Mueller Comercial De Mexico, S. De R.L. De C v. v. United States , 753 F.3d 1227 ( 2014 )


Menu:
  •   United States Court of Appeals
    for the Federal Circuit
    ______________________
    MUELLER COMERCIAL DE MEXICO, S. DE R.L.
    DE C.V. AND SOUTHLAND PIPE NIPPLES CO.,
    INC.,
    Plaintiffs-Appellants,
    v.
    UNITED STATES,
    Defendant-Appellee,
    AND
    TMK IPSCO TUBULARS AND
    ALLIED TUBE AND CONDUIT,
    Defendants-Appellees,
    AND
    UNITED STATES STEEL CORPORATION,
    Defendant-Appellee.
    ______________________
    2013-1391
    ______________________
    Appeal from the United States Court of International
    Trade in No. 11-CV-0319, Judge Leo M. Gordon.
    ______________________
    Decided: May 29, 2014
    ______________________
    2                      MUELLER COMERCIAL DE MEXICO   v. US
    YOHAI BAISBURD, White & Case LLP, of Washington,
    DC, argued for plaintiffs-appellants. With him on the
    brief were DAVID E. BOND, JAY C. CAMPBELL and TING-
    TING KAO.
    DOUGLAS G. EDELSCHICK, Trial Attorney, Commercial
    Litigation Branch, Civil Division, United States Depart-
    ment of Justice, of Washington, DC, argued for defendant-
    appellee United States. With him on the brief were
    STUART F. DELERY, Assistant Attorney General, JEANNE
    E. DAVIDSON, Director, and FRANKLIN E. WHITE, JR.,
    Assistant Director.     Of counsel was NATHANIEL J.
    HALVORSON, Attorney, Office of the Chief Counsel for
    Import Administration, United States Department of
    Commerce, of Washington, DC.
    ROGER B. SCHAGRIN, Schagrin Associates, of Washing-
    ton, DC, argued for defendants-appellees TMK IPSCO
    Tubulars, et al. With him on the brief was JOHN W.
    BOHN.
    ELLEN J. SCHNEIDER, Skadden Arps, Slate, Meagher
    & Flom LLP, of Washington, DC, argued for defendant-
    appellee United States Steel Corporation. With her on
    the brief were ROBERT LIGHTHIZER and JEFFREY D.
    GERRISH. Of counsel were JAMES C. HECHT and LUKE A.
    MEISNER.
    ______________________
    Before NEWMAN, DYK, and TARANTO, Circuit Judges.
    MUELLER COMERCIAL DE MEXICO   v. US                      3
    DYK, Circuit Judge.
    Plaintiffs Mueller Comercial de Mexico, S. de R.L. de
    C.V., and Southland Pipe Nipples Company, Inc. 1 (collec-
    tively, “Mueller”) appeal from a decision of the Court of
    International Trade sustaining the United States De-
    partment of Commerce’s (“Commerce”) antidumping
    determination. We vacate and remand.
    BACKGROUND
    The Tariff Act of 1930 (the “Act”), as amended, per-
    mits Commerce to levy antidumping duties on goods “sold
    in the United States at less than . . . fair value.” 19
    U.S.C. § 1673. Antidumping duty orders are issued for
    imported merchandise that is sold in the United States
    below its fair value and materially injures or threatens to
    injure a domestic industry. 
    Id. An antidumping
    duty
    reflects the amount by which the “normal value” of a
    product (typically, the home market price—the price of
    the merchandise when sold for consumption in the export-
    ing country), 19 U.S.C. § 1677b(1), exceeds the “export
    price” of the merchandise. 19 U.S.C. §§ 1673, 1677(35)(A).
    This difference is called the dumping margin. The impo-
    sition of the antidumping duty, equal to the dumping
    margin, is intended to ensure that merchandise is not sold
    in the United States below its fair value.
    Commerce periodically reviews and reassesses anti-
    dumping duties imposed in earlier proceedings. 19 U.S.C.
    § 1675(a). On November 2, 1992, Commerce published an
    antidumping duty order on certain circular welded non-
    1     Southland Pipe Nipples Company, Inc. is
    Mueller’s importer-of-record for direct sales in the United
    States and is a wholly-owned subsidiary of Mueller Indus-
    tries, Inc.
    4                      MUELLER COMERCIAL DE MEXICO   v. US
    alloy steel pipe from Mexico. On November 2, 2009,
    Commerce published a notice of opportunity to request an
    administrative review of the antidumping duty order.
    Commerce received requests for administrative review
    from appellant Mueller; Tuberia Nacional, S.A. de C.V.
    (“TUNA”); and Ternium Mexico, S.A. de C.V. (“Ternium”),
    and from defendant-appellees Allied Tube and Conduit
    Corporation and TMK IPSCO Tubulars.
    On December 23, 2009, Commerce initiated an anti-
    dumping administrative review concerning the period
    spanning from November 1, 2008, to October 31, 2009,
    issuing questionnaires to three mandatory respondents:
    (1) Mueller, an exporter, which purchased the majority of
    its subject merchandise from TUNA and Ternium, (2)
    TUNA and (3) Ternium, both producers of subject mer-
    chandise. TUNA’s review was rescinded (because there
    were no direct shipments), and Ternium opted not to
    participate in its own margin calculation. As a result,
    Commerce drew an adverse inference against Ternium
    pursuant to 19 U.S.C. § 1677e(b), assigning an adverse
    facts available (“AFA”) dumping margin of 48.33 percent,
    “which is the highest calculated transaction-specific
    margin from the most recently-completed administrative
    review of this antidumping duty order in which a rate was
    calculated.” J.A. 63 (Preliminary Results). Ternium’s
    dumping margin is not at issue in this appeal.
    For Commerce to calculate Mueller’s antidumping
    rate, it was required to determine the difference between
    the “normal value” of Mueller’s goods (typically “home
    market” price) and the “export price” at which Mueller’s
    goods were sold in the United States.           19 U.S.C.
    §§ 1677(35)(A), 1677b(a). The “normal value” is ordinarily
    the price at which the goods were first sold for consump-
    tion in the exporting country—in this case, in Mexico. 
    Id. § 1677b(a)(1)(B)(i).
    Here, Mueller had sufficient volume
    of home market sales such that they could be used to
    MUELLER COMERCIAL DE MEXICO    v. US                      5
    calculate “normal value.” See 
    id. § 1677b(a)(1)(B)(ii)(II).
    However, where an exporter’s home market price is less
    than the cost of production for the goods it sells, Com-
    merce “may” disregard the below cost sales to calculate
    “normal value.” 
    Id. § 1677b(b)(1).
    Therefore, Commerce
    must determine the cost of production of the subject
    merchandise. 
    Id. § 1677b(b)(3).
    Such production costs are
    normally “calculated based on the records of the exporter
    or producer of the merchandise, if such records are kept in
    accordance with the generally accepted accounting princi-
    ples of the exporting country . . . and reasonably reflect
    the costs associated with the production and sale of the
    merchandise.” 
    Id. § 1677b(f)(1)(A).
    If the cost of produc-
    tion is greater than the home market price, home market
    sales below production cost may be disregarded in calcu-
    lating the normal value. 2          
    Id. §§ 1677b(b)(1)(A);
    1677b(b)(2)(C).
    Although Mueller fully cooperated with Commerce’s
    review, Mueller did not possess all of the production cost
    information necessary to calculate its antidumping mar-
    gin. See 19 U.S.C. § 1677b(b)(3). To calculate cost of
    production, Commerce requested data directly from
    Mueller’s two principal suppliers, TUNA and Ternium.
    TUNA fully cooperated with the data requests, report-
    ing cost of production on a product-specific basis. Howev-
    er, Ternium did not “provide detailed product-specific
    calculations that allocate[d] costs based on product di-
    mensions.” J.A. 47 (Memorandum from Mark Flessner,
    Case Analyst, Dep’t of Commerce, to Richard Weible,
    Office Director, Dep’t of Commerce, Certain Circular
    2   Production cost data is also used to calculate “con-
    structed value” in lieu of home market sales. 19 U.S.C.
    § 1677b(e).
    6                      MUELLER COMERCIAL DE MEXICO   v. US
    Welded Non-Alloy Steel Pipe from Mexico: Use of [AFA]
    for Final Results 2 (June 13, 2011)) (“AFA Mem.”) (inter-
    nal quotation marks omitted). Ternium stated that it did
    not provide the data because it was not “readily availa-
    ble.” As a result, Commerce did not have the data neces-
    sary to calculate margins that took into account cost
    differences associated with the different physical charac-
    teristics of the goods.
    For its preliminary analysis, Commerce simply relied
    on the submitted data and calculated a weighted-average
    dumping margin of 4.81 percent for Mueller. But because
    Ternium did not submit necessary cost data before the
    time for a final determination, in making the final calcu-
    lations, Commerce used “facts otherwise available” to
    calculate Mueller’s margin under 19 U.S.C. § 1677e(a) of
    the statute. Specifically, Commerce concluded that the
    production costs of the goods Mueller acquired from
    Ternium (data that was unavailable) were related to
    acquisition costs (data that was available). Commerce
    identified the three sales transactions between TUNA and
    Mueller made at the greatest discount to Mueller—where
    Mueller’s acquisition cost was the furthest below TUNA’s
    production cost. Commerce then inferred that all of
    Ternium’s pipe that was sold to Mueller involved this
    discount for acquisition cost. This enabled Commerce to
    calculate Ternium’s cost of production from Mueller’s cost
    of acquisition from Ternium. Although there were other
    sales transactions between TUNA and Mueller that were
    not discounted as significantly, Commerce chose not to
    use that data. In its Final Results, Commerce used data
    from the three transactions to calculate a new weighted-
    average dumping rate for Mueller of 19.81 percent.
    On August 22, 2011, Mueller filed suit in the Court of
    International Trade (“Trade Court”) seeking to overturn
    Commerce’s Final Results, noting that Mueller had fully
    cooperated and alleging that Commerce’s application of
    MUELLER COMERCIAL DE MEXICO      v. US                    7
    “Ternium’s AFA to its calculation of the margin for
    Mueller,” despite Mueller’s full cooperation with Com-
    merce’s requests, was improper. J.A. 197. Mueller ar-
    gued that, instead, Commerce should have calculated
    production costs using the entire TUNA data set. 3 The
    Trade Court found that Commerce’s application of facts
    available was reasonable, and sustained the Final Re-
    sults. Mueller appealed. We have jurisdiction pursuant
    to 28 U.S.C. § 1295(a)(5).
    DISCUSSION
    I
    As discussed, Mueller’s antidumping rate was based
    on the difference between the “normal value” of the sub-
    ject merchandise (typically, the “home market” price) and
    the “export price” of the goods sold in the United States.
    See 19 U.S.C. § 1677(35)(A). But Mueller’s data alone
    could not be used to determine whether its home market
    sales were below the cost of production for the goods.
    Commerce requested data from Mueller’s two primary
    suppliers, TUNA and Ternium, to calculate the cost of
    production for the subject merchandise. See 19 U.S.C.
    § 1677b(b)(3). Ternium did not provide product-specific
    cost data that would enable Commerce to calculate Terni-
    um’s cost of production for each product, failing to account
    for different costs based on nominal pipe size and pipe
    wall thickness. Therefore, Commerce did not have suffi-
    cient information to calculate Mueller’s antidumping rate.
    When Commerce is missing necessary data, the stat-
    ute provides two options to secure data that can be used
    3   Mueller argued alternatively that Commerce
    should have used Mueller’s acquisition costs from Terni-
    um or extrapolated from Ternium’s limited cost data.
    8                        MUELLER COMERCIAL DE MEXICO   v. US
    as a substitute for the missing information. See 19 U.S.C.
    § 1677e. The first is “facts otherwise available.” The
    statute provides:
    (a) In general
    If—
    (1) necessary information is not available
    on the record, or
    (2) an interested party or any other per-
    son—
    (A) withholds information that has
    been requested by [Commerce]
    under this subtitle,
    (B) fails to provide such infor-
    mation by the deadlines for sub-
    mission of the information or in
    the form and manner requested . . .
    [Commerce] shall . . . use the facts otherwise
    available in reaching the applicable determination
    under this subtitle.
    19 U.S.C. § 1677e(a) (emphases added). The second is the
    “adverse facts available” approach. In this respect, the
    statute provides:
    (b) Adverse Inferences
    If [Commerce] finds that an interested party has
    failed to cooperate by not acting to the best of its
    ability to comply with a request for information
    from [Commerce], [Commerce], in reaching the
    applicable determination under this subtitle, may
    use an inference that is adverse to the interests of
    that party in selecting from the facts otherwise
    available. Such adverse inference may include re-
    liance on information derived from—
    MUELLER COMERCIAL DE MEXICO       v. US                    9
    (1) the petition,
    (2) a final determination in the investiga-
    tion under this subtitle,
    (3) any previous review under section 1675
    of this title or determination under section
    1675b of this title, or
    (4) any other information placed on the
    record.
    19 U.S.C. § 1677e(b) (emphasis added).
    These two subsections have different purposes. Sub-
    section 1677e(a) (“subsection (a)”) may be used whether or
    not any party has failed to cooperate fully with the agency
    in its inquiry. See Zhejiang DunAn Hetian Metal Co. v.
    United States, 
    652 F.3d 1333
    , 1346 (Fed. Cir. 2011)
    (“‘[T]he mere failure of a respondent to furnish requested
    information—for any reason—requires Commerce to
    resort to other sources of information to complete the
    factual record . . . .’” (emphasis added) (quoting Nippon
    Steel v. United States, 
    337 F.3d 1373
    , 1381 (Fed. Cir.
    2003))). In contrast, subsection 1677e(b) (“subsection (b)”)
    authorizes an inference adverse to an interested party
    when “Commerce makes the separate determination that
    [the party] has failed to cooperate by not acting to the best
    of its ability.” 
    Id. (quoting Nippon
    Steel, 337 F.3d at
    1381
    ) (internal quotation marks omitted). In this case,
    Mueller is a cooperating party, while Ternium is not.
    II
    Initially we note that there is no contention here that
    Commerce, acting primarily under subsection (a) in
    setting a margin for Mueller, erred in using TUNA’s data
    as a surrogate for Ternium’s missing data. Mueller’s
    primary complaint is that Commerce limited its analysis
    to a small and unfavorable subset of the TUNA data. As
    stated above, Commerce used the three highest-margin
    10                     MUELLER COMERCIAL DE MEXICO    v. US
    transactions instead of taking the total number of trans-
    actions from the TUNA cost of production data, which
    resulted in a higher normal value, and therefore, a higher
    dumping margin. Mueller argues Commerce arbitrarily
    cherry-picked the data to achieve this higher dumping
    margin.
    We separately address the two rationales that Com-
    merce used to justify its approach. Commerce relied on
    the two rationales in combination, not on either one as an
    independent ground. If one fails, as we conclude it does,
    Commerce’s ruling cannot stand. SEC v. Chenery Corp.,
    
    332 U.S. 194
    , 196–97 (1947).
    First, Commerce concluded that the use of the adverse
    inference to calculate Ternium’s surrogate production cost
    actually yielded the most accurate calculation of Mueller’s
    antidumping rate. 4
    4   See J.A. 40 (Memorandum from Christian Marsh,
    Deputy Assistant Sec’y, Dep’t of Commerce, to Ronald K.
    Lorentzen, Deputy Assistant Sec’y, Dep’t of Commerce,
    Issues and Decision Memorandum for Final Results of
    Antidumping Duty Administrative Review: Certain
    Circular Welded Non-Alloy Steel Pipe from Mexico 16
    (June 13, 2011)) (“Decision Memorandum”) (“[Commerce]
    has selected from the facts otherwise available, the best
    information to use in place of Ternium’s withheld data.”
    (emphasis added)); J.A. 44 (Decision Mem. 20) (“The
    Department considers that if it ignores the fact that
    Ternium chose to withhold necessary information and
    fails to apply an adverse inference in the selection of the
    facts available, the resulting dumping margin would not
    reflect accurately the rate at which Muel[l]er’s sales of
    merchandise produced by Ternium was sold at less than
    normal value.” (emphasis added)).
    MUELLER COMERCIAL DE MEXICO   v. US                     11
    Mueller argues that this rationale is arbitrary and
    capricious or not supported by substantial evidence. We
    agree.
    There is no support for Commerce’s claim that using
    the three least-favorable TUNA transactions would
    produce the most accurate dumping margin for Mueller.
    Even calculating Mueller’s dumping margin based on the
    TUNA transactions where Mueller purchased the subject
    merchandise at below cost prices showed that Mueller
    received an average discount that was approximately half
    of the Commerce rate. An analysis based on all of the
    TUNA data showed that Mueller received, as a weighted
    average, less than a ten percent discount on the subject
    merchandise. Finally, an unweighted average of all the
    TUNA data showed that overall, Mueller’s acquisition
    costs were higher than TUNA’s production costs. Com-
    merce has not explained why using a larger data set
    would produce a less accurate dumping margin. Com-
    merce’s rationale that Ternium would have cooperated if
    disclosing its actual costs to Commerce had been favora-
    ble to its interests does not support a conclusion that the
    particular TUNA data Commerce ultimately chose to rely
    on accurately estimated those costs. There is no showing
    that Ternium, in the hypothesized benefit calculus, could
    have anticipated that, if it chose non-disclosure of its
    actual costs, Commerce would rely on TUNA’s three least
    favorable transactions to calculate Mueller’s rate; indeed,
    there is no showing that Ternium would even have known
    what TUNA’s data contained, given Commerce’s obliga-
    tion to keep TUNA’s data confidential.           19 C.F.R.
    §§ 351.105, 351.303–06. Therefore, we find that Com-
    merce’s accuracy rationale for its calculation of Mueller’s
    antidumping rate was unsupported by substantial evi-
    dence.
    Because Commerce’s calculation of Mueller’s rate re-
    lied in part on this accuracy rationale, this decision must
    12                     MUELLER COMERCIAL DE MEXICO    v. US
    be set aside. There is no contention that the use of the
    particular TUNA data relied on by Commerce was some-
    how required by the antidumping statute. See, e.g., ICC
    v. Bhd of Locomotive Eng’rs, 
    482 U.S. 270
    , 283 (1987);
    Koyo Seiko Co. v. United States, 
    95 F.3d 1094
    , 1101 (Fed.
    Cir. 1996). However, a reversal is also not appropriate
    because, as we conclude below, Commerce’s second ra-
    tionale provides a possible factor supporting the rate that
    Commerce adopted.
    Commerce’s second rationale rested on policy consid-
    erations unrelated to accuracy of the determination to be
    made on the already-developed record. Commerce found
    that Mueller could and should have induced Ternium’s
    cooperation by refusing to do business with Ternium, and
    Ternium would not be sufficiently deterred if Mueller
    were unaffected by Ternium’s non-cooperation, stating
    that Ternium could otherwise evade its antidumping rate
    by funneling its goods through Mueller. 5 We conclude
    5  See J.A. 42–43 (Decision Mem. 18–19) (“[W]e seek
    to induce compliance and to ensure that Ternium does not
    benefit from its non-compliance. As a general matter,
    companies that choose to do business with uncooperative
    parties may also be impacted.”); J.A. 43–44 (Decision
    Mem. 19–20) (“[I]f we were to accept Mueller’s arguments,
    the subject merchandise produced and exported by Terni-
    um would be subject to a total adverse facts available rate
    of 48.33, while the Ternium-produced merchandise ex-
    ported by Mueller would be subject to the much lower
    weighted-average rate of Mueller, such as the rate of 4.81
    from the Preliminary Results. Accordingly, Ternium
    could continue to produce and sell the subject merchan-
    dise for prices less than its normal value to the U.S.
    market by directing it[s] merchandise through Mueller,
    MUELLER COMERCIAL DE MEXICO    v. US                      13
    that Commerce may rely on such policies as part of a
    margin determination for a cooperating party like
    Mueller, as long as the application of those policies is
    reasonable on the particular facts and the predominant
    interest in accuracy is properly taken into account as well.
    This analysis is justified and required, even if Com-
    merce is viewed as acting entirely under subsection (a) in
    determining Mueller’s rate. But Mueller argues that
    because these adverse inferences and related rationales
    are the same as those that support the use of AFA under
    subsection (b), they cannot support a “facts otherwise
    available” determination under subsection (a). Mueller is
    mistaken. Subsection (a) does not provide for the specific
    facts that should be used as a gap-filling mechanism. The
    statute on its face does not preclude Commerce from
    relying on the same considerations under subsection (a)
    for an AFA determination as used under subsection (b).
    Under Chevron, Commerce’s interpretation of subsections
    (a) and (b) otherwise governs as long as it is reasonable
    and a permissible statutory construction. United States v.
    Eurodif S.A., 
    555 U.S. 305
    , 316 (2009); Timken Co. v.
    United States, 
    354 F.3d 1334
    , 1342 (Fed. Cir. 2004).
    Consideration under subsection (a) of facts found or
    rationales applicable under subsection (b), in the way
    Commerce may be viewed as having done here, passes
    muster under Chevron.
    This result is wholly consistent with our precedents
    applying subsection (b) itself, which is properly directed to
    non-cooperating parties. This Court’s decision in F.lli De
    Cecco Di Filippo Fara S. Martino S.p.A. v. United States,
    
    216 F.3d 1027
    , 1032 (Fed. Cir. 2000), required that, even
    where it would have no obligation to ever provide cost of
    production information, under Mueller’s argument.”).
    14                     MUELLER COMERCIAL DE MEXICO    v. US
    for a non-cooperating party, subsection (b) be applied to
    arrive at “a reasonably accurate estimate of the respond-
    ent’s actual rate, albeit with some built-in increase in-
    tended as a deterrent to noncompliance.” All the more so
    for a cooperating party, for which the equities would
    suggest greater emphasis on accuracy in the overall mix.
    Moreover, this Court’s decision in Changzhou made clear
    that, in the case of a cooperating party, Commerce cannot
    confine itself to a deterrence rationale and also must
    carry out a case-specific analysis of the applicability of
    deterrence and similar policies. 
    Changzhou, 703 F.3d at 1379
    . And those principles were in no way questioned in
    Fine Furniture (Shanghai) Ltd. v. United States, No.
    2013-1158, 
    2014 WL 1613883
    , at *4 (Fed. Cir. Apr. 23,
    2014), which simply rejected a contention that a counter-
    vailing duty rate for a cooperating importer could not be
    based on adverse inferences drawn against a non-
    cooperating foreign country (about the country’s subsidiz-
    ing of an input into the importer’s product). Fine Furni-
    ture involved no issue about the application of the De
    Cecco and Changzhou analysis to the selection of the
    particular rate for the cooperating party.
    Contrary to Mueller’s contention, consideration of var-
    ious factors in calculating the rate of a cooperating party
    is not precluded by Changzhou. In Changzhou, Com-
    merce concluded it was necessary to use an adverse rate
    against a cooperating party because other rates “would
    not be sufficiently adverse as to effectuate the purpose of
    the facts available rule to induce respondents to provide
    [Commerce] with complete and accurate information”—in
    other words, they would not have sufficient deterrent
    effect. 
    Changzhou, 701 F.3d at 1378
    (internal quotations
    omitted). But there was no support in the statute for
    imposing any deterrent effect on cooperating parties in
    that case. 
    Id. at 1379.
    The cooperating parties could not
    have induced the non-cooperating party to provide com-
    MUELLER COMERCIAL DE MEXICO    v. US                      15
    plete and accurate information, thus “there was no need
    or justification for deterrence.” 
    Id. Nor was
    there a claim
    that the non-cooperating party was likely to evade its own
    antidumping duty through the cooperating parties. 
    Id. We concluded
    that it was unreasonable to rely on a deter-
    rence rationale. We reversed and remanded to Commerce
    to “act non-arbitrarily” in calculating the separate rate for
    the cooperating parties. 
    Id. There is
    potentially greater support for Commerce’s
    use of an evasion or inducement rationale in this case
    than in Changzhou. While the cooperating plaintiffs in
    Changzhou did not have any mechanism to force the non-
    cooperating party’s cooperation (since the cooperating
    parties did not purchase goods from the non-cooperating
    party), 
    id. at 1370–71,
    Mueller had an existing relation-
    ship with supplier Ternium. Therefore, Mueller could
    potentially have refused to do business with Ternium in
    the future as a tactic to force Ternium to cooperate. In
    fact, the relationship between Mueller and Ternium is
    similar to the relationship between the importer and
    exporter in KYD, Inc. v. United States, 
    607 F.3d 760
    , 768
    (Fed. Cir. 2010). There, King Pac and KYD had an exist-
    ing relationship as importer-exporter, and this court
    found that KYD could have used this relationship to
    induce King Pac to cooperate. 
    Id. (“In the
    aggregate,
    however, the importers’ exposure to enhanced antidump-
    ing duties seems likely to have the effect of either directly
    inducing cooperation from the exporters with whom the
    importers deal or doing so indirectly, by leaving uncoop-
    erative exporters without importing partners who are
    willing to deal in their products.”); see also Fine Furni-
    ture, 
    2014 WL 1613883
    , at *7 (“Fine Furniture is a com-
    pany within the country of China, benefitting directly
    from the subsidies the government of China may be
    providing [and] a remedy that collaterally reaches Fine
    Furniture has the potential to encourage the government
    16                      MUELLER COMERCIAL DE MEXICO    v. US
    of China to cooperate so as to not hurt its overall indus-
    try.”). So too with Mueller and Ternium—if Mueller and
    other entities were not willing to export goods produced
    by Ternium, this would potentially induce Ternium to
    cooperate. On the other hand, if the cooperating entity
    has no control over the non-cooperating suppliers, a
    resulting adverse inference is potentially unfair to the
    cooperating party. SKF USA Inc. v. United States, 
    630 F.3d 1365
    , 1375 (Fed. Cir. 2011).
    In addition, as Commerce recognized, there is the pos-
    sibility that Ternium could evade its own AFA rate of
    48.33 percent by exporting its goods through Mueller if
    Mueller were assigned a favorable dumping rate. In this
    respect, too, this case is different from Changzhou and
    similar to KYD. We noted there that “KYD’s argument
    would allow an uncooperative foreign exporter to avoid
    the adverse inferences permitted by statute simply by
    selecting an unrelated importer, resulting in easy evasion
    of the means Congress intended for Commerce to use to
    induce cooperation with its antidumping investigations.”
    
    KYD, 607 F.3d at 768
    . Mueller argued that there was no
    evidence that Mueller was likely to act on Ternium’s
    behalf and reasoned that Commerce could investigate
    such false exports and impose Ternium’s own antidump-
    ing rate on them. See, e.g., Tung Mung Dev. Co. v. United
    States, 
    354 F.3d 1371
    , 1381 n.10 (Fed. Cir. 2004). But the
    fact that Commerce has alternative methods for address-
    ing evasion does not mean that the particular chosen
    method is arbitrary. Commerce can use all of the meth-
    ods provided in the Act for enforcement of the antidump-
    ing provisions.
    III
    In summary, on the remand, Commerce should recal-
    culate Mueller’s rate. In doing so, Commerce must have
    as its primary objective the calculation of an accurate rate
    MUELLER COMERCIAL DE MEXICO    v. US                     17
    for Mueller—as we said in Changzhou—“[w]e find no
    support in our caselaw or the statute’s plain text for the
    proposition that deterrence, rather than fairness or accu-
    racy, is the overriding purpose of the antidumping statute
    when calculating a rate for a cooperating 
    party.” 701 F.3d at 1378
    (internal quotation marks omitted). But we do
    not foreclose Commerce from also relying on the policy
    considerations that motivated the decision under review—
    namely, its desire to encourage Mueller to induce Terni-
    um’s cooperation and Commerce’s concern that calculat-
    ing too low a rate for Mueller might allow Ternium to
    evade its own dumping duty by channeling sales through
    Mueller.
    Commerce must take into account that Mueller itself
    was a cooperating party and that Commerce’s induce-
    ment/evasion approach to Mueller’s rate calculation could
    discourage Mueller’s own cooperation. See 
    id. To the
    extent that Commerce chooses to rely on induce-
    ment/evasion considerations, its approach must be rea-
    sonable. We do not today decide whether relying on
    inducement/evasion rationales to calculate Mueller’s rate
    would be reasonable in the circumstances of this case. We
    only hold that the statute does not preclude reliance on
    inducement or evasion considerations in calculating
    Mueller’s rate, and that such an approach is not fore-
    closed by Changzhou. We leave it to Commerce in the
    first instance to determine the relevant considerations
    and balance the need to calculate an accurate rate for
    Mueller and Mueller’s status as a cooperating party with
    other potentially relevant concerns.
    Finally, we wish to be clear that under subsection (b)
    we do not bar Commerce from drawing adverse inferences
    against a non-cooperating party that have collateral
    consequences for a cooperating party. Where an adverse
    inference is used to calculate the rate of a non-cooperating
    party that rate may sometimes be used in calculating the
    18                      MUELLER COMERCIAL DE MEXICO    v. US
    rate of a cooperating party and thus have collateral
    consequences for the cooperating party. 
    KYD, 607 F.3d at 768
    . That is not the situation here. Commerce drew two
    adverse inferences against Ternium. The first adverse
    inference was used to calculate Ternium’s own antidump-
    ing rate of 48.33 percent under subsection (b). The second
    adverse inference against Ternium, used to approximate
    Ternium’s cost of production, was not used in calculating
    Ternium’s rate, but only in calculating Mueller’s rate. So
    too this is unlike Fine Furniture where the government of
    China provided a subsidy to Fine Furniture. Fine Furni-
    ture, 
    2014 WL 1613883
    , at *5–6. China was an “interested
    party” as defined by the statute and the adverse inference
    applied was “adverse to the interests of that party.” 19
    U.S.C. § 1677(9)(B); see also Fine Furniture, 
    2014 WL 1613883
    , at *4. The use of an adverse inference was
    contrary to the interest of China because it directly offset
    the subsidy that China provided. Here, there is no direct
    adverse effect on Ternium from using an adverse infer-
    ence as facts otherwise available in computing Mueller’s
    dumping margin. Under these circumstances Commerce
    must proceed in the manner we have described.
    VACATED AND REMANDED
    COSTS
    No costs.