Michigan v. Envtl. Prot. Agency , 135 S. Ct. 2699 ( 2015 )


Menu:
  • (Slip Opinion)              OCTOBER TERM, 2014                                       1
    Syllabus
    NOTE: Where it is feasible, a syllabus (headnote) will be released, as is
    being done in connection with this case, at the time the opinion is issued.
    The syllabus constitutes no part of the opinion of the Court but has been
    prepared by the Reporter of Decisions for the convenience of the reader.
    See United States v. Detroit Timber & Lumber Co., 
    200 U. S. 321
    , 337.
    SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES
    Syllabus
    MICHIGAN ET AL. v. ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION
    AGENCY ET AL.
    CERTIORARI TO THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR
    THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA CIRCUIT*
    No. 14–46. Argued March 25, 2015—Decided June 29, 2015
    The Clean Air Act directs the Environmental Protection Agency to reg-
    ulate emissions of hazardous air pollutants from certain stationary
    sources (such as refineries and factories). 
    42 U. S. C. §7412
    . The
    Agency may regulate power plants under this program only if it con-
    cludes that “regulation is appropriate and necessary” after studying
    hazards to public health posed by power-plant emissions.
    §7412(n)(1)(A). Here, EPA found power-plant regulation “appropri-
    ate” because the plants’ emissions pose risks to public health and the
    environment and because controls capable of reducing these emis-
    sions were available. It found regulation “necessary” because the im-
    position of other Clean Air Act requirements did not eliminate those
    risks. The Agency refused to consider cost when making its decision.
    It estimated, however, that the cost of its regulations to power plants
    would be $9.6 billion a year, but the quantifiable benefits from the
    resulting reduction in hazardous-air-pollutant emissions would be $4
    to $6 million a year. Petitioners (including 23 States) sought review
    of EPA’s rule in the D. C. Circuit, which upheld the Agency’s refusal
    to consider costs in its decision to regulate.
    Held: EPA interpreted §7412(n)(1)(A) unreasonably when it deemed
    cost irrelevant to the decision to regulate power plants. Pp. 5–15.
    (a) Agency action is unlawful if it does not rest “ ‘on a consideration
    ——————
    *Together with No. 14–47, Utility Air Regulatory Group v. Environ-
    mental Protection Agency et al., and No. 14–49, National Mining Assn.
    v. Environmental Protection Agency et al., also on certiorari to the same
    court.
    2                          MICHIGAN v. EPA
    Syllabus
    of the relevant factors.’ ” Motor Vehicle Mfrs. Assn. of United States,
    Inc. v. State Farm Mut. Automobile Ins. Co., 
    463 U. S. 29
    , 43. Even
    under the deferential standard of Chevron U. S. A. Inc. v. Natural
    Resources Defense Council, Inc., 
    467 U. S. 837
    , which directs courts to
    accept an agency’s reasonable resolution of an ambiguity in a statute
    that the agency administers, 
    id.,
     at 842–843, EPA strayed well be-
    yond the bounds of reasonable interpretation in concluding that cost
    is not a factor relevant to the appropriateness of regulating power
    plants. Pp. 5–6.
    (b) “Appropriate and necessary” is a capacious phrase. Read natu-
    rally against the backdrop of established administrative law, this
    phrase plainly encompasses cost. It is not rational, never mind “ap-
    propriate,” to impose billions of dollars in economic costs in return for
    a few dollars in health or environmental benefits. Statutory context
    supports this reading. Section 7412(n)(1) required the EPA to con-
    duct three studies, including one that reflects concern about cost, see
    §7412(n)(1)(B); and the Agency agrees that the term “appropriate and
    necessary” must be interpreted in light of all three studies. Pp. 6–9.
    (c) EPA’s counterarguments are unpersuasive. That other Clean
    Air Act provisions expressly mention cost only shows that
    §7412(n)(1)(A)’s broad reference to appropriateness encompasses
    multiple relevant factors, one of which is cost. Similarly, the modest
    principle of Whitman v. American Trucking Assns., Inc., 
    531 U. S. 457
    —when the Clean Air Act expressly directs EPA to regulate on
    the basis of a discrete factor that does not include cost, the Act should
    not be read as implicitly allowing consideration of cost anyway—has
    no bearing on this case. Furthermore, the possibility of considering
    cost at a later stage, when deciding how much to regulate power
    plants, does not establish its irrelevance at this stage. And although
    the Clean Air Act makes cost irrelevant to the initial decision to regu-
    late sources other than power plants, the whole point of having a
    separate provision for power plants was to treat power plants differ-
    ently. Pp. 9–12.
    (d) EPA must consider cost—including cost of compliance—before
    deciding whether regulation is appropriate and necessary. It will be
    up to the Agency to decide (as always, within the limits of reasonable
    interpretation) how to account for cost. Pp. 12–15.
    
    748 F. 3d 1222
    , reversed and remanded.
    SCALIA, J., delivered the opinion of the Court, in which ROBERTS,
    C. J., and KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., joined. THOMAS, J., filed a
    concurring opinion. KAGAN, J., filed a dissenting opinion, in which
    GINSBURG, BREYER, and SOTOMAYOR, JJ., joined.
    Cite as: 576 U. S. ____ (2015)                              1
    Opinion of the Court
    NOTICE: This opinion is subject to formal revision before publication in the
    preliminary print of the United States Reports. Readers are requested to
    notify the Reporter of Decisions, Supreme Court of the United States, Wash-
    ington, D. C. 20543, of any typographical or other formal errors, in order
    that corrections may be made before the preliminary print goes to press.
    SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES
    _________________
    Nos. 14–46, 14–47, and 14–49
    _________________
    MICHIGAN, ET AL., PETITIONERS
    14–46                 v.
    ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION AGENCY, ET AL.
    UTILITY AIR REGULATORY GROUP, PETITIONER
    14–47                v.
    ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION AGENCY, ET AL.
    NATIONAL MINING ASSOCIATION, PETITIONER
    14–49               v.
    ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION AGENCY, ET AL.
    ON WRITS OF CERTIORARI TO THE UNITED STATES COURT OF
    APPEALS FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA CIRCUIT
    [June 29, 2015]
    JUSTICE SCALIA delivered the opinion of the Court.
    The Clean Air Act directs the Environmental Protection
    Agency to regulate emissions of hazardous air pollutants
    from power plants if the Agency finds regulation “appro-
    priate and necessary.” We must decide whether it was
    reasonable for EPA to refuse to consider cost when making
    this finding.
    I
    The Clean Air Act establishes a series of regulatory
    2                    MICHIGAN v. EPA
    Opinion of the Court
    programs to control air pollution from stationary sources
    (such as refineries and factories) and moving sources (such
    as cars and airplanes). 
    69 Stat. 322
    , as amended, 
    42 U. S. C. §§7401
    –7671q. One of these is the National
    Emissions Standards for Hazardous Air Pollutants Pro-
    gram—the hazardous-air-pollutants program, for short.
    Established in its current form by the Clean Air Act
    Amendments of 1990, 
    104 Stat. 2531
    , this program targets
    for regulation stationary-source emissions of more than
    180 specified “hazardous air pollutants.” §7412(b).
    For stationary sources in general, the applicability of
    the program depends in part on how much pollution the
    source emits. A source that emits more than 10 tons of a
    single pollutant or more than 25 tons of a combination of
    pollutants per year is called a major source. §7412(a)(1).
    EPA is required to regulate all major sources under the
    program. §7412(c)(1)–(2). A source whose emissions do
    not cross the just-mentioned thresholds is called an area
    source. §7412(a)(2). The Agency is required to regulate an
    area source under the program if it “presents a threat of
    adverse effects to human health or the environment . . .
    warranting regulation.” §7412(c)(3).
    At the same time, Congress established a unique proce-
    dure to determine the applicability of the program to
    fossil-fuel-fired power plants. The Act refers to these
    plants as electric utility steam generating units, but we
    will simply call them power plants. Quite apart from the
    hazardous-air-pollutants program, the Clean Air Act
    Amendments of 1990 subjected power plants to various
    regulatory requirements. The parties agree that these
    requirements were expected to have the collateral effect of
    reducing power plants’ emissions of hazardous air pollu-
    tants, although the extent of the reduction was unclear.
    Congress directed the Agency to “perform a study of the
    hazards to public health reasonably anticipated to occur as
    a result of emissions by [power plants] of [hazardous air
    Cite as: 576 U. S. ____ (2015)           3
    Opinion of the Court
    pollutants] after imposition of the requirements of this
    chapter.” §7412(n)(1)(A). If the Agency “finds . . . regula-
    tion is appropriate and necessary after considering the
    results of the study,” it “shall regulate [power plants]
    under [§7412].” Ibid. EPA has interpreted the Act to
    mean that power plants become subject to regulation on
    the same terms as ordinary major and area sources, see 
    77 Fed. Reg. 9330
     (2012), and we assume without deciding
    that it was correct to do so.
    And what are those terms? EPA must first divide
    sources covered by the program into categories and sub-
    categories in accordance with statutory criteria.
    §7412(c)(1). For each category or subcategory, the Agency
    must promulgate certain minimum emission regulations,
    known as floor standards. §7412(d)(1), (3). The statute
    generally calibrates the floor standards to reflect the
    emissions limitations already achieved by the best-
    performing 12% of sources within the category or subcate-
    gory. §7412(d)(3). In some circumstances, the Agency
    may also impose more stringent emission regulations,
    known as beyond-the-floor standards. The statute ex-
    pressly requires the Agency to consider cost (alongside
    other specified factors) when imposing beyond-the-floor
    standards. §7412(d)(2).
    EPA completed the study required by §7412(n)(1)(A) in
    1998, 
    65 Fed. Reg. 79826
     (2000), and concluded that regu-
    lation of coal- and oil-fired power plants was “appropriate
    and necessary” in 2000, 
    id., at 79830
    . In 2012, it reaf-
    firmed the appropriate-and-necessary finding, divided
    power plants into subcategories, and promulgated floor
    standards. The Agency found regulation “appropriate”
    because (1) power plants’ emissions of mercury and other
    hazardous air pollutants posed risks to human health and
    the environment and (2) controls were available to reduce
    these emissions. 
    77 Fed. Reg. 9363
    . It found regulation
    “necessary” because the imposition of the Act’s other
    4                    MICHIGAN v. EPA
    Opinion of the Court
    requirements did not eliminate these risks. 
    Ibid.
     EPA
    concluded that “costs should not be considered” when
    deciding whether power plants should be regulated under
    §7412. Id., at 9326.
    In accordance with Executive Order, the Agency issued
    a “Regulatory Impact Analysis” alongside its regulation.
    This analysis estimated that the regulation would force
    power plants to bear costs of $9.6 billion per year. Id., at
    9306. The Agency could not fully quantify the benefits of
    reducing power plants’ emissions of hazardous air pollu-
    tants; to the extent it could, it estimated that these bene-
    fits were worth $4 to $6 million per year. Ibid. The costs
    to power plants were thus between 1,600 and 2,400 times
    as great as the quantifiable benefits from reduced emis-
    sions of hazardous air pollutants. The Agency continued
    that its regulations would have ancillary benefits—
    including cutting power plants’ emissions of particulate
    matter and sulfur dioxide, substances that are not covered
    by the hazardous-air-pollutants program. Although the
    Agency’s appropriate-and-necessary finding did not rest on
    these ancillary effects, id., at 9320, the regulatory impact
    analysis took them into account, increasing the Agency’s
    estimate of the quantifiable benefits of its regulation to
    $37 to $90 billion per year, id., at 9306. EPA concedes
    that the regulatory impact analysis “played no role” in its
    appropriate-and-necessary finding.        Brief for Federal
    Respondents 14.
    Petitioners (who include 23 States) sought review of
    EPA’s rule in the Court of Appeals for the D. C. Circuit.
    As relevant here, they challenged the Agency’s refusal to
    consider cost when deciding whether to regulate power
    plants. The Court of Appeals upheld the Agency’s decision
    not to consider cost, with Judge Kavanaugh concurring in
    part and dissenting in part. White Stallion Energy Center,
    LLC v. EPA, 
    748 F. 3d 1222
     (2014) (per curiam). We
    granted certiorari. 574 U. S. ___ (2014).
    Cite as: 576 U. S. ____ (2015)            5
    Opinion of the Court
    II
    Federal administrative agencies are required to engage
    in “reasoned decisionmaking.” Allentown Mack Sales &
    Service, Inc. v. NLRB, 
    522 U. S. 359
    , 374 (1998) (internal
    quotation marks omitted). “Not only must an agency’s
    decreed result be within the scope of its lawful authority,
    but the process by which it reaches that result must be
    logical and rational.” 
    Ibid.
     It follows that agency action is
    lawful only if it rests “on a consideration of the relevant
    factors.” Motor Vehicle Mfrs. Assn. of United States, Inc. v.
    State Farm Mut. Automobile Ins. Co., 
    463 U. S. 29
    , 43
    (1983) (internal quotation marks omitted).
    EPA’s decision to regulate power plants under §7412
    allowed the Agency to reduce power plants’ emissions of
    hazardous air pollutants and thus to improve public
    health and the environment. But the decision also ulti-
    mately cost power plants, according to the Agency’s own
    estimate, nearly $10 billion a year. EPA refused to con-
    sider whether the costs of its decision outweighed the
    benefits. The Agency gave cost no thought at all, be-
    cause it considered cost irrelevant to its initial decision to
    regulate.
    EPA’s disregard of cost rested on its interpretation of
    §7412(n)(1)(A), which, to repeat, directs the Agency to
    regulate power plants if it “finds such regulation is appro-
    priate and necessary.” The Agency accepts that it could
    have interpreted this provision to mean that cost is rele-
    vant to the decision to add power plants to the program.
    Tr. of Oral Arg. 44. But it chose to read the statute to
    mean that cost makes no difference to the initial decision
    to regulate. See 
    76 Fed. Reg. 24988
     (2011) (“We further
    interpret the term ‘appropriate’ to not allow for the con-
    sideration of costs”); 
    77 Fed. Reg. 9327
     (“Cost does not
    have to be read into the definition of ‘appropriate’ ”).
    We review this interpretation under the standard set
    out in Chevron U. S. A. Inc. v. Natural Resources Defense
    6                    MICHIGAN v. EPA
    Opinion of the Court
    Council, Inc., 
    467 U. S. 837
     (1984). Chevron directs courts
    to accept an agency’s reasonable resolution of an ambigu-
    ity in a statute that the agency administers. 
    Id.,
     at 842–
    843. Even under this deferential standard, however,
    “agencies must operate within the bounds of reasonable
    interpretation. ” Utility Air Regulatory Group v. EPA, 573
    U. S. ___, ___ (2014) (slip op., at 16) (internal quotation
    marks omitted). EPA strayed far beyond those bounds
    when it read §7412(n)(1) to mean that it could ignore cost
    when deciding whether to regulate power plants.
    A
    The Clean Air Act treats power plants differently from
    other sources for purposes of the hazardous-air-pollutants
    program. Elsewhere in §7412, Congress established cab-
    ined criteria for EPA to apply when deciding whether to
    include sources in the program. It required the Agency to
    regulate sources whose emissions exceed specified numeri-
    cal thresholds (major sources). It also required the Agency
    to regulate sources whose emissions fall short of these
    thresholds (area sources) if they “presen[t] a threat of
    adverse effects to human health or the environment . . .
    warranting regulation.” §7412(c)(3). In stark contrast,
    Congress instructed EPA to add power plants to the pro-
    gram if (but only if) the Agency finds regulation “appro-
    priate and necessary.” §7412(n)(1)(A). One does not need
    to open up a dictionary in order to realize the capacious-
    ness of this phrase. In particular, “appropriate” is “the
    classic broad and all-encompassing term that naturally
    and traditionally includes consideration of all the relevant
    factors.” 748 F. 3d, at 1266 (opinion of Kavanaugh, J.).
    Although this term leaves agencies with flexibility, an
    agency may not “entirely fai[l] to consider an important
    aspect of the problem” when deciding whether regulation
    is appropriate. State Farm, 
    supra, at 43
    .
    Read naturally in the present context, the phrase “ap-
    Cite as: 576 U. S. ____ (2015)           7
    Opinion of the Court
    propriate and necessary” requires at least some attention
    to cost. One would not say that it is even rational, never
    mind “appropriate,” to impose billions of dollars in eco-
    nomic costs in return for a few dollars in health or envi-
    ronmental benefits. In addition, “cost” includes more than
    the expense of complying with regulations; any disad-
    vantage could be termed a cost. EPA’s interpretation
    precludes the Agency from considering any type of cost—
    including, for instance, harms that regulation might do to
    human health or the environment. The Government
    concedes that if the Agency were to find that emissions
    from power plants do damage to human health, but that
    the technologies needed to eliminate these emissions do
    even more damage to human health, it would still deem
    regulation appropriate. See Tr. of Oral Arg. 70. No regu-
    lation is “appropriate” if it does significantly more harm
    than good.
    There are undoubtedly settings in which the phrase
    “appropriate and necessary” does not encompass cost. But
    this is not one of them. Section 7412(n)(1)(A) directs EPA
    to determine whether “regulation is appropriate and nec-
    essary.” (Emphasis added.) Agencies have long treated
    cost as a centrally relevant factor when deciding whether
    to regulate. Consideration of cost reflects the understand-
    ing that reasonable regulation ordinarily requires paying
    attention to the advantages and the disadvantages of
    agency decisions. It also reflects the reality that “too
    much wasteful expenditure devoted to one problem may
    well mean considerably fewer resources available to deal
    effectively with other (perhaps more serious) problems.”
    Entergy Corp. v. Riverkeeper, Inc., 
    556 U. S. 208
    , 233
    (2009) (BREYER, J., concurring in part and dissenting in
    part). Against the backdrop of this established adminis-
    trative practice, it is unreasonable to read an instruction
    to an administrative agency to determine whether “regula-
    tion is appropriate and necessary” as an invitation to
    8                     MICHIGAN v. EPA
    Opinion of the Court
    ignore cost.
    Statutory context reinforces the relevance of cost. The
    procedures governing power plants that we consider today
    appear in §7412(n)(1), which bears the caption “Electric
    utility steam generating units.” In subparagraph (A), the
    part of the law that has occupied our attention so far,
    Congress required EPA to study the hazards to public
    health posed by power plants and to determine whether
    regulation is appropriate and necessary. But in subpara-
    graphs (B) and (C), Congress called for two additional
    studies. One of them, a study into mercury emissions
    from power plants and other sources, must consider “the
    health and environmental effects of such emissions, tech-
    nologies which are available to control such emissions,
    and the costs of such technologies.” §7412(n)(1)(B) (em-
    phasis added). This directive to EPA to study cost is a
    further indication of the relevance of cost to the decision to
    regulate.
    In an effort to minimize this express reference to cost,
    EPA now argues that §7412(n)(1)(A) requires it to consider
    only the study mandated by that provision, not the sepa-
    rate mercury study, before deciding whether to regulate
    power plants. But when adopting the regulations before
    us, the Agency insisted that the provisions concerning all
    three studies “provide a framework for [EPA’s] determina-
    tion of whether to regulate [power plants].” 
    76 Fed. Reg. 24987
    . It therefore decided “to interpret the scope of the
    appropriate and necessary finding in the context of all
    three studies.” 
    77 Fed. Reg. 9325
     (emphasis added). For
    example:
     EPA considered environmental effects relevant to the
    appropriate-and-necessary finding. It deemed the
    mercury study’s reference to this factor “direct evi-
    dence that Congress was concerned with environmen-
    tal effects.” 
    76 Fed. Reg. 24987
    .
    Cite as: 576 U. S. ____ (2015)            9
    Opinion of the Court
     EPA considered availability of controls relevant to the
    appropriate-and-necessary finding. It thought that
    doing so was “consistent with” the mercury study’s
    reference to availability of controls. 
    Id., at 24989
    .
     EPA concluded that regulation of power plants would
    be appropriate and necessary even if a single pollu-
    tant emitted by them posed a hazard to health or the
    environment. It believed that “Congress’ focus” on a
    single pollutant in the mercury study “support[ed]”
    this interpretation. 
    Ibid.
    EPA has not explained why §7412(n)(1)(B)’s reference to
    “environmental effects . . . and . . . costs” provides “direct
    evidence that Congress was concerned with environmental
    effects,” but not “direct evidence” that it was concerned
    with cost. Chevron allows agencies to choose among com-
    peting reasonable interpretations of a statute; it does not
    license interpretive gerrymanders under which an agency
    keeps parts of statutory context it likes while throwing
    away parts it does not.
    B
    EPA identifies a handful of reasons to interpret
    §7412(n)(1)(A) to mean that cost is irrelevant to the initial
    decision to regulate. We find those reasons unpersuasive.
    EPA points out that other parts of the Clean Air Act
    expressly mention cost, while §7412(n)(1)(A) does not. But
    this observation shows only that §7412(n)(1)(A)’s broad
    reference to appropriateness encompasses multiple rele-
    vant factors (which include but are not limited to cost);
    other provisions’ specific references to cost encompass just
    cost. It is unreasonable to infer that, by expressly making
    cost relevant to other decisions, the Act implicitly makes
    cost irrelevant to the appropriateness of regulating power
    plants. (By way of analogy, the Fourth Amendment’s
    Reasonableness Clause requires searches to be
    10                    MICHIGAN v. EPA
    Opinion of the Court
    “[r]easonable,” while its Warrant Clause requires war-
    rants to be supported by “probable cause.” Nobody would
    argue that, by expressly making level of suspicion relevant
    to the validity of a warrant, the Fourth Amendment im-
    plicitly makes level of suspicion categorically irrelevant to
    the reasonableness of a search. To the contrary, all would
    agree that the expansive word “reasonable” encompasses
    degree of suspicion alongside other relevant circumstances.)
    Other parts of the Clean Air Act also expressly men-
    tion environmental effects, while §7412(n)(1)(A) does not.
    Yet that did not stop EPA from deeming environmental
    effects relevant to the appropriateness of regulating power
    plants.
    Along similar lines, EPA seeks support in this Court’s
    decision in Whitman v. American Trucking Assns., Inc.,
    
    531 U. S. 457
     (2001). There, the Court addressed a provi-
    sion of the Clean Air Act requiring EPA to set ambient air
    quality standards at levels “requisite to protect the public
    health” with an “adequate margin of safety.” 
    42 U. S. C. §7409
    (b). Read naturally, that discrete criterion does not
    encompass cost; it encompasses health and safety. The
    Court refused to read that provision as carrying with it an
    implicit authorization to consider cost, in part because
    authority to consider cost had “elsewhere, and so often,
    been expressly granted.” 
    531 U. S., at 467
    . American
    Trucking thus establishes the modest principle that where
    the Clean Air Act expressly directs EPA to regulate on the
    basis of a factor that on its face does not include cost, the
    Act normally should not be read as implicitly allowing the
    Agency to consider cost anyway. That principle has no
    application here. “Appropriate and necessary” is a far
    more comprehensive criterion than “requisite to protect
    the public health”; read fairly and in context, as we have
    explained, the term plainly subsumes consideration of
    cost.
    Turning to the mechanics of the hazardous-air-
    Cite as: 576 U. S. ____ (2015)           11
    Opinion of the Court
    pollutants program, EPA argues that it need not consider
    cost when first deciding whether to regulate power plants
    because it can consider cost later when deciding how much
    to regulate them. The question before us, however, is the
    meaning of the “appropriate and necessary” standard that
    governs the initial decision to regulate. And as we have
    discussed, context establishes that this expansive stand-
    ard encompasses cost. Cost may become relevant again at
    a later stage of the regulatory process, but that possibility
    does not establish its irrelevance at this stage. In addi-
    tion, once the Agency decides to regulate power plants, it
    must promulgate certain minimum or floor standards no
    matter the cost (here, nearly $10 billion a year); the
    Agency may consider cost only when imposing regulations
    beyond these minimum standards. By EPA’s logic, some-
    one could decide whether it is “appropriate” to buy a Fer-
    rari without thinking about cost, because he plans to think
    about cost later when deciding whether to upgrade the
    sound system.
    EPA argues that the Clean Air Act makes cost irrele-
    vant to the initial decision to regulate sources other than
    power plants. The Agency claims that it is reasonable to
    interpret §7412(n)(1)(A) in a way that “harmonizes” the
    program’s treatment of power plants with its treatment of
    other sources. This line of reasoning overlooks the whole
    point of having a separate provision about power plants:
    treating power plants differently from other stationary
    sources. Congress crafted narrow standards for EPA to
    apply when deciding whether to regulate other sources; in
    general, these standards concern the volume of pollution
    emitted by the source, §7412(c)(1), and the threat posed by
    the source “to human health or the environment,”
    §7412(c)(3). But Congress wrote the provision before us
    more expansively, directing the Agency to regulate power
    plants if “appropriate and necessary.” “That congressional
    election settles this case. [The Agency’s] preference for
    12                   MICHIGAN v. EPA
    Opinion of the Court
    symmetry cannot trump an asymmetrical statute.” CSX
    Transp., Inc. v. Alabama Dept. of Revenue, 
    562 U. S. 277
    ,
    296 (2011).
    EPA persists that Congress treated power plants differ-
    ently from other sources because of uncertainty about
    whether regulation of power plants would still be needed
    after the application of the rest of the Act’s requirements.
    That is undoubtedly one of the reasons Congress treated
    power plants differently; hence §7412(n)(1)(A)’s require-
    ment to study hazards posed by power plants’ emissions
    “after imposition of the requirements of [the rest of the
    Act].” But if uncertainty about the need for regulation
    were the only reason to treat power plants differently,
    Congress would have required the Agency to decide only
    whether regulation remains “necessary,” not whether
    regulation is “appropriate and necessary.” In any event,
    EPA stated when it adopted the rule that “Congress did
    not limit [the] appropriate and necessary inquiry to [the
    study mentioned in §7412(n)(1)(A)].” 
    77 Fed. Reg. 9325
    .
    The Agency instead decided that the appropriate-and-
    necessary finding should be understood in light of all three
    studies required by §7412(n)(1), and as we have discussed,
    one of those three studies reflects concern about cost.
    C
    The dissent does not embrace EPA’s far-reaching claim
    that Congress made costs altogether irrelevant to the
    decision to regulate power plants. Instead, it maintains
    that EPA need not “explicitly analyze costs” before deem-
    ing regulation appropriate, because other features of the
    regulatory program will on their own ensure the cost-
    effectiveness of regulation. Post, at 2 (opinion of KAGAN,
    J.). This line of reasoning contradicts the foundational
    principle of administrative law that a court may uphold
    agency action only on the grounds that the agency invoked
    when it took the action. SEC v. Chenery Corp., 318 U. S.
    Cite as: 576 U. S. ____ (2015)           13
    Opinion of the Court
    80, 87 (1943). When it deemed regulation of power plants
    appropriate, EPA said that cost was irrelevant to that
    determination—not that cost-benefit analysis would be
    deferred until later. Much less did it say (what the dissent
    now concludes) that the consideration of cost at subse-
    quent stages will ensure that the costs are not dispropor-
    tionate to the benefits. What it said is that cost is irrele-
    vant to the decision to regulate.
    That is enough to decide these cases. But for what it is
    worth, the dissent vastly overstates the influence of cost at
    later stages of the regulatory process. For example, the
    dissent claims that the floor standards—which the Act
    calibrates to reflect emissions limitations already achieved
    by the best-performing sources in the industry—reflect
    cost considerations, because the best-performing power
    plants “must have considered costs in arriving at their
    emissions outputs.” Post, at 10. EPA did not rely on this
    argument, and it is not obvious that it is correct. Because
    power plants are regulated under other federal and state
    laws, the best-performing power plants’ emissions limita-
    tions might reflect cost-blind regulation rather than cost-
    conscious decisions. Similarly, the dissent suggests that
    EPA may consider cost when dividing sources into catego-
    ries and subcategories. Post, at 11–12. Yet according to
    EPA, “it is not appropriate to premise subcategorization on
    costs.” 
    77 Fed. Reg. 9395
     (emphasis added). That state-
    ment presumably explains the dissent’s carefully worded
    observation that EPA considered “technological, geographic,
    and other factors” when drawing categories, post, at 13,
    n. 4, which factors were in turn “related to costs” in some
    way, post, at 11. Attenuated connections such as these
    hardly support the assertion that EPA’s regulatory process
    featured “exhaustive consideration of costs,” post, at 2.
    All in all, the dissent has at most shown that some
    elements of the regulatory scheme mitigate cost in limited
    ways; it has not shown that these elements ensure cost-
    14                   MICHIGAN v. EPA
    Opinion of the Court
    effectiveness. If (to take a hypothetical example) regulat-
    ing power plants would yield $5 million in benefits, the
    prospect of mitigating cost from $11 billion to $10 billion
    at later stages of the program would not by itself make
    regulation appropriate. In all events, we need not pursue
    these points, because EPA did not say that the parts of the
    regulatory program mentioned by the dissent prevent the
    imposition of costs far in excess of benefits. “[EPA’s]
    action must be measured by what [it] did, not by what it
    might have done.” Chenery, supra, at 93–94.
    D
    Our reasoning so far establishes that it was unreasona-
    ble for EPA to read §7412(n)(1)(A) to mean that cost is
    irrelevant to the initial decision to regulate power plants.
    The Agency must consider cost—including, most im-
    portantly, cost of compliance—before deciding whether
    regulation is appropriate and necessary. We need not and
    do not hold that the law unambiguously required the
    Agency, when making this preliminary estimate, to con-
    duct a formal cost-benefit analysis in which each ad-
    vantage and disadvantage is assigned a monetary value.
    It will be up to the Agency to decide (as always, within the
    limits of reasonable interpretation) how to account for
    cost.
    Some of the respondents supporting EPA ask us to
    uphold EPA’s action because the accompanying regulatory
    impact analysis shows that, once the rule’s ancillary bene-
    fits are considered, benefits plainly outweigh costs. The
    dissent similarly relies on these ancillary benefits when
    insisting that “the outcome here [was] a rule whose bene-
    fits exceed its costs.” Post, at 16. As we have just ex-
    plained, however, we may uphold agency action only upon
    the grounds on which the agency acted. Even if the Agen-
    cy could have considered ancillary benefits when deciding
    whether regulation is appropriate and necessary—a point
    Cite as: 576 U. S. ____ (2015)                 15
    Opinion of the Court
    we need not address—it plainly did not do so here. In the
    Agency’s own words, the administrative record “utterly
    refutes [the] assertion that [ancillary benefits] form the
    basis for the appropriate and necessary finding.” 
    77 Fed. Reg. 9323
    . The Government concedes, moreover, that
    “EPA did not rely on the [regulatory impact analysis]
    when deciding to regulate power plants,” and that “[e]ven
    if EPA had considered costs, it would not necessarily have
    adopted . . . the approach set forth in [that analysis].”
    Brief for Federal Respondents 53–54.
    *    *     *
    We hold that EPA interpreted §7412(n)(1)(A) unreason-
    ably when it deemed cost irrelevant to the decision to
    regulate power plants. We reverse the judgment of the
    Court of Appeals for the D. C. Circuit and remand the
    cases for further proceedings consistent with this opinion.
    It is so ordered.
    Cite as: 576 U. S. ____ (2015)          1
    THOMAS, J., concurring
    SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES
    _________________
    Nos. 14–46, 14–47, and 14–49
    _________________
    MICHIGAN, ET AL., PETITIONERS
    14–46                 v.
    ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION AGENCY, ET AL.
    UTILITY AIR REGULATORY GROUP, PETITIONER
    14–47                v.
    ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION AGENCY, ET AL.
    NATIONAL MINING ASSOCIATION, PETITIONER
    14–49               v.
    ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION AGENCY, ET AL.
    ON WRITS OF CERTIORARI TO THE UNITED STATES COURT OF
    APPEALS FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA CIRCUIT
    [June 29, 2015]
    JUSTICE THOMAS, concurring.
    The Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) asks the
    Court to defer to its interpretation of the phrase “appro-
    priate and necessary” in §112(n)(1)(A) of the Clean Air
    Act, 
    42 U. S. C. §7412
    . JUSTICE SCALIA’s opinion for the
    Court demonstrates why EPA’s interpretation deserves no
    deference under our precedents. I write separately to note
    that its request for deference raises serious questions
    about the constitutionality of our broader practice of de-
    ferring to agency interpretations of federal statutes. See
    Chevron U. S. A. Inc. v. Natural Resources Defense Coun-
    cil, Inc., 
    467 U. S. 837
     (1984).
    Chevron deference is premised on “a presumption that
    Congress, when it left ambiguity in a statute meant for
    2                    MICHIGAN v. EPA
    THOMAS, J., concurring
    implementation by an agency, understood that the ambi-
    guity would be resolved, first and foremost, by the agency,
    and desired the agency (rather than the courts) to possess
    whatever degree of discretion the ambiguity allows.”
    Smiley v. Citibank (South Dakota), N. A., 
    517 U. S. 735
    ,
    740–741 (1996). We most often describe Congress’ sup-
    posed choice to leave matters to agency discretion as an
    allocation of interpretive authority. See, e.g., National
    Cable & Telecommunications Assn. v. Brand X Internet
    Services, 
    545 U. S. 967
    , 983 (2005) (referring to the agency
    as “the authoritative interpreter (within the limits of
    reason) of [ambiguous] statutes”). But we sometimes treat
    that discretion as though it were a form of legislative
    power. See, e.g., United States v. Mead Corp., 
    533 U. S. 218
    , 229 (2001) (noting that the agency “speak[s] with the
    force of law when it addresses ambiguity in the statute or
    fills a space in the enacted law” even when “ ‘Congress did
    not actually have an intent’ as to a particular result”).
    Either way, Chevron deference raises serious separation-
    of-powers questions.
    As I have explained elsewhere, “[T]he judicial power, as
    originally understood, requires a court to exercise its
    independent judgment in interpreting and expounding
    upon the laws.” Perez v. Mortgage Bankers Assn., 575
    U. S. ___, ___ (2015) (opinion concurring in judgment) (slip
    op., at 8). Interpreting federal statutes—including ambig-
    uous ones administered by an agency—“calls for that
    exercise of independent judgment.” 
    Id.,
     at ___ (slip op., at
    12). Chevron deference precludes judges from exercising
    that judgment, forcing them to abandon what they believe
    is “the best reading of an ambiguous statute” in favor of an
    agency’s construction. Brand X, supra, at 983. It thus
    wrests from Courts the ultimate interpretative authority
    to “say what the law is,” Marbury v. Madison, 
    1 Cranch 137
    , 177 (1803), and hands it over to the Executive. See
    Brand X, supra, at 983 (noting that the judicial construc-
    Cite as: 576 U. S. ____ (2015)             3
    THOMAS, J., concurring
    tion of an ambiguous statute is “not authoritative”). Such
    a transfer is in tension with Article III’s Vesting Clause,
    which vests the judicial power exclusively in Article III
    courts, not administrative agencies. U. S. Const., Art. III,
    §1.
    In reality, as the Court illustrates in the course of dis-
    mantling EPA’s interpretation of §112(n)(1)(A), agencies
    “interpreting” ambiguous statutes typically are not en-
    gaged in acts of interpretation at all. See, e.g., ante, at 9.
    Instead, as Chevron itself acknowledged, they are engaged
    in the “ ‘formulation of policy.’ ” 
    467 U. S., at 843
    . Statu-
    tory ambiguity thus becomes an implicit delegation of rule-
    making authority, and that authority is used not to find
    the best meaning of the text, but to formulate legally
    binding rules to fill in gaps based on policy judgments
    made by the agency rather than Congress.
    Although acknowledging this fact might allow us to
    escape the jaws of Article III’s Vesting Clause, it runs
    headlong into the teeth of Article I’s, which vests “[a]ll
    legislative Powers herein granted” in Congress. U. S.
    Const., Art I., §1. For if we give the “force of law” to agency
    pronouncements on matters of private conduct as to
    which “ ‘Congress did not actually have an intent,’ ” Mead,
    
    supra, at 229
    , we permit a body other than Congress to
    perform a function that requires an exercise of the legisla-
    tive power. See Department of Transportation v. Associa-
    tion of American Railroads, 575 U. S. ___, ___–___ (2015)
    (THOMAS, J., concurring in judgment) (slip op., at 21–22).
    These cases bring into bold relief the scope of the poten-
    tially unconstitutional delegations we have come to coun-
    tenance in the name of Chevron deference. What EPA
    claims for itself here is not the power to make political
    judgments in implementing Congress’ policies, nor even
    the power to make tradeoffs between competing policy
    goals set by Congress, American Railroads, 
    supra,
     at ___–
    ___ (opinion of THOMAS, J.) (slip op., at 20–21) (collecting
    4                         MICHIGAN v. EPA
    THOMAS, J., concurring
    cases involving statutes that delegated this legislative
    authority). It is the power to decide—without any particu-
    lar fidelity to the text—which policy goals EPA wishes to
    pursue. Should EPA wield its vast powers over electric
    utilities to protect public health? A pristine environment?
    Economic security? We are told that the breadth of the
    word “appropriate” authorizes EPA to decide for itself how
    to answer that question. Compare 
    77 Fed. Reg. 9327
    (2012) (“[N]othing about the definition [of “appropriate”]
    compels a consideration of costs” (emphasis added)) with
    Tr. of Oral Arg. 42 (“[T]he phrase appropriate and neces-
    sary doesn’t, by its terms, preclude the EPA from consider-
    ing cost” (emphasis added)).1
    Perhaps there is some unique historical justification for
    deferring to federal agencies, see Mead, 
    supra, at 243
    (SCALIA, J., dissenting), but these cases reveal how paltry
    an effort we have made to understand it or to confine
    ourselves to its boundaries. Although we hold today that
    EPA exceeded even the extremely permissive limits on
    agency power set by our precedents, we should be alarmed
    that it felt sufficiently emboldened by those precedents to
    make the bid for deference that it did here.2 As in other
    areas of our jurisprudence concerning administrative
    agencies, see, e.g., B&B Hardware, Inc. v. Hargis Indus-
    tries, Inc., 575 U. S. ___, ___–___ (2015) (THOMAS, J.,
    dissenting) (slip op., at 10–14), we seem to be straying
    ——————
    1I
    can think of no name for such power other than “legislative power.”
    Had we deferred to EPA’s interpretation in these cases, then, we might
    have violated another constitutional command by abdicating our check
    on the political branches—namely, our duty to enforce the rule of law
    through an exercise of the judicial power. Perez v. Mortgage Bankers
    Assn., 575 U. S. ___, ___–___ (2015) (THOMAS, J., concurring in judg-
    ment) (slip op., at 14–16).
    2 This is not the first time an agency has exploited our practice of
    deferring to agency interpretations of statutes. See, e.g., Texas Dept. of
    Housing and Community Affairs v. Inclusive Communities Project, Inc.,
    ante, at 6–7 (THOMAS, J., dissenting).
    Cite as: 576 U. S. ____ (2015)          5
    THOMAS, J., concurring
    further and further from the Constitution without so much
    as pausing to ask why. We should stop to consider that
    document before blithely giving the force of law to any
    other agency “interpretations” of federal statutes.
    Cite as: 576 U. S. ____ (2015)           1
    KAGAN, J., dissenting
    SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES
    _________________
    Nos. 14–46, 14–47, and 14–49
    _________________
    MICHIGAN, ET AL., PETITIONERS
    14–46                 v.
    ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION AGENCY, ET AL.
    UTILITY AIR REGULATORY GROUP, PETITIONER
    14–47                v.
    ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION AGENCY, ET AL.
    NATIONAL MINING ASSOCIATION, PETITIONER
    14–49               v.
    ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION AGENCY, ET AL.
    ON WRITS OF CERTIORARI TO THE UNITED STATES COURT OF
    APPEALS FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA CIRCUIT
    [June 29, 2015]
    JUSTICE KAGAN, with whom JUSTICE GINSBURG,
    JUSTICE BREYER, and JUSTICE SOTOMAYOR join,
    dissenting.
    The Environmental Protection Agency placed emissions
    limits on coal and oil power plants following a lengthy
    regulatory process during which the Agency carefully
    considered costs. At the outset, EPA determined that
    regulating plants’ emissions of hazardous air pollutants is
    “appropriate and necessary” given the harm they cause,
    and explained that it would take costs into account in
    developing suitable emissions standards.       Next, EPA
    divided power plants into groups based on technological
    and other characteristics bearing significantly on their
    cost structures. It required plants in each group to match
    2                    MICHIGAN v. EPA
    KAGAN, J., dissenting
    the emissions levels already achieved by the best-
    performing members of the same group—benchmarks
    necessarily reflecting those plants’ own cost analyses.
    EPA then adopted a host of measures designed to make
    compliance with its proposed emissions limits less costly
    for plants that needed to catch up with their cleaner peers.
    And with only one narrow exception, EPA decided not to
    impose any more stringent standards (beyond what some
    plants had already achieved on their own) because it found
    that doing so would not be cost-effective. After all that,
    EPA conducted a formal cost-benefit study which found
    that the quantifiable benefits of its regulation would
    exceed the costs up to nine times over—by as much as $80
    billion each year. Those benefits include as many as
    11,000 fewer premature deaths annually, along with a far
    greater number of avoided illnesses.
    Despite that exhaustive consideration of costs, the Court
    strikes down EPA’s rule on the ground that the Agency
    “unreasonably . . . deemed cost irrelevant.” Ante, at 15.
    On the majority’s theory, the rule is invalid because EPA
    did not explicitly analyze costs at the very first stage of
    the regulatory process, when making its “appropriate and
    necessary” finding. And that is so even though EPA later
    took costs into account again and again and . . . so on. The
    majority thinks entirely immaterial, and so entirely ig-
    nores, all the subsequent times and ways EPA considered
    costs in deciding what any regulation would look like.
    That is a peculiarly blinkered way for a court to assess
    the lawfulness of an agency’s rulemaking. I agree with
    the majority—let there be no doubt about this—that EPA’s
    power plant regulation would be unreasonable if “[t]he
    Agency gave cost no thought at all.” Ante, at 5 (emphasis
    in original). But that is just not what happened here.
    Over more than a decade, EPA took costs into account at
    multiple stages and through multiple means as it set
    emissions limits for power plants. And when making its
    Cite as: 576 U. S. ____ (2015)              3
    KAGAN, J., dissenting
    initial “appropriate and necessary” finding, EPA knew it
    would do exactly that—knew it would thoroughly consider
    the cost-effectiveness of emissions standards later on.
    That context matters. The Agency acted well within its
    authority in declining to consider costs at the opening bell
    of the regulatory process given that it would do so in every
    round thereafter—and given that the emissions limits
    finally issued would depend crucially on those ac-
    countings. Indeed, EPA could not have measured costs at
    the process’s initial stage with any accuracy. And the
    regulatory path EPA chose parallels the one it has trod in
    setting emissions limits, at Congress’s explicit direction,
    for every other source of hazardous air pollutants over two
    decades. The majority’s decision that EPA cannot take the
    same approach here—its micromanagement of EPA’s
    rulemaking, based on little more than the word “appropri-
    ate”—runs counter to Congress’s allocation of authority
    between the Agency and the courts. Because EPA reason-
    ably found that it was “appropriate” to decline to analyze
    costs at a single stage of a regulatory proceeding otherwise
    imbued with cost concerns, I respectfully dissent.
    I
    A
    The Clean Air Act Amendments of 1990, as the majority
    describes, obligate EPA to regulate emissions of mercury
    and other hazardous air pollutants from stationary
    sources discharging those substances in large quantities.
    See ante, at 2. For most industries, the statute prescribes
    the same multi-step regulatory process. At the initial
    stage, EPA must decide whether to regulate a source,
    based solely on the quantity of pollutants it emits and
    their health and environmental effects. See 
    42 U. S. C. §§7412
    (a)(1), (a)(2), (c)(1), (c)(3); ante, at 2. Costs enter the
    equation after that, affecting the emissions limits that the
    eventual regulation will require. Under the statute, EPA
    4                        MICHIGAN v. EPA
    KAGAN, J., dissenting
    must divide sources into categories and subcategories and
    then set “floor standards” that reflect the average emis-
    sions level already achieved by the best-performing 12% of
    sources within each group. See §7412(d)(3); ante, at 3.
    Every 12% floor has cost concerns built right into it be-
    cause the top sources, as successful actors in a market
    economy, have had to consider costs in choosing their own
    emissions levels. Moreover, in establishing categories and
    subcategories at this first stage, EPA can (significantly)
    raise or lower the costs of regulation for each source,
    because different classification schemes will alter the
    group—and so the emissions level—that the source has to
    match.1 Once the floor is set, EPA has to decide whether
    to impose any stricter (“beyond-the-floor”) standards,
    “taking into consideration,” among other things, “the cost
    of achieving such emissions reduction.” §7412(d)(2); see
    ante, at 3. Finally, by virtue of a longstanding Executive
    Order applying to significant rules issued under the Clean
    Air Act (as well as other statutes), the Agency must sys-
    tematically assess the regulation’s costs and benefits. See
    Exec. Order No. 12866, 
    58 Fed. Reg. 51735
    , 51738, 51741
    (1993) (applying to all rules with an annual economic
    effect of at least $100 million).
    Congress modified that regulatory scheme for power
    plants. It did so because the 1990 amendments estab-
    lished a separate program to control power plant emis-
    sions contributing to acid rain, and many thought that
    just by complying with those requirements, plants might
    ——————
    1 Considerit this way: Floor standards equal the top 12% of some-
    thing, but until you know the something, you can’t know what it will
    take to attain that level. To take a prosaic example, the strongest 12%
    of NFL players can lift a lot more weight than the strongest 12% of
    human beings generally. To match the former, you will have to spend
    many more hours in the gym than to match the latter—and you will
    probably still come up short. So everything depends on the comparison
    group.
    Cite as: 576 U. S. ____ (2015)            5
    KAGAN, J., dissenting
    reduce their emissions of hazardous air pollutants to
    acceptable levels. See ante, at 2. That prospect counseled
    a “wait and see” approach, under which EPA would give
    the Act’s acid rain provisions a chance to achieve that side
    benefit before imposing any further regulation. Accord-
    ingly, Congress instructed EPA to “perform a study of the
    hazards to public health reasonably anticipated” to result
    from power plants’ emissions after the 1990 amendments
    had taken effect. §7412(n)(1)(A). And Congress provided
    that EPA “shall regulate” those emissions only if the
    Agency “finds such regulation is appropriate and neces-
    sary after considering the results of the [public health]
    study.” Ibid. Upon making such a finding, however, EPA
    is to regulate power plants as it does every other station-
    ary source: first, by categorizing plants and setting floor
    standards for the different groups; then by deciding
    whether to regulate beyond the floors; and finally, by
    conducting the cost-benefit analysis required by Executive
    Order.
    EPA completed the mandated health study in 1998, and
    the results gave much cause for concern. The Agency
    concluded that implementation of the acid rain provisions
    had failed to curb power plants’ emissions of hazardous air
    pollutants. Indeed, EPA found, coal plants were on track
    to increase those emissions by as much as 30% over the
    next decade. See 1 EPA, Study of Hazardous Air Pollu-
    tant Emissions from Electric Utility Steam Generating
    Units—Final Report to Congress, p. ES–25 (1998). And
    EPA determined, focusing especially on mercury, that the
    substances released from power plants cause substantial
    health harms. Noting that those plants are “the largest
    [non-natural] source of mercury emissions,” id., §1.2.5.1,
    at 1–7, EPA found that children of mothers exposed to
    high doses of mercury during pregnancy “have exhibited a
    variety of developmental neurological abnormalities,”
    including delayed walking and talking, altered muscles,
    6                        MICHIGAN v. EPA
    KAGAN, J., dissenting
    and cerebral palsy. Id., §7.2.2, at 7–17 to 7–18; see also 7
    EPA, Mercury Study Report to Congress, p. 6–31 (1997)
    (Mercury Study) (estimating that 7% of women of
    childbearing age are exposed to mercury in amounts ex-
    ceeding a safe level).
    Informed by its public health study and additional data,
    EPA found in 2000 that it is “appropriate and necessary”
    to regulate power plants’ emissions of mercury and other
    hazardous air pollutants. 
    65 Fed. Reg. 79830
    .2 Pulling
    apart those two adjectives, the Agency first stated that
    such regulation is “appropriate” because those pollutants
    “present[ ] significant hazards to public health and the
    environment” and because “a number of control options”
    can “effectively reduce” their emission. 
    Ibid.
     EPA then
    determined that regulation is “necessary” because other
    parts of the 1990 amendments—most notably, the acid
    rain provisions—“will not adequately address” those haz-
    ards. 
    Ibid.
     In less bureaucratic terms, EPA decided that
    it made sense to kick off the regulatory process given that
    power plants’ emissions pose a serious health problem,
    that solutions to the problem are available, and that the
    problem will remain unless action is taken.
    B
    If the regulatory process ended as well as started there,
    I would agree with the majority’s conclusion that EPA
    failed to adequately consider costs. Cost is almost always
    a relevant—and usually, a highly important—factor in
    regulation. Unless Congress provides otherwise, an agency
    acts unreasonably in establishing “a standard-setting proc-
    ess that ignore[s] economic considerations.” Industrial
    ——————
    2 EPA reaffirmed its “appropriate and necessary” finding in 2011 and
    2012 when it issued a proposed rule and a final rule. See 
    76 Fed. Reg. 24980
     (2011) (“The Agency’s appropriate and necessary finding was
    correct in 2000, and it remains correct today”); accord, 
    77 Fed. Reg. 9310
    –9311 (2012).
    Cite as: 576 U. S. ____ (2015)            7
    KAGAN, J., dissenting
    Union Dept., AFL–CIO v. American Petroleum Institute,
    
    448 U. S. 607
    , 670 (1980) (Powell, J., concurring in part
    and concurring in judgment). At a minimum, that is
    because such a process would “threaten[ ] to impose mas-
    sive costs far in excess of any benefit.” Entergy Corp. v.
    Riverkeeper, Inc., 
    556 U. S. 208
    , 234 (2009) (BREYER, J.,
    concurring in part and dissenting in part). And account-
    ing for costs is particularly important “in an age of limited
    resources available to deal with grave environmental
    problems, where too much wasteful expenditure devoted to
    one problem may well mean considerably fewer resources
    available to deal effectively with other (perhaps more
    serious) problems.” 
    Id., at 233
    ; see ante, at 7. As the
    Court notes, that does not require an agency to conduct a
    formal cost-benefit analysis of every administrative action.
    See ante, at 14. But (absent contrary indication from
    Congress) an agency must take costs into account in some
    manner before imposing significant regulatory burdens.
    That proposition, however, does not decide the issue
    before us because the “appropriate and necessary” finding
    was only the beginning. At that stage, EPA knew that a
    lengthy rulemaking process lay ahead of it; the determina-
    tion of emissions limits was still years away. And the
    Agency, in making its kick-off finding, explicitly noted that
    consideration of costs would follow: “As a part of develop-
    ing a regulation” that would impose those limits, “the
    effectiveness and costs of controls will be examined.” 
    65 Fed. Reg. 79830
    . Likewise, EPA explained that, in the
    course of writing its regulation, it would explore regula-
    tory approaches “allowing for least-cost solutions.” 
    Id.,
     at
    79830–79831. That means the Agency, when making its
    “appropriate and necessary” finding, did not decline to
    consider costs as part of the regulatory process. Rather, it
    declined to consider costs at a single stage of that process,
    knowing that they would come in later on.
    The only issue in these cases, then, is whether EPA
    8                     MICHIGAN v. EPA
    KAGAN, J., dissenting
    acted reasonably in structuring its regulatory process in
    that way—in making its “appropriate and necessary find-
    ing” based on pollution’s harmful effects and channeling
    cost considerations to phases of the rulemaking in which
    emission levels are actually set. Said otherwise, the ques-
    tion is not whether EPA can reasonably find it “appropri-
    ate” to regulate without thinking about costs, full stop. It
    cannot, and it did not. Rather, the question is whether
    EPA can reasonably find it “appropriate” to trigger the
    regulatory process based on harms (and technological
    feasibility) alone, given that costs will come into play, in
    multiple ways and at multiple stages, before any emission
    limit goes into effect.
    In considering that question, the very nature of the
    word “appropriate” matters. “[T]he word ‘appropriate,’ ”
    this Court has recognized, “is inherently context-
    dependent”: Giving it content requires paying attention to
    the surrounding circumstances. Sossamon v. Texas, 
    563 U. S. 277
    , ___ (2011) (slip op., at 7). (That is true, too, of
    the word “necessary,” although the majority spends less
    time on it. See Armour & Co. v. Wantock, 
    323 U. S. 126
    ,
    129–130 (1944) (“[T]he word ‘necessary’ . . . has always
    been recognized as a word to be harmonized with its con-
    text”).) And here that means considering the place of the
    “appropriate and necessary” finding in the broader regula-
    tory scheme—as a triggering mechanism that gets a com-
    plex rulemaking going. The interpretive task is thus at
    odds with the majority’s insistence on staring fixedly “at
    this stage.” Ante, at 11 (emphasis in original). The task
    instead demands taking account of the entire regulatory
    process in thinking about what is “appropriate” in its first
    phase. The statutory language, in other words, is a di-
    rective to remove one’s blinders and view things whole—to
    consider what it is fitting to do at the threshold stage
    given what will happen at every other.
    And that instruction is primarily given to EPA, not to
    Cite as: 576 U. S. ____ (2015)            9
    KAGAN, J., dissenting
    courts: Judges may interfere only if the Agency’s way of
    ordering its regulatory process is unreasonable—i.e.,
    something Congress would never have allowed. The ques-
    tion here, as in our seminal case directing courts to defer
    to agency interpretations of their own statutes, arises “not
    in a sterile textual vacuum, but in the context of imple-
    menting policy decisions in a technical and complex arena.”
    Chevron U. S. A. Inc. v. Natural Resources Defense
    Council, Inc., 
    467 U. S. 837
    , 863 (1984). EPA’s experience
    and expertise in that arena—and courts’ lack of those
    attributes—demand that judicial review proceed with
    caution and care. The majority actually phrases this
    principle well, though honors it only in the breach: Within
    wide bounds, it is “up to the Agency to decide . . . how to
    account for cost.” Ante, at 14. That judges might have
    made different regulatory choices—might have considered
    costs in different ways at different times—will not suffice
    to overturn EPA’s action where Congress, as here, chose
    not to speak directly to those matters, but to leave them to
    the Agency to decide.
    All of that means our decision here properly rests on
    something the majority thinks irrelevant: an understand-
    ing of the full regulatory process relating to power plants
    and of EPA’s reasons for considering costs only after mak-
    ing its initial “appropriate and necessary” finding. I there-
    fore turn to those issues, to demonstrate the simple point
    that should resolve these cases: that EPA, in regulating
    power plants’ emissions of hazardous air pollutants, ac-
    counted for costs in a reasonable way.
    II
    A
    In the years after its “appropriate and necessary” find-
    ing, EPA made good on its promise to account for costs
    “[a]s a part of developing a regulation.” 
    65 Fed. Reg. 79830
    ; see supra, at 7. For more than a decade, as EPA
    10                   MICHIGAN v. EPA
    KAGAN, J., dissenting
    deliberated on and then set emissions limits, costs came
    into the calculus at nearly every turn. Reflecting that
    consideration, EPA’s final rule noted that steps taken
    during the regulatory process had focused on “flexib[ility]
    and cost-effective[ness]” and had succeeded in making “the
    rule less costly and compliance more readily manageable.”
    
    77 Fed. Reg. 9306
    , 9376. And the regulation concluded
    that “the benefits of th[e] rule” to public health and the
    environment “far outweigh the costs.” 
    Id., at 9306
    .
    Consistent with the statutory framework, EPA initially
    calculated floor standards: emissions levels of the best-
    performing 12% of power plants in a given category or
    subcategory. The majority misperceives this part of the
    rulemaking process. It insists that EPA “must promulgate
    certain . . . floor standards no matter the cost.” Ante, at
    11. But that ignores two crucial features of the top-12%
    limits: first, the way in which any such standard intrinsi-
    cally accounts for costs, and second, the way in which the
    Agency’s categorization decisions yield different standards
    for plants with different cost structures.
    The initial point is a fact of life in a market economy:
    Costs necessarily play a role in any standard that uses
    power plants’ existing emissions levels as a benchmark.
    After all, the best-performing 12% of power plants must
    have considered costs in arriving at their emissions out-
    puts; that is how profit-seeking enterprises make deci-
    sions. And in doing so, they must have selected achievable
    levels; else, they would have gone out of business. (The
    same would be true even if other regulations influenced
    some of those choices, as the majority casually speculates.
    See ante, at 13.) Indeed, this automatic accounting for
    costs is why Congress adopted a market-leader-based
    standard. As the Senate Report accompanying the 1990
    amendments explained: “Cost considerations are reflected
    in the selection of emissions limitations which have been
    achieved in practice (rather than those which are merely
    Cite as: 576 U. S. ____ (2015)           11
    KAGAN, J., dissenting
    theoretical) by sources of a similar type or character.”
    S. Rep. No. 101–228, pp. 168–169 (1989). Of course, such
    a standard remains technology-forcing: It requires lag-
    gards in the industry to catch up with frontrunners, some-
    times at significant expense. But the benchmark is, by
    definition, one that some power plants have achieved
    economically. And when EPA made its “appropriate and
    necessary” finding, it knew that fact—knew that the con-
    sequence of doing so was to generate floor standards with
    cost considerations baked right in.
    Still more, EPA recognized that in making categoriza-
    tion decisions, it could take account of multiple factors
    related to costs of compliance—and so avoid impracticable
    regulatory burdens. Suppose, to use a simple example,
    that curbing emissions is more technologically difficult—
    and therefore more costly—for plants burning coal than
    for plants burning oil. EPA can then place those two types
    of plants in different categories, so that coal plants need
    only match other coal plants rather than having to incur
    the added costs of meeting the top oil plants’ levels. Now
    multiply and complexify that example many times over.
    As the Agency noted when making its “appropriate and
    necessary” finding, EPA “build[s] flexibility” into the
    regulatory regime by “bas[ing] subcategorization on . . .
    the size of a facility; the type of fuel used at the facility;
    and the plant type,” and also “may consider other relevant
    factors such as geographic conditions.” 
    65 Fed. Reg. 79830
    ; see S. Rep. No. 101–228, at 166 (listing similar
    factors and noting that “[t]he proper definition of catego-
    ries . . . will assure maximum protection of public health
    and the environment while minimizing costs imposed on
    the regulated community”). Using that classification tool,
    EPA can ensure that plants have to attain only the emis-
    sions levels previously achieved by peers facing compara-
    ble cost constraints, so as to further protect plants from
    unrealistic floor standards.
    12                       MICHIGAN v. EPA
    KAGAN, J., dissenting
    And that is exactly what EPA did over the course of its
    rulemaking process, insisting on apples-to-apples compar-
    isons that bring floor standards within reach of diverse
    kinds of power plants. Even in making its “appropriate
    and necessary” finding, the Agency announced it would
    divide plants into the two categories mentioned above:
    “coal-fired” and “oil-fired.” 
    65 Fed. Reg. 79830
    .3 Then, as
    the rulemaking progressed, EPA went further. Noting
    that different technologies significantly affect the ease of
    attaining a given emissions level, the Agency’s proposed
    rule subdivided those two classes into five: plants designed
    to burn high-rank coal; plants designed to burn low-rank
    virgin coal; plants that run on a technology termed inte-
    grated gasification combined cycle; liquid oil units; and
    solid oil units. See 
    76 Fed. Reg. 25036
    –25037. EPA ex-
    plained that by subcategorizing in that way, it had spared
    many plants the need to “retrofit[ ],” “redesign[ ],” or make
    other “extensive changes” to their facilities. 
    Id., at 25036
    .
    And in its final rule, EPA further refined its groupings in
    ways that eased compliance. Most notably, the Agency
    established a separate subcategory, and attendant (less
    stringent) floor, for plants in Hawaii, Puerto Rico, Guam,
    and the Virgin Islands on the ground that plants in those
    places have “minimal control over the quality of available
    fuel[ ] and disproportionately high operational and
    maintenance costs.” 
    77 Fed. Reg. 9401
    .4
    ——————
    3 EPA   also determined at that stage that it is “not appropriate or
    necessary” to regulate natural gas plants’ emissions of hazardous air
    pollutants because they have only “negligible” impacts. 
    65 Fed. Reg. 79831
    . That decision meant that other plants would not have to match
    their cleaner natural gas counterparts, thus making the floor standards
    EPA established that much less costly to achieve.
    4 The majority insists on disregarding how EPA’s categorization deci-
    sions made floor standards less costly for various power plants to
    achieve, citing the Agency’s statement that “it is not appropriate to
    premise subcategorization on costs.” 
    77 Fed. Reg. 9395
     (quoted ante, at
    13). But that misunderstands EPA’s point. It is quite true that EPA
    Cite as: 576 U. S. ____ (2015)                     13
    KAGAN, J., dissenting
    Even after establishing multiple floor standards that
    factored in costs, EPA adopted additional “compliance
    options” to “minimize costs” associated with attaining a
    given floor—just as its “appropriate and necessary” find-
    ing explicitly contemplated. 
    Id., at 9306
    ; 
    76 Fed. Reg. 25057
    ; see 
    65 Fed. Reg. 79830
    . For example, the Agency
    calculated each floor as both an “input-based” standard
    (based on emissions per unit of energy used) and an
    “output-based” standard (based on emissions per unit of use-
    ful energy produced), and allowed plants to choose which
    standard they would meet. That option, EPA explained,
    can “result in . . . reduced compliance costs.” 
    76 Fed. Reg. 25063
    . Similarly, EPA allowed plants to meet a given 12%
    floor by averaging emissions across all units at the same
    site, instead of having to meet the floor at each unit. Some
    plants, EPA understood, would find such averaging a “less
    costly alternative.” 
    77 Fed. Reg. 9385
    . Yet again: EPA
    permitted “limited use” plants—those primarily burning
    ——————
    did not consider costs separate and apart from all other factors in
    crafting categories and subcategories. See S. Rep. No. 101–128, p. 166
    (1989) (noting that EPA may not make classifications decisions “based
    wholly on economic grounds”); 
    77 Fed. Reg. 9395
     (citing Senate Report).
    That approach could have subverted the statutory scheme: To use an
    extreme example, it would have allowed EPA, citing costs of compli-
    ance, to place the top few plants in one category, the next few in another
    category, the third in a third, and all the way down the line, thereby
    insulating every plant from having to make an appreciable effort to
    catch up with cleaner facilities. But in setting up categories and
    subcategories, EPA did consider technological, geographic, and other
    factors directly relevant to the costs that diverse power plants would
    bear in trying to attain a given emissions level. (For some reason, the
    majority calls this a “carefully worded observation,” ante, at 13, but it is
    nothing other than the fact of the matter.) The Agency’s categorization
    decisions (among several other measures, see supra, at 10–11; infra
    this page and 14) thus refute the majority’s suggestion, see ante, at 11,
    that the “appropriate and necessary” finding automatically generates
    floor standards with no relation to cost. To the contrary, the Agency
    used its categorization authority to establish different floor standards
    for different types of plants with different cost structures.
    14                   MICHIGAN v. EPA
    KAGAN, J., dissenting
    natural gas but sometimes switching to oil—to comply
    with the final rule by meeting qualitative “work practice
    standards” rather than numeric emissions limits. Id., at
    9400–9401. EPA explained that it would be “economically
    impracticable” for those plants to demonstrate compliance
    through emissions testing, and that an alternative stand-
    ard, focused on their adoption of pollution control tech-
    niques, would allow them to both reduce emissions and
    avoid “extra cost.” Id., at 9401. And the list goes on. See,
    e.g., id., at 9409–9410 (allowing extra year for plants to
    comply with emissions limits where “source-specific con-
    struction, permitting, or labor, procurement or resource
    challenges” arise); id., at 9417 (describing additional
    “compliance options”).
    With all that cost-consideration under its belt, EPA next
    assessed whether to set beyond-the-floor standards, and
    here too, as it knew it would, the Agency took costs into
    account. For the vast majority of coal and oil plants, EPA
    decided that beyond-the-floor standards would not be
    “reasonable after considering costs.” Id., at 9331. The
    Agency set such a standard for only a single kind of plant,
    and only after determining that the technology needed to
    meet the more lenient limit would also achieve the more
    stringent one. See id., at 9393; 
    76 Fed. Reg. 25046
    –25047.
    Otherwise, EPA determined, the market-leader-based
    standards were enough.
    Finally, as required by Executive Order and as antici-
    pated at the time of the “appropriate and necessary” find-
    ing, EPA conducted a formal cost-benefit analysis of its
    new emissions standards and incorporated those findings
    into its proposed and final rules. See 
    id.,
     at 25072–25078;
    
    77 Fed. Reg. 9305
    –9306, 9424–9432. That analysis esti-
    mated that the regulation’s yearly costs would come in at
    under $10 billion, while its annual measureable benefits
    would total many times more—between $37 and $90
    billion. See 
    id.,
     at 9305–9306; ante, at 4. On the costs
    Cite as: 576 U. S. ____ (2015)          15
    KAGAN, J., dissenting
    side, EPA acknowledged that plants’ compliance with the
    rule would likely cause electricity prices to rise by about
    3%, but projected that those prices would remain lower
    than they had been as recently as 2010. See 
    77 Fed. Reg. 9413
    –9414. EPA also thought the rule’s impact on jobs
    would be about a wash, with jobs lost at some high-
    emitting plants but gained both at cleaner plants and in
    the pollution control industry. See 
    ibid.
     On the benefits
    side, EPA noted that it could not quantify many of the
    health gains that would result from reduced mercury
    exposure. See 
    id., at 9306
    . But even putting those aside,
    the rule’s annual benefits would include between 4,200
    and 11,000 fewer premature deaths from respiratory and
    cardiovascular causes, 3,100 fewer emergency room visits
    for asthmatic children, 4,700 fewer non-fatal heart at-
    tacks, and 540,000 fewer days of lost work. See 
    id., at 9429
    .
    Those concrete findings matter to these cases—which,
    after all, turn on whether EPA reasonably took costs into
    account in regulating plants’ emissions of hazardous air
    pollutants. The majority insists that it may ignore EPA’s
    cost-benefit analysis because “EPA did not rely on” it
    when issuing the initial “appropriate and necessary”
    finding. Ante, at 15 (quoting Solicitor General); see also
    SEC v. Chenery Corp., 
    318 U. S. 80
    , 87, 93–94 (1943). At
    one level, that description is true—indeed, a simple func-
    tion of chronology: The kick-off finding preceded the cost-
    benefit analysis by years and so could not have taken its
    conclusions into account. But more fundamentally, the
    majority’s account is off, because EPA knew when it made
    that finding that it would consider costs at every subse-
    quent stage, culminating in a formal cost-benefit study.
    And EPA knew that, absent unusual circumstances, the
    rule would need to pass that cost-benefit review in order to
    issue. See Exec. Order No. 12866, 
    58 Fed. Reg. 51736
    (“Each agency shall . . . adopt a regulation only upon a
    16                   MICHIGAN v. EPA
    KAGAN, J., dissenting
    reasoned determination that the benefits of the intended
    regulation justify its costs”). The reasonableness of the
    Agency’s decision to consider only the harms of emissions
    at the threshold stage must be evaluated in that broader
    context. And in thinking about that issue, it is well to
    remember the outcome here: a rule whose benefits exceed
    its costs by three to nine times. In making its “appropri-
    ate and necessary” finding, EPA had committed to as-
    sessing and mitigating costs throughout the rest of its
    rulemaking; if nothing else, the findings of the Agency’s
    cost-benefit analysis—making clear that the final emis-
    sions standards were cost-effective—show that EPA did
    just that.
    B
    Suppose you were in charge of designing a regulatory
    process. The subject matter—an industry’s emissions of
    hazardous material—was highly complex, involving mul-
    tivarious factors demanding years of study. Would you
    necessarily try to do everything at once? Or might you try
    to break down this lengthy and complicated process into
    discrete stages? And might you consider different factors,
    in different ways, at each of those junctures? I think you
    might. You know that everything must get done in the
    end—every relevant factor considered. But you tend to
    think that “in the end” does not mean “in the beginning.”
    And you structure your rulemaking process accordingly,
    starting with a threshold determination that does not
    mirror your end-stage analysis. Would that be at least
    (which is all it must be) a “reasonable policy choice”?
    Chevron, 
    467 U. S., at 845
    .
    That is the question presented here, and it nearly an-
    swers itself. Setting emissions levels for hazardous air
    pollutants is necessarily a lengthy and complicated pro-
    cess, demanding analysis of many considerations over
    many years. Costs are a key factor in that process: As I
    Cite as: 576 U. S. ____ (2015)          17
    KAGAN, J., dissenting
    have said, sensible regulation requires careful scrutiny of
    the burdens that potential rules impose. See supra, at 6–
    7. But in ordering its regulatory process, EPA knew it
    would have the opportunity to consider costs in one after
    another of that rulemaking’s stages—in setting the level of
    floor standards, in providing a range of options for plants
    to meet them, in deciding whether or where to require
    limits beyond the floor, and in finally completing a formal
    cost-benefit analysis. See 
    65 Fed. Reg. 79830
    –79831;
    supra, at 9–15. Given that context, EPA reasonably de-
    cided that it was “appropriate”—once again, the only
    statutory requirement relevant here—to trigger the regu-
    latory process based on the twin findings that the emis-
    sions in question cause profound health and environmen-
    tal harms and that available pollution control technologies
    can reduce those emissions. By making that decision,
    EPA did no more than commit itself to developing a realis-
    tic and cost-effective regulation—a rule that would take
    account of every relevant factor, costs and benefits alike.
    And indeed, particular features of the statutory scheme
    here indicate that EPA’s policy choice was not just a min-
    imally reasonable option but an eminently reasonable one.
    To start, that decision brought EPA’s regulation of
    power plants into sync with its regulation of every other
    significant source of hazardous pollutants under the Clean
    Air Act. For all those types of sources (totaling over 100),
    the Act instructs EPA to make the threshold decision to
    regulate based solely on the quantity and effects of pollu-
    tants discharged; costs enter the picture afterward, when
    the Agency takes up the task of actually establishing
    emissions limits. See supra, at 3–4. Industry after indus-
    try, year after year, EPA has followed that approach to
    standard-setting, just as Congress contemplated. See, e.g.,
    
    58 Fed. Reg. 49354
     (1993) (dry cleaning facilities); 
    59 Fed. Reg. 64303
     (1994) (gasoline distributors); 
    60 Fed. Reg. 45948
     (1995) (aerospace manufacturers). And apparently
    18                    MICHIGAN v. EPA
    KAGAN, J., dissenting
    with considerable success. At any rate, neither those
    challenging this rule nor the Court remotely suggests that
    these regulatory regimes have done “significantly more
    harm than good.” Ante, at 7. So when making its “appro-
    priate and necessary” finding for power plants, EPA had
    good reason to continue in the same vein. See, e.g., Entergy,
    
    556 U. S., at 236
     (opinion of BREYER, J.) (noting that the
    reasonableness of an agency’s approach to considering
    costs rests in part on whether that tack has met “with
    apparent success in the past”). And that is exactly how
    EPA explained its choice. Stating that it would consider
    the “costs of controls” when “developing a regulation,” the
    Agency noted that such an “approach has helped build
    flexibility in meeting environmental objectives in the
    past,” thereby preventing the imposition of disproportion-
    ate costs. 
    65 Fed. Reg. 79830
    . Indeed, as EPA further
    commented in issuing its rule, it would seem “inequitable
    to impose a regulatory regime on every industry in Amer-
    ica and then to exempt one category” after finding it repre-
    sented “a significant part of the air toxics problem.” 
    77 Fed. Reg. 9322
     (quoting 136 Cong. Rec. 36062 (1990)
    (statement of Sen. Durenberger)).
    The majority’s attempt to answer this point founders on
    even its own statement of facts. The majority objects that
    “the whole point of having a separate provision about
    power plants” is to “treat[ ] power plants differently from
    other stationary sources.” Ante, at 11 (emphasis in origi-
    nal). But turn back about 10 pages, and read what the
    majority says about why Congress treated power plants
    differently: because, as all parties agree, separate regula-
    tory requirements involving acid rain “were expected to
    have the collateral effect of reducing power plants’ emis-
    sions of hazardous air pollutants, although the extent of
    the reduction was unclear.” Ante, at 2; see supra, at 4–5.
    For that reason alone (the majority does not offer any
    other), Congress diverted EPA from its usual regulatory
    Cite as: 576 U. S. ____ (2015)           19
    KAGAN, J., dissenting
    path, instructing the Agency, as a preliminary matter, to
    complete and consider a study about the residual harms to
    public health arising from those emissions. See ante, at 2–
    3; supra, at 5. But once EPA found in its study that the
    acid rain provisions would not significantly affect power
    plants’ emissions of hazardous pollutants, any rationale
    for treating power plants differently from other sources
    discharging the same substances went up in smoke. See
    
    65 Fed. Reg. 79830
    . At that point, the Agency would have
    had far more explaining to do if, rather than following a
    well-tested model, it had devised a new scheme of regula-
    tion for power plants only.
    Still more, EPA could not have accurately assessed costs
    at the time of its “appropriate and necessary” finding. See
    8 Mercury Study, at 6–2 (noting the “many uncertainties”
    in any early-stage analysis of pollution control costs).
    Under the statutory scheme, that finding comes before—
    years before—the Agency designs emissions standards.
    And until EPA knows what standards it will establish, it
    cannot know what costs they will impose. Nor can those
    standards even be reasonably guesstimated at such an
    early stage. Consider what it takes to set floor standards
    alone. First, EPA must divide power plants into catego-
    ries and subcategories; as explained earlier, those classifi-
    cation decisions significantly affect what floors are estab-
    lished. See supra, at 4, and n. 1, 11–12. And then, EPA
    must figure out the average emissions level already
    achieved by the top 12% in each class so as to set the new
    standards. None of that can realistically be accomplished
    in advance of the Agency’s regulatory process: Indeed,
    those steps are the very stuff of the rulemaking. Simi-
    larly, until EPA knows what “compliance options” it will
    develop, it cannot know how they will mitigate the costs
    plants must incur to meet the floor standards. See supra,
    at 13–14. And again, deciding on those options takes
    substantial time. So there is good reason for different
    20                    MICHIGAN v. EPA
    KAGAN, J., dissenting
    considerations to go into the threshold finding than into
    the final rule. Simply put, calculating costs before start-
    ing to write a regulation would put the cart before the
    horse.
    III
    The central flaw of the majority opinion is that it ig-
    nores everything but one thing EPA did. It forgets that
    EPA’s “appropriate and necessary” finding was only a first
    step which got the rest of the regulatory process rolling. It
    narrows its field of vision to that finding in isolation, with
    barely a glance at all the ways in which EPA later took
    costs into account. See supra, at 10–11 (in establishing
    floor standards); supra, at 13–14 (in adopting compliance
    options); supra, at 14 (in deciding whether to regulate
    beyond the floor); supra, at 14–15 (in conducting a formal
    cost-benefit analysis as a final check). In sum, the major-
    ity disregards how consideration of costs infused the regu-
    latory process, resulting not only in EPA’s adoption of
    mitigation measures, ante, at 13–14, but also in EPA’s
    crafting of emissions standards that succeed in producing
    benefits many times their price.
    That mistake accounts for the majority’s primary argu-
    ment that the word “appropriate,” as used in
    §7412(n)(1)(A), demands consideration of costs. See ante,
    at 6–7. As I have noted, that would be true if the “appro-
    priate and necessary” finding were the only step before
    imposing regulations on power plants. See supra, at 6–7.
    But, as should be more than clear by now, it was just the
    first of many: Under the Clean Air Act, a long road lay
    ahead in which the Agency would have more—and far
    better—opportunities to evaluate the costs of diverse
    emissions standards on power plants, just as it did on all
    other sources. See supra, at 4, 7, 9–15. EPA well under-
    stood that fact: “We evaluate the terms ‘appropriate’ and
    ‘necessary,’ ” it explained, in light of their “statutory con-
    Cite as: 576 U. S. ____ (2015)          21
    KAGAN, J., dissenting
    text.” 
    76 Fed. Reg. 24986
    . And EPA structured its regula-
    tory process accordingly, with consideration of costs com-
    ing (multiple times) after the threshold finding. The only
    way the majority can cast that choice as unreasonable,
    given the deference this Court owes to such agency deci-
    sions, is to blind itself to the broader rulemaking scheme.
    The same fault inheres in the majority’s secondary
    argument that EPA engaged in an “interpretive gerry-
    mander[ ]” by considering environmental effects but not
    costs in making its “appropriate and necessary” finding.
    Ante, at 8–9. The majority notes—quite rightly—that
    Congress called for EPA to examine both subjects in a
    study of mercury emissions from all sources (separate
    from the study relating to power plants’ emissions alone).
    See ante, at 8. And the majority states—again, rightly—
    that Congress’s demand for that study “provides direct
    evidence that Congress was concerned with [both] envi-
    ronmental effects [and] cost.” Ante, at 9 (internal quota-
    tion marks omitted). But nothing follows from that fact,
    because EPA too was concerned with both. True enough,
    EPA assessed the two at different times: environmental
    harms (along with health harms) at the threshold, costs
    afterward. But that was for the very reasons earlier de-
    scribed: because EPA wanted to treat power plants like
    other sources and because it thought harms, but not costs,
    could be accurately measured at that early stage. See
    supra, at 17–20. Congress’s simple request for a study of
    mercury emissions in no way conflicts with that choice of
    when and how to consider both harms and costs. Once
    more, the majority perceives a conflict only because it
    takes so partial a view of the regulatory process.
    And the identical blind spot causes the majority’s
    sports-car metaphor to run off the road. The majority
    likens EPA to a hypothetical driver who decides that “it is
    ‘appropriate’ to buy a Ferrari without thinking about cost,
    because he plans to think about cost later when deciding
    22                    MICHIGAN v. EPA
    KAGAN, J., dissenting
    whether to upgrade the sound system.” Ante, at 11. The
    comparison is witty but wholly inapt. To begin with,
    emissions limits are not a luxury good: They are a safety
    measure, designed to curtail the significant health and
    environmental harms caused by power plants spewing
    hazardous pollutants. And more: EPA knows from past
    experience and expertise alike that it will have the oppor-
    tunity to purchase that good in a cost-effective way. A
    better analogy might be to a car owner who decides with-
    out first checking prices that it is “appropriate and neces-
    sary” to replace her worn-out brake-pads, aware from
    prior experience that she has ample time to comparison-
    shop and bring that purchase within her budget. Faced
    with a serious hazard and an available remedy, EPA
    moved forward like that sensible car owner, with a prom-
    ise that it would, and well-grounded confidence that it
    could, take costs into account down the line.
    That about does it for the majority’s opinion, save for its
    final appeal to Chenery—and Chenery cannot save its
    holding. See ante, at 14. Of course a court may not up-
    hold agency action on grounds different from those the
    agency gave. See Chenery, 
    318 U. S., at 87
    . But equally, a
    court may not strike down agency action without consider-
    ing the reasons the agency gave. 
    Id., at 95
    . And that is
    what the majority does. Indeed, it is difficult to know
    what agency document the majority is reading. It denies
    that “EPA said . . . that cost-benefit analysis would be
    deferred until later.” Ante, at 13. But EPA said exactly
    that: The “costs of controls,” the Agency promised, “will be
    examined” as “a part of developing a regulation.” 
    65 Fed. Reg. 79830
    . Tellingly, these words appear nowhere in the
    majority’s opinion. But what are they other than a state-
    ment that cost concerns, contra the majority, are not
    “irrelevant,” ante, at 13 (without citation)—that they are
    simply going to come in later?
    And for good measure, EPA added still extra explana-
    Cite as: 576 U. S. ____ (2015)          23
    KAGAN, J., dissenting
    tion. In its “appropriate and necessary” finding, the Agency
    committed to exploring “least-cost solutions” in “devel-
    oping a standard for utilities.” 
    65 Fed. Reg. 79830
    . The
    Agency explained that such an approach—particularly
    mentioning the use of averaging and subcategorization—
    had offered “opportunit[ies] for lower cost solutions” and
    “helped build flexibility in meeting environmental objec-
    tives in the past.” Ibid.; see supra, at 7, 18. Then, in
    issuing its proposed and final rules, EPA affirmed that it
    had done just what it said. EPA recognized that standard-
    setting must “allow the industry to make practical in-
    vestment decisions that minimize costs.” 
    76 Fed. Reg. 25057
    . Accordingly, the Agency said, it had “provid[ed]
    flexibility and compliance options” so as to make the rule
    “less costly” for regulated parties. 
    77 Fed. Reg. 9306
    .
    EPA added that it had rejected beyond-the-floor standards
    for almost all power plants because they would not be
    “reasonable after considering costs.” 
    Id., at 9331
    . And it
    showed the results of a formal analysis finding that the
    rule’s costs paled in comparison to its benefits. In sum,
    EPA concluded, it had made the final standards “cost-
    efficient.” 
    Id., at 9434
    . What more would the majority
    have EPA say?
    IV
    Costs matter in regulation. But when Congress does not
    say how to take costs into account, agencies have broad
    discretion to make that judgment. Accord, ante, at 14
    (noting that it is “up to the Agency to decide (as always,
    within the limits of reasonable interpretation) how to
    account for cost”). Far more than courts, agencies have
    the expertise and experience necessary to design regula-
    tory processes suited to “a technical and complex arena.”
    Chevron, 
    467 U. S., at 863
    . And in any event, Congress
    has entrusted such matters to them, not to us.
    EPA exercised that authority reasonably and responsi-
    24                   MICHIGAN v. EPA
    KAGAN, J., dissenting
    bly in setting emissions standards for power plants. The
    Agency treated those plants just as it had more than 100
    other industrial sources of hazardous air pollutants, at
    Congress’s direction and with significant success. It made
    a threshold finding that regulation was “appropriate and
    necessary” based on the harm caused by power plants’
    emissions and the availability of technology to reduce
    them. In making that finding, EPA knew that when it
    decided what a regulation would look like—what emis-
    sions standards the rule would actually set—the Agency
    would consider costs. Indeed, EPA expressly promised to
    do so. And it fulfilled that promise. The Agency took
    account of costs in setting floor standards as well as in
    thinking about beyond-the-floor standards. It used its full
    kit of tools to minimize the expense of complying with its
    proposed emissions limits. It capped the regulatory proc-
    ess with a formal analysis demonstrating that the bene-
    fits of its rule would exceed the costs many times over. In
    sum, EPA considered costs all over the regulatory process,
    except in making its threshold finding—when it could not
    have measured them accurately anyway. That approach
    is wholly consonant with the statutory scheme. Its adop-
    tion was “up to the Agency to decide.” Ante, at 14.
    The majority arrives at a different conclusion only by
    disregarding most of EPA’s regulatory process. It insists
    that EPA must consider costs—when EPA did just that,
    over and over and over again. It concedes the importance
    of “context” in determining what the “appropriate and
    necessary” standard means, see ante, at 7, 10—and then
    ignores every aspect of the rulemaking context in which
    that standard plays a part. The result is a decision that
    deprives the Agency of the latitude Congress gave it to
    design an emissions-setting process sensibly accounting
    for costs and benefits alike. And the result is a decision
    that deprives the American public of the pollution control
    measures that the responsible Agency, acting well within
    Cite as: 576 U. S. ____ (2015)     25
    KAGAN, J., dissenting
    its delegated authority, found would save many, many
    lives. I respectfully dissent.
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 14–46; 14–47; 14–49.

Citation Numbers: 192 L. Ed. 2d 674, 135 S. Ct. 2699, 2015 U.S. LEXIS 4256

Judges: Scaliadelivered, Thomas

Filed Date: 6/29/2015

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 10/19/2024

Authorities (14)

United States v. Mead Corp. , 121 S. Ct. 2164 ( 2001 )

CSX Transportation, Inc. v. Alabama Department of Revenue , 131 S. Ct. 1101 ( 2011 )

Whitman v. American Trucking Assns., Inc. , 121 S. Ct. 903 ( 2001 )

Marbury v. Madison , 2 L. Ed. 60 ( 1803 )

Smiley v. Citibank (South Dakota), N. A. , 116 S. Ct. 1730 ( 1996 )

National Cable & Telecommunications Assn. v. Brand X ... , 125 S. Ct. 2688 ( 2005 )

Chevron U. S. A. Inc. v. Natural Resources Defense Council, ... , 104 S. Ct. 2778 ( 1984 )

Motor Vehicle Mfrs. Assn. of United States, Inc. v. State ... , 103 S. Ct. 2856 ( 1983 )

Allentown MacK Sales & Service, Inc. v. National Labor ... , 118 S. Ct. 818 ( 1998 )

Entergy Corp. v. Riverkeeper, Inc. , 129 S. Ct. 1498 ( 2009 )

United States v. Detroit Timber & Lumber Co. , 26 S. Ct. 282 ( 1906 )

Sossamon v. Texas , 131 S. Ct. 1651 ( 2011 )

Armour & Co. v. Wantock , 65 S. Ct. 165 ( 1944 )

Industrial Union Dept., AFL-CIO v. American Petroleum ... , 100 S. Ct. 2844 ( 1980 )

View All Authorities »

Cited By (82)

Policy and Research, LLC v. Department of Health and Human ... ( 2018 )

In re Determination of Existence of Significantly Excessive ... , 2020 Ohio 5450 ( 2020 )

United States Sugar Corp. v. Environmental Protection Agency , 830 F.3d 579 ( 2016 )

Louisiana State v. United States Army Corps of Engineers , 834 F.3d 574 ( 2016 )

Sierra Club, Inc. v. U.S. Forest Service , 897 F.3d 582 ( 2018 )

Nicopure Labs, LLC v. Food and Drug Administration , 266 F. Supp. 3d 360 ( 2017 )

Van Hollen v. Federal Election Commission , 811 F.3d 486 ( 2016 )

Union Pacific Railroad Co. v. STB ( 2017 )

Solomon v. State ( 2015 )

Solomon v. State , 303 Kan. 512 ( 2015 )

Sierra Club v. Mosier ( 2017 )

Murray Energy Corp. v. Administrator of Environmental ... , 861 F.3d 529 ( 2017 )

Global TelLink v. FCC ( 2017 )

Murray Energy Corporation v. EPA ( 2017 )

State ex rel. McCann v. Delaware Cty. Bd. of Elections (... , 155 Ohio St. 3d 14 ( 2018 )

Util. Solid Waste Activities Grp. v. Envtl. Prot. Agency , 901 F.3d 414 ( 2018 )

State ex rel. McCann v. Delaware Cty. Bd. of Elections (... , 2018 Ohio 3342 ( 2018 )

Mkt. Synergy Grp., Inc. v. U.S. Dep't of Labor , 885 F.3d 676 ( 2018 )

National Labor Relations Board v. CNN America, Inc. , 865 F.3d 740 ( 2017 )

Shenzhen Xinboda Industrial Co., Ltd. v. United States , 2017 CIT 166 ( 2017 )

View All Citing Opinions »