regulations; but he cannot set wp any trade barriers which would keep them, out.

    “Mr. ANDRESEN. A great many Members have inquired about that feature, and I just wanted the gentleman to bring that out.

    “Mr. JONES. The amendments require a uniform price and uniform set of conditions and fair distribution. In the first place, I do not believe we could give authority to set up these barriers. In the second place, the bill does not do that. It simply enables them to have a program in one of these regions, and in developing these orders which the Secretary issues, he uses the word ‘region’ wherever possible. Those on the outside must come into that.” (Emphasis added.)

    The proposed amendment read:

    "Sec. — (b) No marketing agreement, order, or regulation shall contain any term or provision which will tend to result in preventing or hindering an)' agricultural commodity or product thereof produced in any region or area of the United States from being brought into or sold in any other such region or area, or shall have the effect of subsidizing the production or sale of any agricultural commodity or product 1 hereof in any such region or area, in such a manner that such commodity or product thereof AA'ill tend to be sold in such other region or area at prices AA'hich will tend to depress prices therein of such commodity or product thereof.”

    “Mr. JONES. Mr. Chairman, the adoption of the amendment of the gentleman from Wisconsin Avould absolutely wreck the AA'hole milk program. In order to get away from the terrific conditions that have prevailed in the milk industry there is provided in the bill *94authority to fix a minimum price to producers. That, at least in a measure, would limit or tend to limit shipment, and yet the gentleman, I am sure, does not want to interfere with the price to producers. Then it is a universal custom in the marketing of milk to classify milk. This, in a way, is a limitation. . . .

    “Mr. BOILEAU. . . . Mr. Chairman, I should like to ask the distinguished chairman of the committee if in his opinion there is anything in this bill that gives to the Secretary of Agriculture or to anyone else any power to restrict the free flow of milk or any other commodity between the various States?

    “Mr. JONES. No; there is nothing in it that will do that. The only tendency is to make all sections comply with the same rules.

    “Mr. HULL. . . . Mr. Chairman, if there is nothing in this bill which would authorize the Secretary of Agriculture or any subordinate so to limit transportation or shipment of dairy products from one State into another, then the amendment of the gentleman from Minnesota as amended by the amendment of the gentleman from Wisconsin [Mr. Sauthoff] can do no harm.

    "The three States of Minnesota, Iowa, and Wisconsin, produce about 45 percent of the butter made in this country and we are-interested in this matter of the shipment of dairy products to other States.

    “Mr. JONES. Mr. Chairman, will the gentleman yield?

    “Mr. HULL. I yield.

    “Mr. JONES. Would the gentleman object to the requirement that Chicago dealers pay the Wisconsin producer a minimum price?

    “Mr. HULL. Not at all.

    “Mr. JONES. That certainly would tend to limit.”

    The "3-month period” provision here referred to is the present § 8c (5) (D) which authorizes the Secretary to set the surplus-use price as the price to be paid to any new producer who enters the pool. In the final version of the Act the introductory period was reduced to two months.

    "Subsection (d)” is § 8c (5)(D). See note 18, supra.

    While we need not reach the point, we would have difficulty in concluding, as did the Court of Appeals for the Second Circuit in Kass v. Brannan, supra, that the provisions of § 8c (5) (A) precluded, in themselves, the promulgation of the present compensatory payment provision.

Document Info

Docket Number: 79

Citation Numbers: 8 L. Ed. 2d 345, 82 S. Ct. 1168, 370 U.S. 76, 1962 U.S. LEXIS 1158

Judges: Harlan, Black, Frankfurter, White

Filed Date: 6/4/1962

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 10/19/2024