Kimble v. Marvel Entertainment, LLC ( 2015 )


Menu:
  • (Slip Opinion)              OCTOBER TERM, 2014                                       1
    Syllabus
    NOTE: Where it is feasible, a syllabus (headnote) will be released, as is
    being done in connection with this case, at the time the opinion is issued.
    The syllabus constitutes no part of the opinion of the Court but has been
    prepared by the Reporter of Decisions for the convenience of the reader.
    See United States v. Detroit Timber & Lumber Co., 
    200 U.S. 321
    , 337.
    SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES
    Syllabus
    KIMBLE ET AL. v. MARVEL ENTERTAINMENT, LLC,
    SUCCESSOR TO MARVEL ENTERPRISES, INC.
    CERTIORARI TO THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR
    THE NINTH CIRCUIT
    No. 13–720.      Argued March 31, 2015—Decided June 22, 2015
    Respondent Marvel Entertainment’s corporate predecessor agreed to
    purchase petitioner Stephen Kimble’s patent for a Spider-Man toy in
    exchange for a lump sum plus a 3% royalty on future sales. The
    agreement set no end date for royalties. As the patent neared the
    end of its statutory 20-year term, Marvel discovered Brulotte v. Thys
    Co., 
    379 U.S. 29
    , in which this Court held that a patentee cannot
    continue to receive royalties for sales made after his patent expires.
    Marvel then sought a declaratory judgment in federal district court
    confirming that it could stop paying Kimble royalties. The district
    court granted relief, and the Ninth Circuit affirmed. Kimble now
    asks this Court to overrule Brulotte.
    Held: Stare decisis requires this Court to adhere to Brulotte. Pp. 3–18.
    (a) A patent typically expires 20 years from its application date. 
    35 U.S. C
    . §154(a)(2). At that point, the unrestricted right to make or
    use the article passes to the public. See Sears, Roebuck & Co. v.
    Stiffel Co., 
    376 U.S. 225
    , 230. This Court has carefully guarded the
    significance of that expiration date, declining to enforce laws and
    contracts that restrict free public access to formerly patented, as well
    as unpatentable, inventions. See, e.g., 
    id., at 230–233;
    Scott Paper
    Co. v. Marcalus Mfg. Co., 
    326 U.S. 249
    , 255–256.
    Brulotte applied that principle to a patent licensing agreement that
    provided for the payment of royalties accruing after the patent’s expi-
    
    ration. 379 U.S., at 30
    . The Court held that the post-patent royalty
    provision was “unlawful per se,” 
    id., at 30,
    32, because it continued
    “the patent monopoly beyond the [patent] period,” 
    id., at 33,
    and, in
    so doing, conflicted with patent law’s policy of establishing a “post-
    expiration . . . public domain,” 
    ibid. 2 KIMBLE v.
    MARVEL ENTERTAINMENT, LLC
    Syllabus
    The Brulotte rule may prevent some parties from entering into
    deals they desire, but parties can often find ways to achieve similar
    outcomes. For example, Brulotte leaves parties free to defer pay-
    ments for pre-expiration use of a patent, tie royalties to non-patent
    rights, or make non-royalty-based business arrangements. Contend-
    ing that such alternatives are not enough, Kimble asks this Court to
    abandon Brulotte’s bright-line rule in favor of a case-by-case ap-
    proach based on antitrust law’s “rule of reason.” Pp. 3–7.
    (b) The doctrine of stare decisis provides that today’s Court should
    stand by yesterday’s decisions. Application of that doctrine, though
    “not an inexorable command,” is the “preferred course.” Payne v.
    Tennessee, 
    501 U.S. 808
    , 828, 827. Overruling a case always re-
    quires “special justification”—over and above the belief “that the
    precedent was wrongly decided.” Halliburton Co. v. Erica P. John
    Fund, Inc., 573 U. S. ___, ___. Where, as here, the precedent inter-
    prets a statute, stare decisis carries enhanced force, since critics are
    free to take their objections to Congress. See e.g., Patterson v.
    McLean Credit Union, 
    491 U.S. 164
    , 172–173. Congress, moreover,
    has spurned multiple opportunities to reverse Brulotte, see Watson v.
    United States, 
    552 U.S. 74
    , 82–83, and has even rebuffed bills that
    would have replaced Brulotte’s per se rule with the standard Kimble
    urges. In addition, Brulotte implicates property and contract law,
    two contexts in which considerations favoring stare decisis are “at
    their acme,” 
    Payne, 501 U.S., at 828
    , because parties are especially
    likely to rely on such precedents when ordering their affairs.
    Given those good reasons for adhering to stare decisis in this case,
    this Court would need a very strong justification for overruling
    Brulotte. But traditional justifications for abandoning stare decisis
    do not help Kimble here. First, Brulotte’s doctrinal underpinnings
    have not eroded over time. The patent statute at issue in Brulotte is
    essentially unchanged. And the precedent on which the Brulotte
    Court primarily relied, like other decisions enforcing a patent’s cut-
    off date, remains good law. Indeed, Brulotte’s close relation to a
    whole web of precedents means that overruling it could threaten oth-
    ers. Second, nothing about Brulotte has proved unworkable. See
    
    Patterson, 491 U.S., at 173
    . To the contrary, the decision itself is
    simple to apply—particularly as compared to Kimble’s proposed al-
    ternative, which can produce high litigation costs and unpredictable
    results. Pp. 7–12.
    (c) Neither of the justifications Kimble offers gives cause to over-
    rule Brulotte. Pp. 12–18.
    (1) Kimble first argues the Brulotte hinged on an economic er-
    ror—i.e., an assumption that post-expiration royalties are always an-
    ticompetitive. This Court sees no error in Kimble’s economic analy-
    Cite as: 576 U. S. ____ (2015)                    3
    Syllabus
    sis. But even assuming Kimble is right that Brulotte relied on an
    economic misjudgment, Congress is the right entity to fix it. The pa-
    tent laws are not like the Sherman Act, which gives courts exception-
    al authority to shape the law and reconsider precedent based on bet-
    ter economic analysis. Moreover, Kimble’s argument is based not on
    evolving economic theory but rather on a claim that the Brulotte
    Court simply made the wrong call. That claim fails to clear stare de-
    cisis’s high bar. In any event, Brulotte did not even turn on the no-
    tion that post-patent royalties harm competition. Instead, the
    Brulotte Court simply applied the categorical principle that all pa-
    tent-related benefits must end when the patent term expires. Kim-
    ble’s real complaint may go to the merits of that principle as a policy
    matter. But Congress, not this Court, gets to make patent policy.
    Pp. 12–16.
    (2) Kimble also argues that Brulotte suppresses technological in-
    novation and harms the national economy by preventing parties from
    reaching agreements to commercialize patents. This Court cannot
    tell whether that is true. Brulotte leaves parties free to enter alter-
    native arrangements that may suffice to accomplish parties’ payment
    deferral and risk-spreading goals. And neither Kimble nor his amici
    offer any empirical evidence connecting Brulotte to decreased innova-
    tion. In any event, claims about a statutory precedent’s consequences
    for innovation are “more appropriately addressed to Congress.” Hal-
    liburton, 573 U. S., at ___. Pp. 16–18.
    
    727 F.3d 856
    , affirmed.
    KAGAN, J., delivered the opinion of the Court, in which SCALIA, KEN-
    NEDY, GINSBURG, BREYER, and SOTOMAYOR, JJ., joined. ALITO, J., filed a
    dissenting opinion, in which ROBERTS, C. J., and THOMAS, J., joined.
    Cite as: 576 U. S. ____ (2015)                              1
    Opinion of the Court
    NOTICE: This opinion is subject to formal revision before publication in the
    preliminary print of the United States Reports. Readers are requested to
    notify the Reporter of Decisions, Supreme Court of the United States, Wash-
    ington, D. C. 20543, of any typographical or other formal errors, in order
    that corrections may be made before the preliminary print goes to press.
    SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES
    _________________
    No. 13–720
    _________________
    STEPHEN KIMBLE, ET AL., PETITIONERS v. MARVEL
    ENTERTAINMENT, LLC, SUCCESSOR TO MARVEL
    ENTERPRISES, INC.
    ON WRIT OF CERTIORARI TO THE UNITED STATES COURT OF
    APPEALS FOR THE NINTH CIRCUIT
    [June 22, 2015]
    JUSTICE KAGAN delivered the opinion of the Court.
    In Brulotte v. Thys Co., 
    379 U.S. 29
    (1964), this Court
    held that a patent holder cannot charge royalties for the
    use of his invention after its patent term has expired. The
    sole question presented here is whether we should over-
    rule Brulotte. Adhering to principles of stare decisis, we
    decline to do so. Critics of the Brulotte rule must seek
    relief not from this Court but from Congress.
    I
    In 1990, petitioner Stephen Kimble obtained a patent on
    a toy that allows children (and young-at-heart adults) to
    role-play as “a spider person” by shooting webs—really,
    pressurized foam string—“from the palm of [the] hand.”
    U. S. Patent No. 5,072,856, Abstract (filed May 25, 1990).1
    Respondent Marvel Entertainment, LLC (Marvel) makes
    and markets products featuring Spider-Man, among other
    comic-book characters. Seeking to sell or license his pa-
    ——————
    1 Petitioner Robert Grabb later acquired an interest in the patent.
    For simplicity, we refer only to Kimble.
    2          KIMBLE v. MARVEL ENTERTAINMENT, LLC
    Opinion of the Court
    tent, Kimble met with the president of Marvel’s corporate
    predecessor to discuss his idea for web-slinging fun. Soon
    afterward, but without remunerating Kimble, that com-
    pany began marketing the “Web Blaster”—a toy that, like
    Kimble’s patented invention, enables would-be action
    heroes to mimic Spider-Man through the use of a polyester
    glove and a canister of foam.
    Kimble sued Marvel in 1997 alleging, among other
    things, patent infringement. The parties ultimately set-
    tled that litigation. Their agreement provided that Marvel
    would purchase Kimble’s patent in exchange for a lump
    sum (of about a half-million dollars) and a 3% royalty on
    Marvel’s future sales of the Web Blaster and similar prod-
    ucts. The parties set no end date for royalties, apparently
    contemplating that they would continue for as long as kids
    want to imitate Spider-Man (by doing whatever a spider
    can).
    And then Marvel stumbled across Brulotte, the case at
    the heart of this dispute. In negotiating the settlement,
    neither side was aware of Brulotte. But Marvel must have
    been pleased to learn of it. Brulotte had read the patent
    laws to prevent a patentee from receiving royalties for
    sales made after his patent’s expiration. 
    See 379 U.S., at 32
    . So the decision’s effect was to sunset the settlement’s
    royalty clause.2 On making that discovery, Marvel sought
    a declaratory judgment in federal district court confirming
    that the company could cease paying royalties come
    2010—the end of Kimble’s patent term. The court ap-
    proved that relief, holding that Brulotte made “the royalty
    provision . . . unenforceable after the expiration of the
    Kimble patent.” 
    692 F. Supp. 2d 1156
    , 1161 (Ariz. 2010).
    ——————
    2 In Brulotte, the patent holder retained ownership of the patent
    while licensing customers to use the patented article in exchange for
    royalty payments. 
    See 379 U.S., at 29
    –30. By contrast, Kimble sold
    his whole patent to obtain royalties. But no one here disputes that
    Brulotte covers a transaction structured in that alternative way.
    Cite as: 576 U. S. ____ (2015)                    3
    Opinion of the Court
    The Court of Appeals for the Ninth Circuit affirmed,
    though making clear that it was none too happy about
    doing so. “[T]he Brulotte rule,” the court complained, “is
    counterintuitive and its rationale is arguably unconvinc-
    ing.” 
    727 F.3d 856
    , 857 (2013).
    We granted certiorari, 574 U. S. ___ (2014), to decide
    whether, as some courts and commentators have suggested,
    we should overrule Brulotte.3 For reasons of stare decisis,
    we demur.
    II
    Patents endow their holders with certain superpowers,
    but only for a limited time. In crafting the patent laws,
    Congress struck a balance between fostering innovation
    and ensuring public access to discoveries. While a patent
    lasts, the patentee possesses exclusive rights to the pa-
    tented article—rights he may sell or license for royalty
    payments if he so chooses. See 
    35 U.S. C
    . §154(a)(1). But
    a patent typically expires 20 years from the day the appli-
    cation for it was filed. See §154(a)(2). And when the
    patent expires, the patentee’s prerogatives expire too, and
    the right to make or use the article, free from all re-
    striction, passes to the public. See Sears, Roebuck & Co. v.
    Stiffel Co., 
    376 U.S. 225
    , 230 (1964).
    This Court has carefully guarded that cut-off date, just
    as it has the patent laws’ subject-matter limits: In case
    after case, the Court has construed those laws to preclude
    ——————
    3 See, e.g., Scheiber v. Dolby Labs., Inc., 
    293 F.3d 1014
    , 1017–1018
    (CA7 2002) (Posner, J.) (Brulotte has been “severely, and as it seems to
    us, with all due respect, justly criticized . . . . However, we have no
    authority to overrule a Supreme Court decision no matter how dubious
    its reasoning strikes us, or even how out of touch with the Supreme
    Court’s current thinking the decision seems”); Ayres & Klemperer,
    Limiting Patentees’ Market Power Without Reducing Innovation
    Incentives: The Perverse Benefits of Uncertainty and Non-Injunctive
    Remedies, 
    97 Mich. L
    . Rev. 985, 1027 (1999) (“Our analysis . . . suggests
    that Brulotte should be overruled”).
    4        KIMBLE v. MARVEL ENTERTAINMENT, LLC
    Opinion of the Court
    measures that restrict free access to formerly patented, as
    well as unpatentable, inventions. In one line of cases, we
    have struck down state statutes with that consequence.
    See, e.g., 
    id., at 230–233;
    Bonito Boats, Inc. v. Thunder
    Craft Boats, Inc., 
    489 U.S. 141
    , 152, 167–168 (1989);
    Compco Corp. v. Day-Brite Lighting, Inc., 
    376 U.S. 234
    ,
    237–238 (1964). By virtue of federal law, we reasoned, “an
    article on which the patent has expired,” like an un-
    patentable article, “is in the public domain and may be
    made and sold by whoever chooses to do so.” 
    Sears, 376 U.S., at 231
    . In a related line of decisions, we have
    deemed unenforceable private contract provisions limiting
    free use of such inventions. In Scott Paper Co. v. Marcalus
    Mfg. Co., 
    326 U.S. 249
    (1945), for example, we determined
    that a manufacturer could not agree to refrain from chal-
    lenging a patent’s validity. Allowing even a single com-
    pany to restrict its use of an expired or invalid patent, we
    explained, “would deprive . . . the consuming public of the
    advantage to be derived” from free exploitation of the
    discovery. 
    Id., at 256.
    And to permit such a result,
    whether or not authorized “by express contract,” would
    impermissibly undermine the patent laws. 
    Id., at 255–
    256; see also, e.g., Edward Katzinger Co. v. Chicago Metal-
    lic Mfg. Co., 
    329 U.S. 394
    , 400–401 (1947) (ruling that
    Scott Paper applies to licensees); Lear, Inc. v. Adkins, 
    395 U.S. 653
    , 668–675 (1969) (refusing to enforce a contract
    requiring a licensee to pay royalties while contesting a
    patent’s validity).
    Brulotte was brewed in the same barrel. There, an
    inventor licensed his patented hop-picking machine to
    farmers in exchange for royalties from hop crops harvested
    both before and after his patents’ expiration dates. The
    Court (by an 8-1 vote) held the agreement unenforceable—
    “unlawful per se”—to the extent it provided for the pay-
    ment of royalties “accru[ing] after the last of the patents
    incorporated into the machines had expired.” 379 U. S., at
    Cite as: 576 U. S. ____ (2015)           5
    Opinion of the Court
    30, 32. To arrive at that conclusion, the Court began with
    the statutory provision setting the length of a patent term.
    See 
    id., at 30
    (quoting the then-current version of §154).
    Emphasizing that a patented invention “become[s] public
    property once [that term] expires,” the Court then quoted
    from Scott Paper: Any attempt to limit a licensee’s post-
    expiration use of the invention, “whatever the legal device
    employed, runs counter to the policy and purpose of the
    patent 
    laws.” 379 U.S., at 31
    (quoting 326 U.S., at 256
    ).
    In the Brulotte Court’s view, contracts to pay royalties for
    such use continue “the patent monopoly beyond the [pa-
    tent] period,” even though only as to the licensee 
    affected. 379 U.S., at 33
    . And in so doing, those agreements con-
    flict with patent law’s policy of establishing a “post-
    expiration . . . public domain” in which every person can
    make free use of a formerly patented product. 
    Ibid. The Brulotte rule,
    like others making contract provi-
    sions unenforceable, prevents some parties from entering
    into deals they desire. As compared to lump-sum fees,
    royalty plans both draw out payments over time and tie
    those payments, in each month or year covered, to a prod-
    uct’s commercial success. And sometimes, for some par-
    ties, the longer the arrangement lasts, the better—not just
    up to but beyond a patent term’s end. A more extended
    payment period, coupled (as it presumably would be) with
    a lower rate, may bring the price the patent holder seeks
    within the range of a cash-strapped licensee. (Anyone who
    has bought a product on installment can relate.) See Brief
    for Memorial Sloan Kettering Cancer Center et al. as
    Amici Curiae 17. Or such an extended term may better
    allocate the risks and rewards associated with commer-
    cializing inventions—most notably, when years of devel-
    opment work stand between licensing a patent and bring-
    ing a product to market. See, e.g., 3 R. Milgrim & E.
    Bensen, Milgrim on Licensing §18.05, p. 18–9 (2013). As
    to either goal, Brulotte may pose an obstacle.
    6        KIMBLE v. MARVEL ENTERTAINMENT, LLC
    Opinion of the Court
    Yet parties can often find ways around Brulotte, ena-
    bling them to achieve those same ends. To start, Brulotte
    allows a licensee to defer payments for pre-expiration use
    of a patent into the post-expiration period; all the decision
    bars are royalties for using an invention after it has
    moved into the public domain. 
    See 379 U.S., at 31
    ; Zenith
    Radio Corp. v. Hazeltine Research, Inc., 
    395 U.S. 100
    , 136
    (1969). A licensee could agree, for example, to pay the
    licensor a sum equal to 10% of sales during the 20-year
    patent term, but to amortize that amount over 40 years.
    That arrangement would at least bring down early out-
    lays, even if it would not do everything the parties might
    want to allocate risk over a long timeframe. And parties
    have still more options when a licensing agreement covers
    either multiple patents or additional non-patent rights.
    Under Brulotte, royalties may run until the latest-running
    patent covered in the parties’ agreement expires. 
    See 379 U.S., at 30
    . Too, post-expiration royalties are allowable so
    long as tied to a non-patent right—even when closely
    related to a patent. See, e.g., 3 Milgrim on Licensing
    §18.07, at 18–16 to 18–17. That means, for example, that
    a license involving both a patent and a trade secret can set
    a 5% royalty during the patent period (as compensation for
    the two combined) and a 4% royalty afterward (as pay-
    ment for the trade secret alone). Finally and most broadly,
    Brulotte poses no bar to business arrangements other than
    royalties—all kinds of joint ventures, for example—that
    enable parties to share the risks and rewards of commer-
    cializing an invention.
    Contending that such alternatives are not enough,
    Kimble asks us to abandon Brulotte in favor of “flexible,
    case-by-case analysis” of post-expiration royalty clauses
    “under the rule of reason.” Brief for Petitioners 45. Used
    in antitrust law, the rule of reason requires courts to
    evaluate a practice’s effect on competition by “taking into
    account a variety of factors, including specific information
    Cite as: 576 U. S. ____ (2015)              7
    Opinion of the Court
    about the relevant business, its condition before and after
    the [practice] was imposed, and the [practice’s] history,
    nature, and effect.” State Oil Co. v. Khan, 
    522 U.S. 3
    , 10
    (1997). Of primary importance in this context, Kimble
    posits, is whether a patent holder has power in the rele-
    vant market and so might be able to curtail competition.
    See Brief for Petitioners 47–48; Illinois Tool Works Inc. v.
    Independent Ink, Inc., 
    547 U.S. 28
    , 44 (2006) (“[A] patent
    does not necessarily confer market power”). Resolving
    that issue, Kimble notes, entails “a full-fledged economic
    inquiry into the definition of the market, barriers to entry,
    and the like.” Brief for Petitioners 48 (quoting 1 H.
    Hovenkamp, M. Janis, M. Lemley, & C. Leslie, IP and
    Antitrust §3.2e, p. 3–12.1 (2d ed., Supp. 2014)
    (Hovenkamp)).
    III
    Overruling precedent is never a small matter. Stare
    decisis—in English, the idea that today’s Court should
    stand by yesterday’s decisions—is “a foundation stone of
    the rule of law.” Michigan v. Bay Mills Indian Commu-
    nity, 572 U. S. ___, ___ (2014) (slip op., at 15). Application of
    that doctrine, although “not an inexorable command,” is
    the “preferred course because it promotes the evenhanded,
    predictable, and consistent development of legal princi-
    ples, fosters reliance on judicial decisions, and contributes
    to the actual and perceived integrity of the judicial pro-
    cess.” Payne v. Tennessee, 
    501 U.S. 808
    , 827–828 (1991).
    It also reduces incentives for challenging settled prece-
    dents, saving parties and courts the expense of endless
    relitigation.
    Respecting stare decisis means sticking to some wrong
    decisions. The doctrine rests on the idea, as Justice
    Brandeis famously wrote, that it is usually “more im-
    portant that the applicable rule of law be settled than that
    it be settled right.” Burnet v. Coronado Oil & Gas Co., 285
    8         KIMBLE v. MARVEL ENTERTAINMENT, LLC
    Opinion of the Court
    U. S. 393, 406 (1932) (dissenting opinion). Indeed, stare
    decisis has consequence only to the extent it sustains
    incorrect decisions; correct judgments have no need for
    that principle to prop them up. Accordingly, an argument
    that we got something wrong—even a good argument to
    that effect—cannot by itself justify scrapping settled
    precedent. Or otherwise said, it is not alone sufficient that
    we would decide a case differently now than we did then.
    To reverse course, we require as well what we have
    termed a “special justification”—over and above the belief
    “that the precedent was wrongly decided.” Halliburton
    Co. v. Erica P. John Fund, Inc., 573 U. S. ___, ___ (2014)
    (slip op., at 4).
    What is more, stare decisis carries enhanced force when
    a decision, like Brulotte, interprets a statute. Then, unlike
    in a constitutional case, critics of our ruling can take their
    objections across the street, and Congress can correct any
    mistake it sees. See, e.g., Patterson v. McLean Credit
    Union, 
    491 U.S. 164
    , 172–173 (1989). That is true, con-
    trary to the dissent’s view, see post, at 6–7 (opinion of
    ALITO, J.), regardless whether our decision focused only on
    statutory text or also relied, as Brulotte did, on the policies
    and purposes animating the law. See, e.g., Bilski v. Kap-
    pos, 
    561 U.S. 593
    , 601–602 (2010). Indeed, we apply
    statutory stare decisis even when a decision has an-
    nounced a “judicially created doctrine” designed to imple-
    ment a federal statute. Halliburton, 573 U. S., at ___ (slip
    op., at 12). All our interpretive decisions, in whatever way
    reasoned, effectively become part of the statutory scheme,
    subject (just like the rest) to congressional change. Absent
    special justification, they are balls tossed into Congress’s
    court, for acceptance or not as that branch elects.
    And Congress has spurned multiple opportunities to
    reverse Brulotte—openings as frequent and clear as this
    Court ever sees. Brulotte has governed licensing agree-
    ments for more than half a century. See Watson v. United
    Cite as: 576 U. S. ____ (2015)            9
    Opinion of the Court
    States, 
    552 U.S. 74
    , 82–83 (2007) (stating that “long
    congressional acquiescence,” there totaling just 14 years,
    “enhance[s] even the usual precedential force we accord to
    our interpretations of statutes” (internal quotation marks
    omitted)). During that time, Congress has repeatedly
    amended the patent laws, including the specific provision
    (
    35 U.S. C
    . §154) on which Brulotte rested. See, e.g.,
    Uruguay Round Agreements Act, §532(a), 108 Stat. 4983
    (1994) (increasing the length of the patent term); Act of
    Nov. 19, 1988, §201, 102 Stat. 4676 (limiting patent-
    misuse claims). Brulotte survived every such change.
    Indeed, Congress has rebuffed bills that would have re-
    placed Brulotte’s per se rule with the same antitrust-style
    analysis Kimble now urges. See, e.g., S. 1200, 100th
    Cong., 1st Sess., Tit. II (1987) (providing that no patent
    owner would be guilty of “illegal extension of the patent
    right by reason of his or her licensing practices . . . unless
    such practices . . . violate the antitrust laws”); S. 438,
    100th Cong., 2d Sess., §201(3) (1988) (same). Congress’s
    continual reworking of the patent laws—but never of the
    Brulotte rule—further supports leaving the decision in
    place.
    Nor yet are we done, for the subject matter of Brulotte
    adds to the case for adhering to precedent. Brulotte lies at
    the intersection of two areas of law: property (patents) and
    contracts (licensing agreements). And we have often
    recognized that in just those contexts—“cases involving
    property and contract rights”—considerations favoring
    stare decisis are “at their acme.” E.g., 
    Payne, 501 U.S., at 828
    ; 
    Khan, 522 U.S., at 20
    . That is because parties are
    especially likely to rely on such precedents when ordering
    their affairs. To be sure, Marvel and Kimble disagree
    about whether Brulotte has actually generated reliance.
    Marvel says yes: Some parties, it claims, do not specify an
    end date for royalties in their licensing agreements, in-
    stead relying on Brulotte as a default rule. Brief for Re-
    10       KIMBLE v. MARVEL ENTERTAINMENT, LLC
    Opinion of the Court
    spondent 32–33; see 1 D. Epstein, Eckstrom’s Licensing in
    Foreign and Domestic Operations §3.13, p. 3–13, and n. 2
    (2014) (noting that it is not “necessary to specify the term
    . . . of the license” when a decision like Brulotte limits it
    “by law”). Overturning Brulotte would thus upset expecta-
    tions, most so when long-dormant licenses for long-expired
    patents spring back to life. Not true, says Kimble: Unfair
    surprise is unlikely, because no “meaningful number of
    [such] license agreements . . . actually exist.” Reply Brief
    18. To be honest, we do not know (nor, we suspect, do
    Marvel and Kimble). But even uncertainty on this score
    cuts in Marvel’s direction. So long as we see a reasonable
    possibility that parties have structured their business
    transactions in light of Brulotte, we have one more reason
    to let it stand.
    As against this superpowered form of stare decisis, we
    would need a superspecial justification to warrant revers-
    ing Brulotte. But the kinds of reasons we have most often
    held sufficient in the past do not help Kimble here. If
    anything, they reinforce our unwillingness to do what he
    asks.
    First, Brulotte’s statutory and doctrinal underpinnings
    have not eroded over time. When we reverse our statutory
    interpretations, we most often point to subsequent legal
    developments—“either the growth of judicial doctrine or
    further action taken by Congress”—that have removed the
    basis for a decision. 
    Patterson, 491 U.S., at 173
    (calling
    this “the primary reason” for overruling statutory prece-
    dent). But the core feature of the patent laws on which
    Brulotte relied remains just the same: Section 154 now, as
    then, draws a sharp line cutting off patent rights after a
    set number of years. And this Court has continued to
    draw from that legislative choice a broad policy favoring
    unrestricted use of an invention after its patent’s expira-
    tion. 
    See supra, at 3
    –4. Scott Paper—the decision on
    which Brulotte primarily relied—remains good law. So too
    Cite as: 576 U. S. ____ (2015)                    11
    Opinion of the Court
    do this Court’s other decisions refusing to enforce either
    state laws or private contracts constraining individuals’
    free use of formerly patented (or unpatentable) discover-
    ies. 
    See supra, at 3
    –4. Brulotte, then, is not the kind of
    doctrinal dinosaur or legal last-man-standing for which
    we sometimes depart from stare decisis. Compare, e.g.,
    Alleyne v. United States, 570 U. S. ___, ___–___ (2013)
    (SOTOMAYOR, J., concurring) (slip op., at 2–5). To the
    contrary, the decision’s close relation to a whole web of
    precedents means that reversing it could threaten others.
    If Brulotte is outdated, then (for example) is Scott Paper
    too? We would prefer not to unsettle stable law.4
    And second, nothing about Brulotte has proved unwork-
    able. See, e.g., 
    Patterson, 491 U.S., at 173
    (identifying
    unworkability as another “traditional justification” for
    ——————
    4 The only legal erosion to which Kimble gestures is a change in the
    treatment of patent tying agreements—i.e., contracts conditioning a
    licensee’s right to use a patent on the purchase of an unpatented
    product. See Brief for Petitioners 43. When Brulotte was decided,
    those agreements counted as per se antitrust violations and patent
    misuse; now, they are unlawful only if the patent holder wields power
    in the relevant market. See Act of Nov. 19, 1988, §201, 102 Stat. 4676
    (adding the market power requirement in the patent misuse context);
    Illinois Tool Works Inc. v. Independent Ink, Inc., 
    547 U.S. 28
    , 41–43
    (2006) (relying on that legislative change to overrule antitrust decisions
    about tying and to adopt the same standard). But it is far from clear
    that the old rule of tying was among Brulotte’s legal underpinnings.
    Brulotte briefly analogized post-expiration royalty agreements to tying
    arrangements, but only after relating the statutory and caselaw basis
    for its holding and “conclud[ing]” that post-patent royalties are “unlaw-
    ful per 
    se.” 379 U.S., at 32
    . And even if that analogy played some real
    role in Brulotte, the development of tying law would not undercut the
    decision—rather the opposite. Congress took the lead in changing the
    treatment of tying agreements and, in doing so, conspicuously left
    Brulotte in place. Indeed, Congress declined to enact bills that would
    have modified not only tying doctrine but also Brulotte. 
    See supra, at 9
    (citing S. 1200, 100th Cong., 1st Sess. (1987), and S. 438, 100th Cong.,
    2d Sess. (1988)). That choice suggests congressional acquiescence in
    Brulotte, and so further supports adhering to stare decisis.
    12       KIMBLE v. MARVEL ENTERTAINMENT, LLC
    Opinion of the Court
    overruling precedent). The decision is simplicity itself to
    apply. A court need only ask whether a licensing agree-
    ment provides royalties for post-expiration use of a patent.
    If not, no problem; if so, no dice. Brulotte’s ease of use
    appears in still sharper relief when compared to Kimble’s
    proposed alternative. Recall that he wants courts to
    employ antitrust law’s rule of reason to identify and invali-
    date those post-expiration royalty clauses with anti-
    competitive consequences. 
    See supra, at 6
    –7. But what-
    ever its merits may be for deciding antitrust claims, that
    “elaborate inquiry” produces notoriously high litigation
    costs and unpredictable results. Arizona v. Maricopa
    County Medical Soc., 
    457 U.S. 332
    , 343 (1982). For that
    reason, trading in Brulotte for the rule of reason would
    make the law less, not more, workable than it is now.
    Once again, then, the case for sticking with long-settled
    precedent grows stronger: Even the most usual reasons for
    abandoning stare decisis cut the other way here.
    IV
    Lacking recourse to those traditional justifications for
    overruling a prior decision, Kimble offers two different
    ones. He claims first that Brulotte rests on a mistaken
    view of the competitive effects of post-expiration royalties.
    He contends next that Brulotte suppresses technological
    innovation and so harms the nation’s economy. (The
    dissent offers versions of those same arguments. See post,
    at 1–4.) We consider the two claims in turn, but our an-
    swers to both are much the same: Kimble’s reasoning may
    give Congress cause to upset Brulotte, but does not war-
    rant this Court’s doing so.
    A
    According to Kimble, we should overrule Brulotte be-
    cause it hinged on an error about economics: It assumed
    that post-patent royalty “arrangements are invariably
    Cite as: 576 U. S. ____ (2015)          13
    Opinion of the Court
    anticompetitive.” Brief for Petitioners 37. That is not
    true, Kimble notes; indeed, such agreements more often
    increase than inhibit competition, both before and after
    the patent expires. See 
    id., at 36–40.
    As noted earlier, a
    longer payment period will typically go hand-in-hand with
    a lower royalty rate. 
    See supra, at 5
    . During the patent
    term, those reduced rates may lead to lower consumer
    prices, making the patented technology more competitive
    with alternatives; too, the lesser rates may enable more
    companies to afford a license, fostering competition among
    the patent’s own users. See Brief for Petitioners 38. And
    after the patent’s expiration, Kimble continues, further
    benefits follow: Absent high barriers to entry (a material
    caveat, as even he would agree, see Tr. of Oral Arg. 12–13,
    23), the licensee’s continuing obligation to pay royalties
    encourages new companies to begin making the product,
    figuring that they can quickly attract customers by under-
    cutting the licensee on price. See Brief for Petitioners 38–
    39. In light of those realities, Kimble concludes, “the
    Brulotte per se rule makes little sense.” 
    Id., at 11.
       We do not join issue with Kimble’s economics—only with
    what follows from it. A broad scholarly consensus sup-
    ports Kimble’s view of the competitive effects of post-
    expiration royalties, and we see no error in that shared
    analysis. See 
    id., at 13–18
    (citing numerous treatises and
    articles critiquing Brulotte). Still, we must decide what
    that means for Brulotte. Kimble, of course, says it means
    the decision must go. Positing that Brulotte turned on the
    belief that post-expiration royalties are always anticom-
    petitive, he invokes decisions in which this Court aban-
    doned antitrust precedents premised on similarly shaky
    economic reasoning. See Brief for Petitioners 55–56 (cit-
    ing, e.g., Leegin Creative Leather Products, Inc. v. PSKS,
    Inc., 
    551 U.S. 877
    (2007); Illinois Tool Works, 
    547 U.S. 28
    ). But to agree with Kimble’s conclusion, we must re-
    solve two questions in his favor. First, even assuming
    14       KIMBLE v. MARVEL ENTERTAINMENT, LLC
    Opinion of the Court
    Kimble accurately characterizes Brulotte’s basis, does the
    decision’s economic mistake suffice to overcome stare
    decisis? Second and more fundamentally, was Brulotte
    actually founded, as Kimble contends, on an analysis of
    competitive effects?
    If Brulotte were an antitrust rather than a patent case,
    we might answer both questions as Kimble would like.
    This Court has viewed stare decisis as having less-than-
    usual force in cases involving the Sherman Act. See, e.g.,
    
    Khan, 522 U.S., at 20
    –21. Congress, we have explained,
    intended that law’s reference to “restraint of trade” to
    have “changing content,” and authorized courts to oversee
    the term’s “dynamic potential.” Business Electronics Corp.
    v. Sharp Electronics Corp., 
    485 U.S. 717
    , 731–732 (1988).
    We have therefore felt relatively free to revise our legal
    analysis as economic understanding evolves and (just as
    Kimble notes) to reverse antitrust precedents that misper-
    ceived a practice’s competitive consequences. See 
    Leegin, 551 U.S., at 899
    –900. Moreover, because the question in
    those cases was whether the challenged activity restrained
    trade, the Court’s rulings necessarily turned on its under-
    standing of economics. See Business Electronics 
    Corp., 485 U.S., at 731
    . Accordingly, to overturn the decisions in
    light of sounder economic reasoning was to take them “on
    [their] own terms.” Halliburton, 573 U. S., at ___ (slip op.,
    at 9).
    But Brulotte is a patent rather than an antitrust case,
    and our answers to both questions instead go against
    Kimble. To begin, even assuming that Brulotte relied on
    an economic misjudgment, Congress is the right entity to
    fix it. By contrast with the Sherman Act, the patent laws
    do not turn over exceptional law-shaping authority to the
    courts. Accordingly, statutory stare decisis—in which this
    Court interprets and Congress decides whether to
    amend—retains its usual strong force. 
    See supra, at 8
    .
    And as we have shown, that doctrine does not ordinarily
    Cite as: 576 U. S. ____ (2015)           15
    Opinion of the Court
    bend to “wrong on the merits”-type arguments; it instead
    assumes Congress will correct whatever mistakes we
    commit. 
    See supra, at 7
    –8. Nor does Kimble offer any
    reason to think his own “the Court erred” claim is special.
    Indeed, he does not even point to anything that has
    changed since Brulotte—no new empirical studies or ad-
    vances in economic theory. Compare, e.g., Halliburton,
    573 U. S., at ___ (slip op., at 9–12) (considering, though
    finding insufficient, recent economic research). On his
    argument, the Brulotte Court knew all it needed to know
    to determine that post-patent royalties are not usually
    anticompetitive; it just made the wrong call. See Brief for
    Petitioners 36–40. That claim, even if itself dead-right,
    fails to clear stare decisis’s high bar.
    And in any event, Brulotte did not hinge on the mistake
    Kimble identifies. Although some of its language invoked
    economic concepts, see n. 
    4, supra
    , the Court did not rely
    on the notion that post-patent royalties harm competition.
    Nor is that surprising. The patent laws—unlike the
    Sherman Act—do not aim to maximize competition (to a
    large extent, the opposite). And the patent term—unlike
    the “restraint of trade” standard—provides an all-
    encompassing bright-line rule, rather than calling for
    practice-specific analysis. So in deciding whether post-
    expiration royalties comport with patent law, Brulotte did
    not undertake to assess that practice’s likely competitive
    effects. Instead, it applied a categorical principle that all
    patents, and all benefits from them, must end when their
    terms expire. See 
    Brulotte, 379 U.S., at 30
    –32; supra, at
    3–5. Or more specifically put, the Court held, as it had in
    Scott Paper, that Congress had made a judgment: that the
    day after a patent lapses, the formerly protected invention
    must be available to all for free. And further: that post-
    expiration restraints on even a single licensee’s access to
    the invention clash with that principle. See 
    Brulotte, 379 U.S., at 31
    –32 (a licensee’s obligation to pay post-patent
    16       KIMBLE v. MARVEL ENTERTAINMENT, LLC
    Opinion of the Court
    royalties conflicts with the “free market visualized for the
    post-expiration period” and so “runs counter to the policy
    and purpose of the patent laws” (quoting Scott 
    Paper, 326 U.S., at 256
    )). That patent (not antitrust) policy gave rise
    to the Court’s conclusion that post-patent royalty contracts
    are unenforceable—utterly “regardless of a demonstrable
    effect on competition.” 1 Hovenkamp §3.2d, at 3–10.
    Kimble’s real complaint may go to the merits of such a
    patent policy—what he terms its “formalis[m],” its “rig-
    id[ity]”, and its detachment from “economic reality.” Brief
    for Petitioners 27–28. But that is just a different version
    of the argument that Brulotte is wrong. And it is, if any-
    thing, a version less capable than the last of trumping
    statutory stare decisis. For the choice of what patent
    policy should be lies first and foremost with Congress. So
    if Kimble thinks patent law’s insistence on unrestricted
    access to formerly patented inventions leaves too little
    room for pro-competitive post-expiration royalties, then
    Congress, not this Court, is his proper audience.
    B
    Kimble also seeks support from the wellspring of all
    patent policy: the goal of promoting innovation. Brulotte,
    he contends, “discourages technological innovation and
    does significant damage to the American economy.” Brief
    for Petitioners 29. Recall that would-be licensors and
    licensees may benefit from post-patent royalty arrange-
    ments because they allow for a longer payment period and
    a more precise allocation of risk. 
    See supra, at 5
    . If the
    parties’ ideal licensing agreement is barred, Kimble rea-
    sons, they may reach no agreement at all. See Brief for
    Petitioners 32. And that possibility may discourage inven-
    tion in the first instance. The bottom line, Kimble con-
    cludes, is that some “breakthrough technologies will never
    see the light of day.” 
    Id., at 33.
       Maybe. Or, then again, maybe not. While we recognize
    Cite as: 576 U. S. ____ (2015)          17
    Opinion of the Court
    that post-patent royalties are sometimes not anticompeti-
    tive, we just cannot say whether barring them imposes
    any meaningful drag on innovation. As we have ex-
    plained, Brulotte leaves open various ways—involving
    both licensing and other business arrangements—to ac-
    complish payment deferral and risk-spreading alike. 
    See supra, at 6
    . Those alternatives may not offer the parties
    the precise set of benefits and obligations they would
    prefer. But they might still suffice to bring patent holders
    and product developers together and ensure that inven-
    tions get to the public. Neither Kimble nor his amici have
    offered any empirical evidence connecting Brulotte to
    decreased innovation; they essentially ask us to take their
    word for the problem. And the United States, which acts
    as both a licensor and a licensee of patented inventions
    while also implementing patent policy, vigorously disputes
    that Brulotte has caused any “significant real-world eco-
    nomic harm.” Brief for United States as Amicus Curiae
    30. Truth be told, if forced to decide that issue, we would
    not know where or how to start.
    Which is one good reason why that is not our job.
    Claims that a statutory precedent has “serious and harm-
    ful consequences” for innovation are (to repeat this opin-
    ion’s refrain) “more appropriately addressed to Congress.”
    Halliburton, 573 U. S., at ___ (slip op., at 15). That
    branch, far more than this one, has the capacity to assess
    Kimble’s charge that Brulotte suppresses technological
    progress. And if it concludes that Brulotte works such
    harm, Congress has the prerogative to determine the exact
    right response—choosing the policy fix, among many
    conceivable ones, that will optimally serve the public
    interest. As we have noted, Congress legislates actively
    with respect to patents, considering concerns of just the
    kind Kimble raises. 
    See supra, at 9
    . In adhering to our
    precedent as against such complaints, we promote the
    rule-of-law values to which courts must attend while
    18       KIMBLE v. MARVEL ENTERTAINMENT, LLC
    Opinion of the Court
    leaving matters of public policy to Congress.
    V
    What we can decide, we can undecide. But stare decisis
    teaches that we should exercise that authority sparingly.
    Cf. S. Lee and S. Ditko, Amazing Fantasy No. 15: “Spider-
    Man,” p. 13 (1962) (“[I]n this world, with great power
    there must also come—great responsibility”). Finding
    many reasons for staying the stare decisis course and no
    “special justification” for departing from it, we decline
    Kimble’s invitation to overrule Brulotte.
    For the reasons stated, the judgment of the Court of
    Appeals is affirmed.
    It is so ordered.
    Cite as: 576 U. S. ____ (2015)            1
    ALITO, J., dissenting
    SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES
    _________________
    No. 13–720
    _________________
    STEPHEN KIMBLE, ET AL., PETITIONERS v. MARVEL
    ENTERTAINMENT, LLC, SUCCESSOR TO MARVEL
    ENTERPRISES, INC.
    ON WRIT OF CERTIORARI TO THE UNITED STATES COURT OF
    APPEALS FOR THE NINTH CIRCUIT
    [June 22, 2015]
    JUSTICE ALITO, with whom THE CHIEF JUSTICE and
    JUSTICE THOMAS join, dissenting.
    The Court employs stare decisis, normally a tool of
    restraint, to reaffirm a clear case of judicial overreach.
    Our decision in Brulotte v. Thys Co., 
    379 U.S. 29
    (1964),
    held that parties cannot enter into a patent licensing
    agreement that provides for royalty payments to continue
    after the term of the patent expires. That decision was not
    based on anything that can plausibly be regarded as an
    interpretation of the terms of the Patent Act. It was based
    instead on an economic theory—and one that has been
    debunked. The decision interferes with the ability of
    parties to negotiate licensing agreements that reflect the
    true value of a patent, and it disrupts contractual expecta­
    tions. Stare decisis does not require us to retain this
    baseless and damaging precedent.
    I
    A
    The Patent Act provides that a patent grants certain
    exclusive rights to the patentee and “his heirs or assigns”
    for a term of 20 years. 
    35 U.S. C
    . §§154(a)(1) and (2). The
    Act says nothing whatsoever about post-expiration royal­
    ties. In Brulotte, however, the Court held that such royal­
    2        KIMBLE v. MARVEL ENTERTAINMENT, LLC
    ALITO, J., dissenting
    ties are per se unlawful. The Court made little pretense of
    finding support for this holding in the language of the Act.
    Instead, the Court reasoned that allowing post-expiration
    royalties would subject “the free market visualized for the
    post-expiration period . . . to monopoly influences that
    have no proper place 
    there.” 379 U.S., at 32
    –33. Invok­
    ing antitrust concepts, the decision suggested that such
    arrangements are “an effort to enlarge the monopoly of the
    patent by t[y]ing the sale or use of the patented article to
    the purchase or use of unpatented ones.” 
    Id., at 33.
       Whatever the merits of this economic argument, it does
    not represent a serious attempt to interpret the Patent
    Act. A licensing agreement that provides for the payment
    of royalties after a patent’s term expires does not enlarge
    the patentee’s monopoly or extend the term of the patent.
    It simply gives the licensor a contractual right. Thus,
    nothing in the text of the Act even arguably forbids licens­
    ing agreements that provide for post-expiration royalties.
    Brulotte was thus a bald act of policymaking. It was not
    simply a case of incorrect statutory interpretation. It was
    not really statutory interpretation at all.
    B
    Not only was Brulotte based on policymaking, it was
    based on a policy that is difficult to defend. Indeed, in the
    intervening 50 years, its reasoning has been soundly
    refuted. See, e.g., 10 P. Areeda & H. Hovenkamp, Anti­
    trust Law: An Analysis of Antitrust Principles and Their
    Application ¶1782c.3, pp. 554–556 (3d ed. 2011); See &
    Caprio, The Trouble with Brulotte: The Patent Royalty
    Term and Patent Monopoly Extension, 
    1990 Utah L
    . Rev.
    813, 846–851; Scheiber v. Dolby Labs., Inc., 
    293 F.3d 1014
    , 1017 (CA7 2002); Brief for Petitioners 23–25, and
    n. 11 (collecting sources); ante, at 3, n. 3.
    Brulotte misperceived the purpose and effect of post-
    expiration royalties. The decision rested on the view that
    Cite as: 576 U. S. ____ (2015)            3
    ALITO, J., dissenting
    post-expiration royalties extend the patent term by means
    of an anti-competitive tying arrangement. As the Court
    understood such an arrangement, the patent holder lever­
    ages its monopoly power during the patent term to require
    payments after the term ends, when the invention would
    otherwise be available for free public use. But agreements
    to pay licensing fees after a patent expires do not “enlarge
    the monopoly of the 
    patent.” 379 U.S., at 33
    . Instead,
    “[o]nce the patent term expires, the power to exclude is
    gone,” and all that is left “is a problem about optimal
    contract design.” Easterbrook, Contract and Copyright, 42
    Hous. L. Rev. 953, 955 (2005).
    The economics are simple: Extending a royalty term
    allows the parties to spread the licensing fees over a longer
    period of time, which naturally has the effect of reduc-
    ing the fees during the patent term. See ante, at 5. Re­
    stricting royalty payments to the patent term, as Brulotte
    requires, compresses payment into a shorter period of
    higher fees. The Patent Act does not prefer one approach
    over the other.
    There are, however, good reasons why parties some­
    times prefer post-expiration royalties over upfront fees,
    and why such arrangements have pro-competitive effects.
    Patent holders and licensees are often unsure whether a
    patented idea will yield significant economic value, and it
    often takes years to monetize an innovation. In those
    circumstances, deferred royalty agreements are economi­
    cally efficient. They encourage innovators, like universi­
    ties, hospitals, and other institutions, to invest in research
    that might not yield marketable products until decades
    down the line. See Brief for Memorial Sloan Kettering
    Cancer Center et al. as Amici Curiae 8–12. And they
    allow producers to hedge their bets and develop more
    products by spreading licensing fees over longer periods.
    See 
    ibid. By prohibiting these
    arrangements, Brulotte
    erects an obstacle to efficient patent use. In patent law
    4         KIMBLE v. MARVEL ENTERTAINMENT, LLC
    ALITO, J., dissenting
    and other areas, we have abandoned per se rules with
    similarly disruptive effects. See, e.g., Illinois Tool Works
    Inc. v. Independent Ink, Inc., 
    547 U.S. 28
    (2006); Leegin
    Creative Leather Products, Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 
    551 U.S. 877
    (2007).
    The majority downplays this harm by insisting that
    “parties can often find ways around Brulotte.” Ante, at 6.
    But the need to avoid Brulotte is an economic inefficiency
    in itself. Parties are not always aware of the prohibition—
    as this case amply demonstrates. And the suggested
    alternatives do not provide the same benefits as post-
    expiration royalty agreements. For instance, although an
    agreement to amortize payments for sales during the
    patent term would “bring down early outlays,” the Court
    admits that such an agreement might not reflect the
    parties’ risk preferences. Ante, at 6. Moreover, such an
    arrangement would not necessarily yield the same amount
    of total royalties, particularly for an invention or a medical
    breakthrough that takes decades to develop into a mar­
    ketable product. The sort of agreements that Brulotte
    prohibits would allow licensees to spread their costs, while
    also allowing patent holders to capitalize on slow-
    developing inventions.
    C
    On top of that, Brulotte most often functions to upset the
    parties’ expectations.
    This case illustrates the point. No one disputes that,
    when “negotiating the settlement, neither side was aware
    of Brulotte.” Ante, at 2. Without knowledge of our per se
    rule, the parties agreed that Marvel would pay 3% in
    royalties on all of its future sales involving the Web
    Blaster and similar products. If the parties had been
    aware of Brulotte, they might have agreed to higher pay­
    ments during the patent term. Instead, both sides ex­
    pected the royalty payments to continue until Marvel
    Cite as: 576 U. S. ____ (2015)            5
    ALITO, J., dissenting
    stopped selling toys that fit the terms of the agreement.
    But that is not what happened. When Marvel discovered
    Brulotte, it used that decision to nullify a key part of the
    agreement. The parties’ contractual expectations were
    shattered, and petitioners’ rights were extinguished.
    The Court’s suggestion that some parties have come to
    rely on Brulotte is fanciful. The Court believes that there
    is a “reasonable possibility that parties have structured
    their business transactions in light of Brulotte.” Ante, at
    10. Its only support for this conclusion is Marvel’s self-
    serving and unsupported assertion that some contracts
    might not specify an end date for royalties because the
    parties expect Brulotte to supply the default rule. To its
    credit, the Court stops short of endorsing this unlikely
    prediction, saying only that “uncertainty on this score cuts
    in Marvel’s direction.” Ante, at 10.
    But there is no real uncertainty. “[W]e do not know” if
    Marvel’s assertion is correct because Marvel has provided
    no evidence to support it. 
    Ibid. And there are
    reasons to
    believe that, if parties actually relied on Brulotte to supply
    a default rule, courts would enforce the contracts as the
    parties expected. See, e.g., 27 R. Lord, Williston on Con­
    tracts §70:124 (4th ed. 2003). What we know for sure,
    however, is that Brulotte has upended the parties’ expec­
    tations here and in many other cases. See, e.g., 
    Scheiber, 293 F.3d, at 1016
    ; Boggild v. Kenner Products, 
    853 F.2d 465
    , 466–467 (CA6 1988); Pitney Bowes, Inc. v. Mestre, 
    701 F.2d 1365
    , 1367, 1373 (CA11 1983). These confirmed
    problems with retaining Brulotte clearly outweigh Mar­
    vel’s hypothetical fears.
    II
    In the end, Brulotte’s only virtue is that we decided it.
    But that does not render it invincible. Stare decisis is
    important to the rule of law, but so are correct judicial
    decisions. Adherence to prior decisions “ ‘promotes the
    6        KIMBLE v. MARVEL ENTERTAINMENT, LLC
    ALITO, J., dissenting
    evenhanded, predictable, and consistent development of
    legal principles, fosters reliance on judicial decisions, and
    contributes to the actual and perceived integrity of the
    judicial process.’ ” Pearson v. Callahan, 
    555 U.S. 223
    , 233
    (2009) (quoting Payne v. Tennessee, 
    501 U.S. 808
    , 827
    (1991)). But stare decisis is not an “inexorable command.”
    
    Payne, supra, at 828
    ; Washington v. W. C. Dawson & Co.,
    
    264 U.S. 219
    , 238 (1924) (Brandeis, J., dissenting). “Re­
    visiting precedent is particularly appropriate where, as
    here, a departure would not upset expectations, the prece­
    dent consists of a judge-made rule . . . , and experience has
    pointed up the precedent’s shortcomings.” 
    Pearson, supra, at 233
    .
    Our traditional approach to stare decisis does not re­
    quire us to retain Brulotte’s per se rule. Brulotte’s holding
    had no basis in the law. Its reasoning has been thoroughly
    disproved. It poses economic barriers that stifle innova­
    tion. And it unsettles contractual expectations.
    It is not decisive that Congress could have altered
    Brulotte’s rule. In general, we are especially reluctant to
    overturn decisions interpreting statutes because those
    decisions can be undone by Congress. See, e.g., John R.
    Sand & Gravel Co. v. United States, 
    552 U.S. 130
    , 139
    (2008); Patterson v. McLean Credit Union, 
    491 U.S. 164
    ,
    172–173 (1989). The Court calls this a “superpowered
    form of stare decisis” that renders statutory interpretation
    decisions nearly impervious to challenge. Ante, at 10. I
    think this goes a bit too far.
    As an initial matter, we do not give super-duper protec­
    tion to decisions that do not actually interpret a statute.
    When a precedent is based on a judge-made rule and is not
    grounded in anything that Congress has enacted, we
    cannot “properly place on the shoulders of Congress” the
    entire burden of correcting “the Court’s own error.”
    Girouard v. United States, 
    328 U.S. 61
    , 69–70 (1946). On
    the contrary, we have recognized that it is appropriate for
    Cite as: 576 U. S. ____ (2015)             7
    ALITO, J., dissenting
    us to correct rules of this sort. See, e.g., 
    Leegin, 551 U.S., at 899
    –900; State Oil Co. v. Khan, 
    522 U.S. 3
    , 20–21
    (1997).
    The Court says that it might agree if Brulotte were an
    antitrust precedent because stare decisis has “less-than­
    usual force in cases involving the Sherman Act.” Ante, at
    14. But this distinction is unwarranted. We have been
    more willing to reexamine antitrust precedents because
    they have attributes of common-law decisions. I see no
    reason why the same approach should not apply where the
    precedent at issue, while purporting to apply a statute, is
    actually based on policy concerns. Indeed, we should be
    even more willing to reconsider such a precedent because
    the role implicitly assigned to the federal courts under the
    Sherman Act has no parallel in Patent Act cases.
    Even taking the Court on its own terms, Brulotte was an
    antitrust decision masquerading as a patent case. The
    Court was principally concerned with patentees improp­
    erly leveraging their monopoly power. 
    See 379 U.S., at 32
    –
    33. And it expressly characterized post-expiration royal­
    ties as anti-competitive tying arrangements. See 
    id., at 33.
    It makes no sense to afford greater stare decisis pro­
    tection to Brulotte’s thinly veiled antitrust reasoning than
    to our Sherman Act decisions.
    The Court also places too much weight on Congress’
    failure to overturn Brulotte. We have long cautioned that
    “[i]t is at best treacherous to find in congressional silence
    alone the adoption of a controlling rule of law.” 
    Girouard, supra, at 69
    . Even where Congress has considered, but
    not adopted, legislation that would abrogate a judicial
    ruling, it cannot be inferred that Congress’ failure to act
    shows that it approves the ruling. See Central Bank of
    Denver, N. A. v. First Interstate Bank of Denver, N. A., 
    511 U.S. 164
    , 187 (1994). “ ‘[S]everal equally tenable infer­
    ences may be drawn from such inaction.’ ” 
    Ibid. (quoting Pension Benefit
    Guaranty Corporation v. LTV Corp., 496
    8        KIMBLE v. MARVEL ENTERTAINMENT, LLC
    ALITO, J., dissenting
    U. S. 633, 650 (1990)).
    Passing legislation is no easy task. A federal statute
    must withstand the “finely wrought” procedure of bicam­
    eralism and presentment. INS v. Chadha, 
    462 U.S. 919
    ,
    951 (1983); Clinton v. City of New York, 
    524 U.S. 417
    , 440
    (1998); see U. S. Const., Art. I, §7. Within that onerous
    process, there are additional practical hurdles. A law
    must be taken up for discussion and not passed over in
    favor of more pressing matters, and Senate rules require
    60 votes to end debate on most legislation. And even if the
    House and Senate agree on a general policy, the details of
    the measure usually must be hammered out in a confer­
    ence committee and repassed by both Houses.
    *    *   *
    A proper understanding of our doctrine of stare decisis
    does not prevent us from reexamining Brulotte. Even the
    Court does not defend the decision on the merits. I would
    reconsider and overrule our obvious mistake. For these
    reasons, I respectfully dissent.
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 13–720.

Judges: Kagan

Filed Date: 6/22/2015

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 10/19/2024

Authorities (21)

Patterson v. McLean Credit Union ( 1989 )

Leegin Creative Leather Products, Inc. v. PSKS, Inc. ( 2007 )

Edward Katzinger Co. v. Chicago Metallic Manufacturing Co. ( 1947 )

Bonito Boats, Inc. v. Thunder Craft Boats, Inc. ( 1989 )

Illinois Tool Works Inc. v. Independent Ink, Inc. ( 2006 )

Bilski v. Kappos ( 2010 )

Immigration & Naturalization Service v. Chadha ( 1983 )

Girouard v. United States ( 1946 )

Peter Scheiber v. Dolby Laboratories, Inc., and Dolby ... ( 2002 )

Compco Corp. v. Day-Brite Lighting, Inc. ( 1964 )

Sears, Roebuck & Co. v. Stiffel Co. ( 1964 )

Payne v. Tennessee ( 1991 )

State Oil Co. v. Khan ( 1997 )

Pearson v. Callahan ( 2009 )

Washington v. W. C. Dawson & Co. ( 1924 )

United States v. Detroit Timber & Lumber Co. ( 1906 )

Pitney Bowes, Inc., Cross-Appellee v. Celina Mestre, ... ( 1983 )

Lear, Inc. v. Adkins ( 1969 )

Clinton v. City of New York ( 1998 )

John R. Sand & Gravel Co. v. United States ( 2008 )

View All Authorities »

Cited By (57)

Randall T. Deviney v. State of Florida ( 2021 )

State v. R. Tome ( 2021 )

Keranos, LLC v. Silicon Storage Technology, Inc. ( 2015 )

William Ochadleus v. City of Detroit ( 2016 )

United States v. Hamid Mohamed Ahmed Ali Rehaif ( 2017 )

United States v. Hamid Mohamed Ahmed Ali Rehaif ( 2018 )

Bayer Cropscience Ag v. Dow Agrosciences LLC ( 2017 )

Shiel v. Rowell ( 2018 )

State of Texas v. USA ( 2019 )

High Point Sarl v. T-Mobile USA, Inc. ( 2016 )

Enzon Pharmaceuticals, Inc. v. Nektar Therapeutics ( 2016 )

Taylor v. Martha's Vineyard Land Bank Commission ( 2016 )

Clark D. Frazier v. State of Tennessee - Dissenting ( 2016 )

Samara v. Matar ( 2018 )

Lipton v. United States Environmental Protection Agency ( 2018 )

Abbvie Inc. v. Medimmune Limited ( 2018 )

State v. Patrick J. Lynch ( 2016 )

Howard County Assessor v. Kohl's Indiana LP ( 2016 )

Committee on the Judiciary of the U.S. House of ... ( 2019 )

State of Texas v. USA ( 2019 )

View All Citing Opinions »