Southern Card & Novelty, Inc. v. Lawson Mardon Label, Inc. ( 1998 )


Menu:
  •                                   United States Court of Appeals,
    Eleventh Circuit.
    No. 96-3682.
    SOUTHERN CARD & NOVELTY, INC., Plaintiff-Appellant,
    v.
    LAWSON MARDON LABEL, INC. d.b.a. Lawson Mardon Post Card, and Daniel J. Saunders,
    Defendants-Appellees.
    April 7, 1998.
    Appeal from the United States District Court for the Middle District of Florida. (No. 95-130-CVI-
    ORL-22), Anne C. Conway, District Judge.
    Before HATCHETT, Chief Judge, EDMONDSON and COX, Circuit Judges.
    HATCHETT, Chief Judge:
    The appellant, Southern Card & Novelty, Inc. (Southern Card), a postcard distributor,
    challenges the district court's grant of summary judgment for the appellees, Lawson Mardon Label,
    Inc. (Lawson), a manufacturer of postcards and related products, and Daniel Saunders, the
    vice-president in charge of Lawson's postcard business, on its federal and state antitrust tying claims.
    We affirm.
    I. FACTS
    Lawson manufactures postcards and sells them to distributors throughout North America.1
    Those distributors then sell the postcards to retail outlets, which in turn sell them to consumers.
    Over a decade ago, Lawson's predecessor-in-interest, H.S. Crocker Company, Inc. (H.S.Crocker),
    secured a license agreement with the Walt Disney Company (Disney Company) that permits Lawson
    to manufacture postcards bearing the copyrighted images of Disney characters such as Mickey
    1
    Lawson has about an eleven percent market share of the North American postcard business.
    Mouse. Although the license agreement is "non-exclusive," the Disney Company has not granted
    similar rights to any other postcard manufacturer. Thus, Lawson is the sole producer of postcards
    bearing Disney images. Lawson also makes "local view" postcards, i.e., postcards depicting
    nonlicensed local images. In Florida, these postcards might present, for example, pictures of
    beaches, palm trees or alligators. Local view postcards comprise over ninety percent of Lawson's
    total postcard production and accounted for over sixty percent of its sales in Florida in 1995. The
    parties do not dispute that at least six other postcard manufacturers produce postcards specific to
    areas in Florida.
    Southern Card, located in Daytona Beach, distributes postcards to retailers—primarily "chain
    stores"—situated in central and northern Florida. Southern Card purchases its postcards from large
    commercial printers such as Lawson, and acts as a rack jobber in the stores it services.2 From
    1986—the year Southern Card commenced business dealings with H.S. Crocker—to 1991, Southern
    Card retained complete control over the quantity and types of postcards that it purchased from the
    manufacturer.3 During the late 1980s and early 1990s, Southern Card bought a percentage of its
    2
    Southern Card asserts that "[t]here are approximately eight main line independent postcard
    distributors in the state of Florida."
    3
    It may well be that in the mid-to-late 1980s, Southern Card and Lawson entered into an
    informal arrangement whereby Southern Card acted as Lawson's exclusive vendor to chain stores
    in exchange for Lawson's promise not to sell Disney postcards to Southern Card's competitors.
    On November 22, 1989, John Nyberg, Southern Card's president, wrote to the chairman of the
    board of H.S. Crocker, detailing the "history of the relationship" between the two companies.
    Nyberg wrote that he had "wanted exclusivity on all H.S. Crocker postcard products, including
    all Walt Disney World items within [Southern Card's] territorial area," and that "[w]ith the
    understanding that H.S. Crocker would not manufacture for, or sell to any other distributor in the
    territory serviced by Southern Card & Novelty, our companies began to do business." Nyberg
    also acknowledged the existence of this arrangement when deposed on April 18, 1996, stating,
    "So de facto, I became—Southern Card & Novelty became the exclusive vendor to the chain
    stores. Although there was never any such agreement made between myself and Lawson
    Mardon, it had indeed evolved that way." However, in an affidavit dated July 30, 1996, Nyberg
    averred that while the parties had entered into an exclusivity agreement concerning retailers in
    local view postcard stock from Lawson's competitors, finding their products superior in terms of
    price and quality.4
    In late 1991, Lawson introduced a "Disney Product Plan" in Florida. In a letter dated
    December 12, 1991, Saunders put forth the terms of the agreement he hoped to reach with Southern
    Card pursuant to this plan:
    d) Distributor will purchase Local View and General Florida post cards and allied products
    from [Lawson] equal to his purchases from [Lawson] of Disney products. [For example,]
    if distributor purchases $100,000 in 1992 of Disney product from [Lawson], distributor
    agrees to purchase a minimum of $100,000 in 1992 of Local View or General Florida
    product from [Lawson].
    e) Failure to meet the minimum requirement agreed to in d) above, may result in [Lawson's]
    decision to not sell any product to distributor in following year.
    Because Southern Card feared losing its lone source of Disney postcards, it began buying Lawson's
    local view postcards in amounts equal to its purchases of Disney postcards.
    In October 1993, Saunders wrote to Nyberg expressing his concern that Southern Card
    continued to buy a significant quantity of postcards from Lawson's competitors. The next month,
    Saunders wrote to Nyberg asking that Southern Card commit to having Lawson postcards comprise
    one hundred percent of Southern Card's business in the Orlando area. Southern Card refused,
    asserting that Lawson already received about seventy-five to eighty percent of its total business, and
    that it never committed to purchasing one hundred percent of its requirements from Lawson.
    A few months later, in February 1994, Lawson began recruiting Southern Card's competitors
    to sell Lawson postcards to chain stores. The next month, Lawson limited Southern Card's
    Daytona Beach, they "had no territorial exclusive agreement for Orlando." For purposes of this
    appeal, we accept this assertion as true.
    4
    About seventy percent of Southern Card's revenue is attributable to its sale of local view
    postcards.
    purchases of Disney postcards to those that Southern Card had bought in 1993.5 In the meantime,
    Lawson sold a number of Disney postcards that had been developed in 1994 to those distributors that
    bought only Lawson local view postcards. The district court found, and Southern Card does not
    dispute, that as a result of these developments, Southern Card "has faced new competition" in retail
    stores in the Orlando area.
    II. PROCEDURAL HISTORY
    Southern Card instituted this lawsuit in February 1995, and its amended complaint asserted
    federal and state claims of (1) illegal tying pursuant to section 1 of the Sherman Act, 
    15 U.S.C. § 1
    , section 3 of the Clayton Act, 
    15 U.S.C. § 14
    , and Florida Statutes section 542.18; and (2)
    monopolization and attempted monopolization under section 2 of the Sherman Act, 
    15 U.S.C. § 2
    ,
    and Florida Statutes section 542.19. In outlining its tying claims, Southern Card stated that (1)
    Disney postcards constituted the "tying" product, and local view postcards were the "tied" product;
    (2) the "greater Orlando area" constituted the relevant geographic market or sub-market; and (3)
    the sale of local view postcards to distributors comprised the relevant product market. The crux of
    the tying claims was that Lawson "illegally compelled and coerced Southern Card and others to
    agree to purchase [local view postcards] from Lawson ... as a condition of obtaining and retaining
    access to Disney Cards." Southern Card sought treble damages, injunctive relief and attorneys' fees.6
    5
    Since 1994, Southern Card has continued to purchase these Disney postcards from Lawson
    but has acquired its entire local view stock from other manufacturers.
    6
    Southern Card's expert witness, Dr. Bruce Seaman, subsequently opined that Southern Card
    had suffered two types of injuries. According to Dr. Seaman, Southern Card "suffered economic
    damages linked to the overcharge on the tied non-Disney post cards." Also, Lawson's "refusal to
    allow Southern Card access to a full Disney array of post card products and other types of
    products has affected and will continue to affect Southern's profits on existing chain store
    accounts as well as the likelihood that chain store clients will continue to be lost due to the
    resulting weakening of Southern's relative competitive position."
    After the parties conducted extensive discovery, Lawson filed a motion for summary
    judgment that Southern Card vigorously opposed. In November 1996, the district court granted
    Lawson's motion. As to Southern Card's federal tying claims, the court first considered whether to
    deem Lawson's practices unlawful per se or subject to evaluation under the rule of reason. The court
    found that Lawson's practices were "unlike traditional tying arrangements" "because Southern Card
    does not allege that the ultimate consumer must buy the tied product (a local view postcard) to buy
    the tying product (a Disney postcard)." The court thus considered the challenged conduct to
    represent " "full' or "representative' line forcing," that is, a vertical nonprice restraint "undeserving
    of per se treatment." Applying the rule of reason, the court held that Southern Card failed to
    demonstrate that Lawson had unreasonably restrained competition in the local view postcard market.
    Notwithstanding its conclusion regarding the applicability of the rule of reason, the district
    court also went on to hold that even if it "were to use a per se analysis, Southern Card's tying claims
    would fail" because "the alleged "Disney' and non-Disney classifications are not separate products
    such that there can be a "tie-in' between them.... Rather, all of Lawson Mardon's postcards are
    sufficiently unitary to be considered a single product." Next, the court rejected Southern Card's
    federal monopolization and attempted monopolization claims on the grounds that Southern Card
    "failed to produce any admissible evidence that creates triable issues of fact with respect to the
    existence of a cognizable market or Lawson Mardon's monopoly power in such a market." Finally,
    the court turned away Southern Card's state claims, recognizing that "Florida antitrust law mirrors
    federal law as applied to the tying, monopolization and attempted monopolization claims in the
    instant case." On appeal, Southern Card challenges the district court's grant of summary judgment
    only as to its federal and state tying claims.
    III. DISCUSSION
    We review the granting of summary judgment de novo, applying the same legal standards
    that bound the district court. Uniforce Temporary Personnel, Inc. v. National Council on
    Compensation Ins., Inc., 
    87 F.3d 1296
    , 1299 (11th Cir.1996). "There is no genuine issue for trial
    unless the non-moving party establishes, through the record presented to the court, that it is able to
    prove evidence sufficient for a jury to return a verdict in its favor." Cohen v. United Am. Bank of
    Cent. Fla., 
    83 F.3d 1347
    , 1349 (11th Cir.1996).
    A.
    "A tying arrangement is "an agreement by a party to sell one product but only on the
    condition that the buyer also purchases a different (or tied) product, or at least agrees that he will
    not purchase that product from any other supplier.' " Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Servs.,
    Inc., 
    504 U.S. 451
    , 462, 
    112 S.Ct. 2072
    , 2079, 
    119 L.Ed.2d 265
     (1992) (quoting Northern Pac. Ry.
    Co. v. United States, 
    356 U.S. 1
    , 5-6, 
    78 S.Ct. 514
    , 518-519, 
    2 L.Ed.2d 545
     (1958)). Such
    arrangements can run afoul of the Sherman Act's prohibition against agreements "in restraint of
    trade," 
    15 U.S.C.A. § 1
     (West 1997), and section 3 of the Clayton Act, 
    15 U.S.C.A. § 14
     (West
    1997). See Spartan Grain & Mill Co. v. Ayers, 
    581 F.2d 419
    , 428 (5th Cir.1978) ("The Clayton Act,
    passed as a response to what Congress considered grudging constructions of the Sherman Act by
    the courts, specifically bans tying arrangements."), cert. denied, 
    444 U.S. 831
    , 
    100 S.Ct. 59
    , 
    62 L.Ed.2d 39
     (1979). As our predecessor court made clear, the two statutory theories of liability are
    substantively synonymous. Bob Maxfield, Inc. v. American Motors Corp., 
    637 F.2d 1033
    , 1037 (5th
    Cir. Unit A Feb.1981), cert. denied, 
    454 U.S. 860
    , 
    102 S.Ct. 315
    , 
    70 L.Ed.2d 158
     (1981); see also
    IX Phillip E. Areeda, Antitrust Law ¶ 1719b, at 254 (1991) ("Although their words differ, the two
    statutes apply a single substantive standard.").7
    Although the Sherman Act, by its terms, prohibits every agreement "in restraint of
    trade," this Court has long recognized that Congress intended to outlaw only unreasonable
    restraints. As a consequence, most antitrust claims are analyzed under a "rule of reason,"
    according to which the finder of fact must decide whether the questioned practice imposes
    an unreasonable restraint on competition, taking into account a variety of factors, including
    specific information about the relevant business, its condition before and after the restraint
    was imposed, and the restraint's history, nature, and effect.
    Some types of restraints, however, have such predictable and pernicious
    anticompetitive effect, and such limited potential for procompetitive benefit, that they are
    deemed unlawful per se. Per se treatment is appropriate once experience with a particular
    kind of restraint enables the Court to predict with confidence that the rule of reason will
    condemn it. Thus, we have expressed reluctance to adopt per se rules with regard to
    restraints imposed in the context of business relationships where the economic impact of
    certain practices is not immediately obvious.
    State Oil Co. v. Khan, --- U.S. ----, ----, 
    118 S.Ct. 275
    , 279, 
    139 L.Ed.2d 199
     (1997) (internal
    quotation marks, citations and brackets omitted). See also Levine v. Central Fla. Med. Affiliates,
    Inc., 
    72 F.3d 1538
    , 1549 (11th Cir.) ("The presumption in cases brought under section 1 of the
    Sherman Act is that the rule-of-reason standard applies. We apply the per se rule only when history
    and analysis have shown that in sufficiently similar circumstances the rule of reason unequivocally
    results in a finding of liability, i.e., when the conduct involved always or almost always tends to
    restrict competition and decrease output.") (internal quotation marks, citations and brackets omitted),
    cert. denied, --- U.S. ----, 
    117 S.Ct. 75
    , 
    136 L.Ed.2d 34
     (1996).
    "[C]ertain tying arrangements pose an unacceptable risk of stifling competition and therefore
    are unreasonable "per se.' " Jefferson Parish Hosp. Dist. No. 2 v. Hyde, 
    466 U.S. 2
    , 9, 
    104 S.Ct. 1551
    , 1556, 
    80 L.Ed.2d 2
     (1984). "It is clear, however, that not every refusal to sell two products
    7
    Because Southern Card does not discuss its state tying claim independently and fails to cite
    any Florida case law, we assume that federal antitrust doctrine controls that claim as well. See
    
    Fla. Stat. Ann. § 542.32
     (West 1997); see also Parts Depot Co. v. Florida Auto Supply, Inc., 
    669 So.2d 321
    , 324 (Fla.App. 4th D.C.A.1996) ("[T]he Legislature has directed courts to rely on
    comparable federal antitrust statutes in construing [Florida Statutes section 542.18].").
    separately can be said to restrain competition." Jefferson Parish, 
    466 U.S. at 11
    , 
    104 S.Ct. at 1557
    .
    "Thus, in a sense the question whether this case involves "tying' is beside the point. The legality of
    [Lawson's] conduct depends on its competitive consequences, not whether it can be labeled "tying.'
    " Jefferson Parish, 
    466 U.S. at
    21 n. 34, 
    104 S.Ct. at
    1563 n. 34.
    We believe that the terms that Lawson imposed on Southern Card pursuant to its "Disney
    Product Plan"—that Southern Card purchase local view postcards in amounts equal to its purchases
    of Disney postcards—are indicative of a manufacturer's "line force" upon a distributor.8 "Line
    forcing, be it full or representative, is a vertical nonprice restraint—an agreement between entities
    at different levels of distribution that does not purport to affect prices charged for the goods." Smith
    Machinery, 878 F.2d at 1295.9 As the Supreme Court has made clear, "economic analysis supports
    the view, and no precedent opposes it, that a vertical restraint is not illegal per se unless it includes
    some agreement on price or price levels." Business Electronics, 485 U.S. at 735-36, 108 S.Ct. at
    1525-26. This is so because such restraints have the "real potential to stimulate interbrand
    competition, "the primary concern of antitrust law.' " Business Electronics, 485 U.S. at 724, 108
    S.Ct. at 1519 (quoting Continental T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 
    433 U.S. 36
    , 51 n. 19, 
    97 S.Ct. 2549
    , 2558 n. 19, 
    53 L.Ed.2d 568
     (1977)).10
    8
    "Full-line" or "representative-line" forcing occurs when "a manufacturer agrees to license or
    franchise a dealer to sell its products, but only on condition that the dealer sell a full or
    representative line of those products." Smith Machinery Co. v. Hesston Corp., 
    878 F.2d 1290
    ,
    1294 (10th Cir.1989), cert. denied, 
    493 U.S. 1073
    , 
    110 S.Ct. 1119
    , 
    107 L.Ed.2d 1026
     (1990).
    9
    "Restraints imposed by agreement between competitors have traditionally been denominated
    as horizontal restraints, and those imposed by agreement between firms at different levels of
    distribution as vertical restraints." Business Elecs. Corp. v. Sharp Elecs. Corp., 
    485 U.S. 717
    ,
    730, 
    108 S.Ct. 1515
    , 1522, 
    99 L.Ed.2d 808
     (1988).
    10
    "Interbrand competition is the competition among the manufacturers of the same generic
    product.... In contrast, intrabrand competition is the competition between the
    distributors—wholesale or retail—of the product of a particular manufacturer." GTE Sylvania,
    As Professor Areeda has written, "requiring dealers to purchase a tied product from the
    defendant need not impair consumers' purchases from his rivals who sell directly to consumers or
    who continue to reach them through an ample number of other dealers." IX Areeda, Antitrust Law
    ¶ 1725a, at 317. The Tenth Circuit has similarly stated—in a case involving a distributor's claim that
    a manufacturer tied the sales of its established, popular farm machinery to sales of its new,
    unestablished tractors—that
    [i]n a line forcing situation, where a dealer is serving as an intermediate link in a distribution
    chain, if one manufacturer is foreclosed from selling to a dealer because of the arrangement,
    it is likely going to find another way to take its product to market, providing a profit
    potential continues to exist. In such a case, there is no ultimate foreclosure to the consumer
    of a choice of goods. In other more traditional tying arrangements there is an ultimate
    foreclosure of choice to the ultimate consumer. Thus, a foreclosure of choice to an ultimate
    consumer appears to be the principal key to a tie that is illegal per se. No such foreclosure
    occurs or is threatened in a typical line forcing situation such as that at bar.
    Smith Machinery, 878 F.2d at 1297 (citing Jefferson Parish, 
    466 U.S. at 5
    , 
    104 S.Ct. at 1554
    ;
    United States v. Loew's, Inc., 
    371 U.S. 38
    , 40, 
    83 S.Ct. 97
    , 99, 
    9 L.Ed.2d 11
     (1962); Northern Pac.
    Ry., 
    356 U.S. at 3
    , 
    78 S.Ct. at 517
    ; and International Salt Co. v. United States, 
    332 U.S. 392
    , 393,
    
    68 S.Ct. 12
    , 13, 
    92 L.Ed. 20
     (1947)). See also Roy B. Taylor Sales, Inc. v. Hollymatic Corp., 
    28 F.3d 1379
    , 1383 (5th Cir.1994) ("Ties that constrain only dealers ... create relatively little danger to
    competition, provided consumers may purchase the two goods separately.") (footnote omitted), cert.
    denied, 
    513 U.S. 1103
    , 
    115 S.Ct. 779
    , 
    130 L.Ed.2d 673
     (1995); Ransomes Am. Corp. v. Spartan
    Distribs., Inc., 
    914 F.Supp. 183
    , 185 (W.D.Mich.1996) ("Tying arrangements that constrain only
    dealers are not presumptively illegal because they pose little danger to competition, as long as
    consumers may purchase the two goods separately."); Paul E. Volpp Tractor Parts, Inc. v.
    Caterpillar, Inc., 
    917 F.Supp. 1208
    , 1229 (W.D.Tenn.1995) ("Because consumers are not hurt by
    
    433 U.S. at
    51 n. 19, 
    97 S.Ct. at 2558
    .
    vertical non-price restraints between manufacturers and dealers, the type of line-forcing/exclusive
    arrangement found in this case should not be subject to the same per se treatment as traditional tying
    arrangements."). Not surprisingly, then, "most courts dealing with the full-line force have not
    applied the per se rule against tying but have required proof in the particular case of a significant
    threat to competition." IX Areeda, Antitrust Law ¶ 1725c, at 323.
    Southern Card has made no showing that line-forcing arrangements like the one at issue
    always or almost always tend to restrict competition and decrease output. This fact, coupled with
    the strength of the authorities cited above, leads us to conclude that it would be inappropriate to
    deem Lawson's line-forcing practice unlawful per se. Thus, we will review the restraint under
    rule-of-reason analysis.
    For the same reasons, Lawson's (unsuccessful) attempt to compel Southern Card to carry
    only Lawson-produced local view postcards does not require us to employ a different standard.
    The claimed arrangement between [Lawson] and [Southern Card] constituted a vertical
    nonprice restraint between a manufacturer and a dealer on goods that the dealer offered to
    customers independently. It was in effect an exclusive-dealing arrangement in which
    [Lawson] required [Southern Card] to sell [Lawson], and only [Lawson], [local view
    postcards]. Such an arrangement is not the sort that would always or almost always tend to
    restrict competition and decrease output. It does not threaten competition to the same extent
    as tying arrangements that bind ultimate customers. Regardless of whether the restraint also
    constituted a tying arrangement, subjecting it to per se analysis would ignore our directive
    from the Court. The measure of legality of relationships between manufacturers and
    independent distributors must not be allowed to turn on labels.
    Taylor Sales, 
    28 F.3d at 1384-85
     (internal quotation marks and footnotes omitted).
    B.
    Under the rule of reason, a plaintiff must prove an anticompetitive effect of the defendant's
    conduct on the relevant market, and that the conduct has no procompetitive benefit or justification.
    Levine, 
    72 F.3d at 1551
    . Southern Card argues that Lawson's behavior generated anticompetitive
    effects because it (1) foreclosed the market to competitive manufacturers; (2) caused consumers to
    pay higher prices; and (3) resulted in a dilution in product quality and service. Southern Card thus
    attempts to prove that Lawson's conduct had an actual detrimental effect on competition. Levine,
    
    72 F.3d at 1551
    . We address Southern Card's contentions in turn.
    1.
    Southern Card asserts that the "record clearly supports the existence of market preclusion
    of competitive manufacturers of local view cards in the Orlando area." In support of this contention,
    Southern Card first argues that Lawson's "specific attack" on the sales base of one of its competitors,
    John Hinde Curteich & Co. (Hinde), evidences an anticompetitive effect. In making this argument,
    Southern Card relies primarily on the affidavit of Hinde vice-president Don Moffet.
    Moffet's affidavit, however, does little to advance Southern Card's cause. Moffet avers that
    Lawson's practices caused Hinde to lose "some"of its share of the local view postcard market to
    Lawson. Moffet also states, however, that as Disney postcards increased in popularity in the late
    1980s and early 1990s, Hinde's sales of local view postcards "began to decrease." We agree with
    Lawson that Moffet's affidavit is woefully deficient, as it fails to (1) state with any degree of
    specificity just how much business Hinde lost to Lawson; (2) describe any competitive actions
    Hinde took in response to Lawson's practices; or (3) explain away other potential reasons for
    Hinde's loss of business.
    Unfortunately for Southern Card, none of the other evidence it proffers is even as probative
    as Moffet's affidavit.11 In short, Southern Card has failed to show that Lawson's dealings somehow
    either precluded other manufacturers from gaining access to the local view postcard market or
    adversely impacted upon consumer choice. Thus, we have little difficulty in turning away Southern
    11
    We reach this conclusion after carefully reviewing the record citations put forth at pages
    fourteen and forty-one through forty-four of Southern Card's initial brief, and at pages seven
    through twelve of its reply brief.
    Card's contention here. As the Fifth Circuit has stated, "[s]peculation about anticompetitive effects
    is not enough." Taylor Sales, 
    28 F.3d at 1385
    .
    2.
    Southern Card next asserts that as a result of Lawson's practices, "the average price of local
    view postcards in the Orlando area was significantly higher than in any other part of [Florida]." In
    support of this assertion, Southern Card relies on a survey that its expert, Dr. Seaman, conducted.12
    Dr. Seaman avers that "[t]he result of the survey was that the average price of non-Disney local view
    cards in the Orlando area, as sold in gift shops by Scenic Card[ ] [a distributor that purchased all of
    its local view postcards from Lawson] is $.30, which is ... higher than the average price of $.25
    charged in retail outlets served by Southern Card [and another distributor].... The average price of
    local view post cards in the non-Orlando locations is also approximately $.25...."
    Southern Card's evidence is again lacking. As the district court correctly pointed out, the
    cited price differential "is of little value" because it may result from "the biased sample of local view
    postcard purchases from Orlando gift and souvenir shops, rather than from lower-cost retail outlets
    served by Southern Card," or from Dr. Seaman's failure "to factor in differentials in the cost of living
    (or cost of a vacation) in the various parts of the state." Moreover, Southern Card has not referenced
    any record evidence that enables this court to assess whether Lawson charged disproportionately
    higher prices for its local view postcards as compared to other manufacturers. In sum, Dr. Seaman's
    conclusion, standing alone, would not enable reasonable jurors to conclude that Lawson's practices
    caused consumers to pay more for local view postcards in the Orlando area. Southern Card's
    purported proof regarding anticompetitive effects thus remains overly speculative.
    12
    Dr. Seaman surveyed postcard prices at over 200 retail stores located throughout
    approximately forty different vacation areas in Florida.
    3.
    Finally, Southern Card argues that Lawson's practices caused a dilution in local view
    postcard quality and service in the Orlando area. Southern Card, however, fails to present any
    expert testimony or consumer survey evidence to support this subjective assessment. Instead,
    Southern Card first refers to a number of internal memoranda from Lawson describing various
    quality and service difficulties it experienced in its production and delivery of certain postcards.
    These documents, however, do not address the relative quality of Lawson's local view postcards.
    Southern Card also cites to the deposition testimony of Duncan Page, a president of both a postcard
    manufacturing company (i.e., a Lawson competitor) and a postcard distribution company, who, not
    surprisingly, states that he prefers to buy postcards from his own manufacturing company (even
    though "[t]he pricing is exactly the same as Lawson Mardon") because the "quality of our postcard
    and our images are better." Southern Card also references the affidavit of Joel Mittelberg, the
    president of Scenic Florida Distributors, Inc., who states, after noting that he purchases local view
    postcards from several manufacturers in addition to Lawson, that Lawson's delivery times on new
    work orders are "generally slower than is standard in the post card industry." The testimony of Page
    and Mittelberg, without more, certainly does not rise to the level of an anticompetitive effect in the
    relevant local view postcard market.13
    IV. CONCLUSION
    For the foregoing reasons, we hold that the district court was correct (1) in evaluating
    Southern Card's claims under the rule of reason, and (2) in concluding that Southern Card's evidence
    was insufficient for a reasonable jury to find that Lawson's sales practices generated an
    13
    Because we conclude that Southern Card has failed to establish a violation of the antitrust
    laws, we have no occasion to consider Lawson's challenge to Southern Card's standing to bring
    this lawsuit. See Levine, 
    72 F.3d at 1545
    .
    anticompetitive effect in the relevant market. Accordingly, we affirm the judgment of the district
    court.
    AFFIRMED.