Sargon Enterprises, Inc. v. University of Southern California , 55 Cal. 4th 747 ( 2012 )


Menu:
  • Filed 11/26/12
    IN THE SUPREME COURT OF CALIFORNIA
    SARGON ENTERPRISES, INC.,             )
    )
    Plaintiff and Appellant,   )
    )                             S191550
    v.                         )
    )               Ct.App. 2/1 B202789, B205034
    UNIVERSITY OF SOUTHERN                )
    CALIFORNIA et al.,                    )
    )                      Los Angeles County
    Defendants and Appellants. )                    Super. Ct. No. BC209992
    ____________________________________)
    A small dental implant company that had net profits of $101,000 in 1998
    has sued a university for breach of a contract for the university to clinically test a
    new implant the company had patented. The company seeks damages for lost
    profits beginning in 1998, ranging from $200 million to over $1 billion. It claims
    that, but for the university‘s breach of the contract, the company would have
    become a worldwide leader in the dental implant industry and made many millions
    of dollars a year in profit. Following an evidentiary hearing, the trial court
    excluded as speculative the proffered testimony of an expert to this effect. We
    must determine whether the court erred in doing so.
    We conclude that the trial court has the duty to act as a ―gatekeeper‖ to
    exclude speculative expert testimony. Lost profits need not be proven with
    mathematical precision, but they must also not be unduly speculative. Here, the
    court acted within its discretion when it excluded opinion testimony that the
    1
    company would have become extraordinarily successful had the university
    completed the clinical testing.
    We reverse the judgment of the Court of Appeal, which had held the trial
    court erred in excluding the testimony.
    I. FACTUAL AND PROCEDURAL HISTORY
    Because neither party petitioned the Court of Appeal for rehearing, much of
    this summary of the factual and procedural history is taken from that court‘s
    majority opinion. (See Richmond v. Shasta Community Services Dist. (2004) 
    32 Cal.4th 409
    , 415; Cal. Rules of Court, rule 8.500(c)(2).)
    A. The Lawsuit and First Appeal
    In 1991, plaintiff Sargon Enterprises, Inc. (Sargon) patented a dental
    implant that its president and chief executive officer, Dr. Sargon Lazarof, had
    developed. The United States Food and Drug Administration approved the
    implant, which meant it could be sold and used in the United States. As the Court
    of Appeal opinion described it, Sargon‘s implant ―could be implanted immediately
    following an extraction and contained both the implant and full restoration. [¶] In
    the 1980‘s, the standard implant was the Branemark implant developed at the
    University of Gothenburg in Sweden. The Branemark implant required several
    steps. First, surgery would place the implant in a healed extraction socket in the
    patient‘s mouth; a second surgery would inspect the implant to see if it had
    properly integrated with the bone (a process known as ‗osseointegration‘); last, a
    crown would be placed on the implant. Sargon‘s implant was a one stage implant:
    it expanded immediately into the bone socket with an expanding screw; this
    mechanism permitted the implant to be ‗loaded‘ with a crown the same day.‖
    In 1996, Sargon contracted with defendant University of Southern
    California (USC) for the USC School of Dentistry to conduct a five-year clinical
    2
    study of the implant. In May 1999, Sargon sued USC and faculty members of its
    dental school involved in the study, alleging breach of contract and other causes of
    action. USC cross-claimed for breach of contract. All of Sargon‘s claims except
    the breach of contract claim against USC were eliminated by demurrer or
    summary judgment. In 2003, the contract action was tried before a jury. Before
    trial, at an in limine hearing, the trial court excluded evidence of Sargon‘s lost
    profits on the ground USC could not have foreseen them.
    The evidence presented at trial showed that after initial success in the
    clinical trials, USC failed to present proper reports as its contract with Sargon
    required. The jury found that USC had breached the contract and awarded Sargon
    $433,000 in compensatory damages. It also found in Sargon‘s favor on USC‘s
    cross-complaint for breach of contract.
    Sargon appealed. The Court of Appeal reversed the judgment, holding that
    the trial court had erred in excluding evidence of Sargon‘s lost profits on the
    ground of foreseeability.1 It also stated, ―Given that the in limine hearings
    focused on foreseeability and not the amount of lost profit damages, it is
    premature to determine whether such damages can be calculated with reasonable
    certainty.‖ (Sargon Enterprises, Inc. v. University of Southern California (Feb.
    25, 2005, B167519) [nonpub. opn.].)
    On remand, the case proceeded to retrial on the breach of contract claim.
    USC moved to exclude as speculative the proffered opinion testimony of one of
    Sargon‘s experts, James Skorheim. The court presided over an eight-day
    evidentiary hearing at which Skorheim was the primary witness.
    1      We express no opinion on the correctness of this ruling, which is not before
    us on review.
    3
    B. The Evidentiary Hearing
    Skorheim testified that he was a certified public accountant and an attorney.
    He had been an accountant for 25 years and ―work[ed] as a business and industry
    analyst and forensic accountant.‖ As the Court of Appeal summarized, he testified
    that Sargon‘s lost profits ―ranged from $220 million to $1.18 billion. In preparing
    his opinion, Skorheim reviewed litigation materials (including deposition
    transcripts and reports of USC‘s damages experts), financial information from
    Sargon and its competitors (including annual reports), and market analyses of the
    global dental implant market prepared by Millennium Research Group . . .‖
    (Millennium). Skorheim based his opinion on a ―market share‖ approach, by
    which he determined what share of the worldwide dental implant market Sargon
    would have gained had USC completed a favorable clinical study, and he
    calculated future profits based on that market share. ―Skorheim used the market
    share approach to lost profit damages because the methodology had been used in
    complicated patent cases, antitrust cases, and unfair competition cases.‖
    The Court of Appeal summarized Skorheim‘s testimony about the dental
    implant industry: ―Nobel Biocare‘s Branemark implant was the pioneer implant
    developed in the 1960‘s and 1970‘s and required two surgeries. Straumann
    developed the second generation implant, which was placed in the bone without
    being submerged in the gum. In the early 1990‘s, there was very little penetration
    into the potential dental implant market. Out of millions of potential patients, only
    about 1 percent of this potential market was receiving product, presenting an
    opportunity for tremendous growth. In the late 1990‘s, the market began to grow
    dramatically. Industry reports demonstrated the global market was expected to
    grow during the period 1998 to 2009 at an annualized rate of 18.5 percent. At the
    time, the market craved technological innovation aimed at shortening healing time,
    cost, and treatment time. [Millennium] predicted that sales of immediate load
    4
    implants would grow at compound annual rates of 56.3 percent during 2002 to
    2006, and 32.8 percent from 2005 to 2009. Further, [Millennium] reported in
    2004, immediate loading implants represented only a ‗niche‘ market because
    demand was limited by industry acceptance. By 2009, immediate load implants
    would account for 14.9 percent of the United States market, up from 0.4 percent in
    2000.
    ―Sargon‘s innovation lay in the use of an ‗immediate load implant,‘ the
    ‗ ―holy grail of dental implantology,‖ ‘ which was directed at the market‘s need
    for ease of use, shortened healing times, and overall cost. Given the state of the
    implant market at the time, in Skorheim‘s opinion an innovator such as Sargon
    would have rapidly commanded a significant market share; with the exception of
    Nobel Biocare, all of the other major implant makers are recent arrivals on the
    scene.‖
    In Skorheim‘s opinion, three key ―market drivers‖ operate in the dental
    implant industry: (1) innovation, (2) clinical studies, and (3) outreach to general
    practitioners. A company must have all three to be successful. Skorheim had
    testified, the Court of Appeal stated, that ―[t]he value of a clinical study to an
    implant maker is two-fold: It establishes the efficacy of the device and permits
    entry into the universities where students can be taught to use the device, with the
    expectation that, upon graduation, they will use the product in their practices.‖ He
    believed that clinical success of the Sargon implant would likely lead to
    commercial success. Skorheim also had testified that because virtually every
    dental implant company employed clinical studies and general practitioner
    outreach, innovation really determined market success and what market share a
    company would achieve. He had explained, ―The greater the technological
    achievement in the product mix, the greater the likelihood for revenues.‖ In
    Skorheim‘s opinion, innovation was a necessary prerequisite to achieving market
    5
    success. ―[F]irst and foremost, you have to have the technological innovation and
    the efficacy.‖
    As the Court of Appeal observed, ―Skorheim‘s ‗market share‘ approach
    was based upon a comparison of Sargon to six other large, multinational dental
    implant companies that were the dominant market leaders in the industry, and
    which controlled in excess of 80 percent of global sales (Big Six): Nobel Biocare,
    Straumann, [Biomet 3i], Zimmer, Dentsply, and Astra Tech. Although there are
    approximately 96 companies worldwide that make dental implants, Skorheim
    believed the Big Six were the top innovators based upon his analysis of the
    [Millennium] report and market intelligence.‖ Skorheim had described the smaller
    companies as ―copycats‖ and ―price cutters‖ that competed on the basis of price
    and were not innovative; he believed that ―the top six are innovators and the rest
    are copycats.‖ The Court of Appeal stated: ―On cross-examination, Skorheim
    acknowledged that [Millennium‘s] report did not state the Big Six were the most
    innovative; rather, it was an inference he drew from reviewing the report and the
    size and success of the companies in comparison to other, smaller companies.‖
    Skorheim had acknowledged that many of the smaller companies claimed
    to be innovative, but he believed in fact they were not. When the trial court noted
    that the Millennium report mentioned other companies that claimed to be
    innovative, Skorheim had responded, ―And I would say that the proof is in the
    pudding. And the proof is their ability to track the market share and they haven‘t
    been able to do that.‖ When asked whether he agreed ―that the company with the
    largest market share is not necessarily the most innovative,‖ Skorheim had
    answered, ―I don‘t think I can agree with that. I mean, ultimately, the markets
    determine what‘s innovative and what‘s not innovative. These markets reward
    innovativeness. . . . And so the market really makes a determination of which of
    these companies is more innovative than not by the extent to which they reward
    6
    them with purchasing their products, and so forth.‖ Skorheim had acknowledged
    that the Millennium report did not specifically indicate that some of the smaller
    companies were not innovative, but explained that this was because ―those
    companies are not big enough to be even addressed in the global market, so there‘s
    nothing specific.‖
    Skorheim believed that Sargon was innovative, like the Big Six, and not a
    copycat or price cutter, like the other small companies. He acknowledged that
    Sargon was a very small company whose annual profits peaked in 1998 at around
    $101,000 and, unlike the big companies, it had no meaningful marketing or
    research and development organization and no parent company to assist it. But he
    believed these factors were merely ―incidental‖ to innovation and played little role
    in achieving market share. Accordingly, and because innovation is the key factor
    driving market success, Skorheim had compared Sargon to the ―Big Six‖ rather
    than to the smaller companies in computing lost profits. He considered the Big
    Six and Sargon to be ―comparable companies.‖
    Skorheim had testified that ―assuming the jury finds [the new implant] was
    a superior innovative revolutionary product and based upon everything else I see
    in the materials here, I think that Sargon had a very good chance of becoming the
    market leader over a period of time. I estimated maybe a 10-year period of time.‖
    Indeed, he believed to a ―reasonable certainty‖ that within 10 years or so Sargon
    would have become a market leader. He also believed it likely that one of the Big
    Six would have dropped out of the leadership, and that Sargon would have
    replaced that company as a world leader.
    When the trial court asked whether it mattered that some of the big
    companies had many different products, Skorheim had responded that Sargon
    ―would have to remain competitive by investing significant amounts of money in
    [research and development] like . . . the other major manufacturers. Each of them
    7
    are investing tens of millions of dollars a year into research and development to
    remain strong and technologically sound.‖ He was confident that a company like
    Sargon would have been able to expend the necessary resources to ―develop other
    products over time, that they would be able to use their patented expandable root
    process with other types of coatings, let‘s say, or shapes or sizes.‖ He thought
    Sargon‘s ability to do so distinguished it from the other small companies.
    The Court of Appeal stated: ―Skorheim outlined similarities and
    differences between the Big Six and Sargon: First, they all manufactured titanium
    implants, and the implants were one-stage, two-stage, or immediate load (Sargon
    only); second, all used clinical studies; third, all used outreach to general
    practitioners; fourth, pricing was substantially the same; fifth, their qualitative and
    quantitative cost structures were the same; and the implants were manufactured
    either in-house or pursuant to a contract with a third party. Qualitative cost
    structure consisted of cost of goods sold, research and development costs (R & D),
    sales and marketing costs, and general administrative costs. Sargon did not have a
    meaningful R & D organization or a sales and marketing department. In all other
    respects, Sargon‘s costs were similar to the Big Six.‖ Skorheim had
    acknowledged, however, that he could not think of any objective ―business
    metric‖ — ―whether it‘s sales, number of employees, number of distributers,
    anything‖ — by which Sargon was comparable to, for example, Astra Tech, the
    member of the Big Six with the smallest market share.
    The Court of Appeal opinion provided a chart summarizing Skorheim‘s
    testimony regarding Sargon and its competitors for the ―relevant time period,
    approximately 1998.‖ We reproduce it here:
    8
    Sargon       AstraZeneca        Dentsply       Biomet 3i        Nobel[2]
    (1998)         (1999)           (1998)          (2000)          (1998)
    Employees      < 20          > 55,000          > 6,000        > 4,000          > 1,000
    R&D            $    46,000   $ 2,923,000,000   $ 18,200,000   $ 40,208,000     $ 8,741,808
    Net Sales      $1,748,612    $18,445,000,000   $795,122,000   $ 920,582,000    $164,747,305
    Net Profits    $ 101,113     $ 1,143,000,000   $ 34,825,000   $ 173,771,000    $ 5,868,080
    Assets         $ 544,977     $19,816,000,000   $895,322,000   $1,218,448,000   $243,621,260
    Market Share   N/A           4.8%              7%             17%              22–23%
    (2007)[3]
    The dental implant business was only part of AstraZeneca‘s company.
    Skorheim testified that Astra Tech, its dental implant division, had sales in 1999 of
    $111 million.
    For the reasons he gave, Skorheim believed that Sargon, unlike any of the
    other smaller companies, would, over time, have become a market leader, one of
    the Big Six. In calculating Sargon‘s lost profits, he had not considered profits
    Sargon had ever actually realized, but instead considered the market leaders‘
    profits. He believed that Sargon‘s profits would have increased over time until
    they reached the level of one of the market leaders. He testified, however, that in
    one respect he had taken into account Sargon‘s actual income.4 He had started
    with Sargon‘s gross revenues (not net income) in 1998, the year USC should have
    produced an interim report, which were around $1.7 million to $1.8 million and
    2       The Court of Appeal explained that these figures were converted from
    Swedish kroner using the exchange rate in effect in 1998. Nobel Biocare acquired
    another implant company in 1999, which increased its market share and added
    products to its portfolio.
    3       The Court of Appeal explained that ―Straumann, another comparator
    company for which there was no data in the record during the relevant period, had
    attained a 22 percent global market share in 10 years.‖
    4       The trial court had initially sustained USC‘s objection to this testimony on
    the basis that it was inconsistent with Skorheim‘s deposition, and Sargon had
    failed to provide notice of this testimony, thus depriving USC of the opportunity to
    cross-examine Skorheim meaningfully on the point. But it permitted Skorheim to
    present this testimony ―to make a record.‖
    9
    constituted approximately one half of 1 percent of the total global market. He then
    doubled that number based on his belief that, had the initial report from the
    clinical study been favorable and had other potentially favorable publicity
    followed, Sargon would have sold approximately 20 implants each to
    approximately 200 additional dentists. This would have brought Sargon‘s market
    share for that year to about 1 percent. Skorheim believed that beginning in 1998,
    Sargon‘s market share would have ―ramp[ed] up‖ over the years from this 1
    percent to a share that a comparable member of the Big Six enjoyed. He had
    calculated the lost profits based on sales in 1998 of over $3 million and a
    subsequent increase each year until Sargon reached the level of one of the Big Six.
    Skorheim claimed no expertise regarding how innovative Sargon‘s dental
    implant was, although he had testified that ―the immediate loading of implants is
    kind of the so-called holy grail of dental implantology.‖ He said the jury would
    have to ―wrestle‖ with the question of how innovative Sargon was. Because of
    this lack of expertise, Skorheim could not give a single sum of lost profits. Rather,
    in Skorheim‘s opinion, the amount would depend on how innovative the jury
    found Sargon to be, compared to the market leaders.
    As the Court of Appeal explained, ―Skorheim‘s damages model created
    four alternative damage scenarios based upon the jury‘s determination of the
    innovativeness of the implant. As a predicate, Skorheim had ranked the
    innovativeness of the comparator companies and established a hierarchy. If the
    jury concluded Sargon‘s level of innovation was equal to the least innovative of
    the benchmark companies, Astra Tech, Sargon would have attained a 3.75 percent
    share; if the jury concluded Sargon‘s level of innovation was equal to one of the
    lesser innovators of the benchmark companies, like Dentsply, Sargon would have
    attained a 5 percent market share; if the jury concluded Sargon‘s level of
    innovation was equal to a middle-level innovator, like [Biomet 3i], Sargon would
    10
    have attained a 10 percent share; and if the jury concluded Sargon‘s level of
    innovation was that of the most innovative companies, Nobel Biocare and
    Straumann, Sargon would have attained a 20 percent market share.‖ In
    establishing this hierarchy, Skorheim had assumed that the higher the market share
    a company had obtained, the more innovative it was. He also agreed, however,
    that it was possible, for example, that Astra Tech, with its smaller market share,
    was more innovative than Biomet 3i, which had a greater market share.
    For each of these four scenarios, Skorheim had calculated lost profits from
    1998 to 2009, then added what he calculated to be post-2009 lost profits.
    Skorheim believed that Sargon‘s net profits, which in actuality peaked at $101,000
    in 1998, would have grown to $26 million per year in 2009 under the least
    profitable of the scenarios, and to $142 million per year in 2009 under the most
    profitable of the scenarios.
    The Court of Appeal opinion provided a chart summarizing Skorheim‘s lost
    profits calculations. We reproduce it here:
    Market             3.75%              5%                10%               20%
    Share           (Astra Tech)       (Dentsply)       (Biomet 3i)      (Nobel/Strau.)
    Lost Profits   $120,011,000      $181,020,949      $335,940,541      $ 640,232,628
    1998-2009
    Value            100,473,347      134,343,563       269,824,425       540,786,150
    Post 2009
    TOTAL:           $220,484,347     $315,364,512      $605,764,968 $1,181,018,778
    Thus, Skorheim had projected total lost profits of $220 million if the jury
    found Sargon‘s innovation was comparable to that of the least innovative market
    leaders, making what he described as a ―meaningful contribution to innovation‖;
    of $315 million if the jury found Sargon‘s innovation was somewhat greater; of
    $600 million if the jury found Sargon‘s innovation was somewhat greater yet; and
    of $1.2 billion if the jury found Sargon‘s innovation was comparable to that of the
    11
    market leaders, making what he described as ―revolutionary industry changing
    technology.‖
    The Court of Appeal summarized the testimony of the other witnesses at
    the evidentiary hearing. ―Dr. Lazarof confirmed Skorheim‘s conclusion that
    innovation coupled with clinical studies was the driver of market share. Sargon
    also presented the testimony of Steven Hanson, president from 1992 to 2004 of
    Calcitek, a successful implant company, who testified Sargon could have
    commanded a 15 to 20 percent share of the market if the USC study had been
    completed, although he had not done a market study or considered the probability
    of all of the other steps necessary to get Sargon a 15 to 20 percent market share.
    Robert Pendry was at Straumann from 1992 to 2001 and at Thommen Medical
    from 2002 to 2006, and testified that in his opinion the Sargon implant was
    ‗absolutely revolutionary‘ and ‗world changing‘ when introduced in 1997 to 1998.
    In Pendry‘s words, the Sargon implant ‗was the most exciting thing I‘d heard in
    the implant business ever.‘ ‖
    C. The Trial Court’s Ruling
    Following the evidentiary hearing, the court issued a 33-page written ruling
    on USC‘s motion to exclude Skorheim‘s testimony.
    The court began by quoting an opinion by Judge Friendly of the Second
    Circuit Court of Appeals stressing the need to protect juries from ―an array of
    figures conveying a delusive impression of exactness in an area where a jury‘s
    common sense is less available than usual to protect it.‖ (Herman Schwabe, Inc. v.
    United Shoe Machinery Corp. (2d Cir. 1962) 
    297 F.2d 906
    , 912.) The court found
    it unreasonable for Skorheim, ―or any such expert, to rely on much of the data
    which forms the basis of his opinions, because no data bears any resemblance to
    Plaintiff‘s historical profits or to those of any similar business.‖ ―Mr. Skorheim‘s
    12
    opinion leaves the determination of up to a billion dollars of lost profit damages to
    pure speculation.‖
    The court assumed for purposes of its ruling ―that a ‗market share‘ analysis
    is appropriate and warranted under California law,‖ but it found that Skorheim‘s
    ―market share opinion is not based on any actual historical financial results or
    comparisons to similar companies and, therefore, is not based on matter of a type
    [on which] an expert may reasonably rely.‖ ―The fatal flaw in Mr. Skorheim‘s
    reasoning is that it starts off assuming, without foundation, its conclusion. The
    fatal flaw in his analysis is that he relies on data that in no way is analogous to
    Plaintiff. Mr. Skorheim deems Plaintiff‘s historical data, such as past business
    volume, ‗not relevant‘ to his lost profits projections.‖ (Fn. omitted.)
    The court noted that at the evidentiary hearing, Skorheim had ―offered a
    new opinion that would have been grounded in some historical performance.‖ It
    explained that it had sustained USC‘s objection to this new opinion ―on grounds it
    was never disclosed in discovery. This court notes that this new methodology is
    directly inconsistent with Mr. Skorheim‘s declaration, depositions testimony and
    the position Plaintiff has taken throughout this litigation. . . . Regardless, the
    methodology of the new opinion is unreasonable.‖ Later in the evidentiary
    hearing, ―Plaintiff again attempted to show some historical grounding for the
    damage projections. Mr. Skorheim testified that his damage projections started
    with Sargon‘s gross revenues of $1,700,000 in 1997. Mr. Skorheim then doubled
    those revenues in 1998 . . . . To accomplish this, Mr. Skorheim assumed a
    favorable USC study and resultant publicity would cause 200 more dentists to buy
    at least 20 more implants each. The Court can find no factual basis for this
    assumption. [¶] . . . [¶] This Court specifically finds that Sargon‘s historical
    performance played no role in determining Mr. Skorheim‘s market projections,
    except to the extent that Sargon‘s data showed it had some sales.‖
    13
    The court found that Skorheim‘s ―projections are wildly beyond, by
    degrees of magnitude, anything Sargon had ever experienced in the past. Under
    the 20% market share scenario, for example, Plaintiff would see its profits climb
    by 534.4% the first year, and by over 157,000% by 2009.‖ Instead, the court
    found, Skorheim ―starts his analysis with a comparison to industry leaders, all
    multi-million or multi-billion international corporations, or subsidiaries of such.
    This, of course, is unavoidable if one only looks to industry ‗drivers‘ to ascertain
    who most successfully employs those ‗drivers.‘ [¶] The only thing these
    established companies have in common with Plaintiff is that they all sell or make
    dental implants. In all other respects, in areas the [Millennium] report deems
    relevant, such as size, history, product line, sales force, access to financing, among
    others, they are worlds apart from Sargon.‖ (Fn. omitted.)
    The court noted that Skorheim had testified ―that of all the 98 dental
    implant manufacturers, he could not identify one that did not pursue clinical
    studies or target general practitioners, rendering these two ‗drivers‘ meaningless
    for comparison purposes. [¶] Moreover, many implant companies who touted
    ‗innovative‘ products, yet had smaller revenues, were omitted for comparison
    purposes.‖ In his testimony, ―Mr. Skorheim grouped the companies that he
    deemed had ‗innovative‘ products. He omitted certain smaller companies who,
    according to the [Millennium] report, also claimed to have innovations. When
    asked in court to explain this omission, he testified, ‗The proof is in the pudding.‘
    The small market share of these companies showed the market disagreed.
    Apparently, a product is ‗innovative‘ if the market embraces it and it sells. [¶]
    The summary exclusion of other companies from his analysis, along with the fact
    that it should not be a startling revelation that biotechnology companies that have
    innovative products, all other things being equal, do better than those who do not,
    14
    render this ‗driver‘ equally meaningless for comparison purposes.‖ The court
    found this argument to be ―entirely circular.‖
    The court continued: ―At the hearing, Plaintiff changed its theory and
    attempted to show that it was similar to the industry leaders in ways other than
    possession of the three ‗drivers.‘ The characteristics that Mr. Skorheim contended
    made Plaintiff ‗similar‘ to the industry leaders, however, were characteristics
    common to most, if not all, implant companies. Obviously, if most share these
    ‗common traits,‘ the traits are meaningless for comparison purposes. If, based
    upon these common characteristics, the very smallest is considered ‗similar‘ to the
    very biggest, all cases that have required objective similarity would be effectively
    overruled, and the rule requiring ‗similarity‘ would cease to exist. This Court
    finds that Sargon is not similar to the industry leaders by any relevant, objective
    business measure.‖
    The court found that the dissimilarity between Sargon and the industry
    leaders ―is sufficient, itself, to grant Defendant‘s motion‖ to exclude Skorheim‘s
    testimony, but ―this court has other problems with Mr. Skorheim‘s opinion that
    give further grounds, by themselves, to grant Defendant‘s motion.‖ It found that
    ―[c]omparing ‗degrees of innovation‘ with other products fails to give the jury
    standards from which it can make a rational decision, is inherently speculative and
    subjective, and thus fails to assist the jury in its fact-finding function. [¶] The
    relevance of Mr. Skorheim‘s testimony, if any, is that it provides the jury with an
    evidentiary basis to make market share choices and thus assess damages. The jury
    can choose from four market shares ranging from 3.75% to 20%, depending upon
    its finding of relative ‗innovativeness.‘ The highest rating gets Nobel Biocare‘s
    share, with the lesser market share percentages awarded depending upon whether
    the innovativeness of the Plaintiff‘s implant is more on a par with products from
    Zimmer, 3i, and Straumann. The lowest percentage finding the jury can make is
    15
    that the innovativeness of the Sargon implant is comparable to Astra Tech‘s or
    Dentsply‘s products. The fatal problem with this is that there is little rational basis
    for this choice, and no rational standards for how the jury is to choose.
    ―Implicit in this choice is that there is an evidentiary basis for this ranking;
    an ‗innovativeness‘ pecking order where, in fact, Nobel Biocare is on top, others
    follow, with Astra Tech and Dentsply on the bottom. Likewise, there must be an
    evidentiary basis for degree of difference; evidence that shows not only that Nobel
    Biocare is more innovative, but, with 20% of the market, it must be twice as
    ‗innovative‘ as 3i, in the 10% group, and so on. Otherwise, ‗innovativeness‘
    would not track the percentage market share for the findings he proposes the jury
    make. Yet, the only factual basis for such a pecking order comes from Dr.
    Lazarof‘s opinion of such, and there is no evidence or reason to believe one
    company is more innovative than another, in the percentage difference, other than
    the fact the companies have different market shares. [¶] . . . [¶] The only
    possible evidentiary support for the percentage difference in the pecking order
    comes from Mr. Skorheim‘s oft repeated observations of the marketplace. Certain
    smaller companies, who claimed to have innovative products, were excluded from
    his ‗industry leader‘ market share list because ‗the market‘ disagreed with their
    claim of ‗innovativeness.‘ ‗The proof is in the pudding,‘ Mr. Skorheim explained.
    If their products were truly innovative, they would sell more and thus have larger
    market shares. [¶] . . . [¶] To the extent that this ranking of ‗innovativeness,‘
    with Nobel Biocare on top with 20%, and Astra Tech on the bottom with 3.75%,
    rests on the fact that some have larger market shares, it rests on nothing more than
    a tautology. As there is no evidentiary basis that equates the degree of
    innovativeness with the degree of difference in market share, the question posed to
    the jury — to rank innovativeness and assign a market share, the sine qua non of
    Mr. Skorheim‘s opinion — has no rational basis.‖
    16
    Additionally, the court continued, ―[t]he only rational answer to the
    question Mr. Skorheim seeks to have the jury answer comparing ‗innovativeness‘
    is ‗it depends.‘ What is ‗most innovative‘ about any implant depends upon what
    the practitioner and patient think is important. [¶] What is good, better or best is
    inherently subjective, and depends upon the need, the patient, the price, and the
    situation. [¶] . . . [¶] It is not that the jury, given the time confines of a trial,
    will not have enough information to decide relative ‗innovativeness,‘ it is that no
    jury, given an infinite amount of time, will ever have enough information. Such is
    the nature of purely subjective determinations. Which is the most innovative
    implant? The Court expects there to be experts giving their views, but do we have
    any standards or guidelines to help us in the determination?‖
    The court explained that in the Millennium reports ―there are many
    different types of implants. The market leaders have product lines of implants to
    serve the diverse needs of patients and practitioners. Some implants have different
    coating and/or screws. Some are immediate loading, some are two-stage loading,
    others have internal or external connections. Astra Tech markets an implant that it
    claims ‗has amassed significant documentation that confirms the increased bone
    retention right up to the top of the implant compared to competitive products.‘
    Another Astra Tech implant is touted as ‗simple and easier to use.‘ [Citation.]
    Others are more ‗affordable‘ such as INNOVA Life Sciences and IMTEC.
    [Citation.] Each company offers a line of implant products it claims are excellent
    for various uses.‖ ―Is the Sargon implant as good or better than those offered by
    competitors? Plaintiff will advocate for the Sargon implant. Who will advocate
    for all the rest?‖
    The court explained why, in its view, Skorheim‘s opinion was speculative.
    ―A jury can determine if a Ford was defective, because there are objective facts,
    such as industry standards and standards for safety, as well as a body of case law
    17
    on the subject of products liability. A jury cannot say if a Ford is a better car than
    a Chevrolet, because that is subjective and depends upon what the driver wants
    and what he can afford, among other things.
    ―By way of example, assume that Miss Oklahoma entered into a contract to
    transport her to the ‗Miss America‘ contest. Assume further that the carrier
    breached the contract and Miss Oklahoma missed the chance to compete. A jury
    could decide if she was damaged by the breach, to the extent damages could be
    ascertained. Could the jury go further and, based upon testimony of experts,
    decide that, had she been allowed to compete, she would have defeated Miss
    Colorado for the title of Miss America, or decide that she would have been second,
    behind Miss Colorado and ahead of Miss Montana? [¶] It is not a situation . . .
    that juries can and do decide complex issues. Of course they do. But in all cases,
    including cases where jurors are asked to ‗rank,‘ as in comparative fault, there are
    standards in the form of jury instructions and a body of case law to refer to if
    needed for special instructions.‖
    The court believed that asking a jury to rank innovativeness ―is no different
    than deciding whether Miss Oklahoma or Miss Colorado should wear the Miss
    America crown. [¶] Mr. Skorheim‘s question calls for nothing but a subjective
    and speculative response. Whether an implant is good, better or best can only be
    answered in the market place, not the jury room. The market place has rendered
    its verdict: ‗It depends.‘ That is why all the various implant companies, even the
    very biggest, and their implants have their own market niche with corresponding
    minority market shares. [¶] . . . [¶] Because there are no standards or guidelines
    to determine ‗degrees of innovation,‘ it relegates the question of determining
    potentially more than a billion dollars in damages to pure speculation.
    Accordingly, the court finds that there are two independent grounds to rule this
    evidence inadmissible: No damage award can be based on speculation; and
    18
    evidence that cannot assist the trier of fact in the resolution of an issue is not
    relevant.‖
    The court continued: ―Mr. Skorheim has no qualifications to opine that but
    for Defendant‘s breach, Plaintiff would have a program of targeting general
    practitioners on a par with any of the companies he singled out for comparison.
    [¶] The [Millennium] report sets forth sales and marketing strategies for the
    industry leaders. For example, Nobel Biocare in the 2001-2003 timeframe had 80
    field representatives in the United States alone. What makes Mr. Skorheim think
    that Plaintiff would equal or surpass these numbers, or done so with equal or
    greater success? The only information he can offer is the uncritical acceptance of
    Dr. Lazarof‘s hoped-for marketing plans. Whether these plans would ever have
    been implemented as anticipated, or succeeded, is pure speculation.‖
    ―Mr. Skorheim testified that, in the perfect world where there had been no
    breach, by 2007 Sargon would have made the seamless transition from a three-
    person operation to sharing industry leadership with Nobel Biocare, a multi-
    million dollar international corporation. Nobel Biocare touts, according to the
    annual reports he relied upon, many different product lines, including different
    types of implants. When asked how Sargon could be an industry leader with only
    one implant (he later testified that Sargon had developed seven) Mr. Skorheim
    testified that ‗he would expect‘ Sargon to have invested in ‗R and D‘ in the
    intervening years and also, by 2007, to have invented new products and coatings.
    Mr. Skorheim thus opined that not only would Sargon have invested in ‗R and D‘
    by 2007, but has also opined on what the results of that ‗R and D‘ would be. [¶] It
    is not reasonable for any expert to make such a faith-based prediction so
    absolutely devoid of any factual basis about an industry where he has no
    expertise.‖
    19
    Additionally, ―nowhere in [Skorheim‘s] success scenario is any mention of
    how competitors will react to having their market share taken by Plaintiff. . . . We
    do not know if these million or billion dollar corporations, or their shareholders,
    would just go quietly, because it is not discussed or considered. We are forced to
    assume they would do nothing.‖ ―This ‗Field of Dreams‘ ‗trust me‘ analysis
    forces us to assume, speculate and believe too much. It is no different than our
    Miss Oklahoma asking the jury to vote her Miss America and arguing that her
    damages include the inevitable movie deals and product endorsements that
    ‗common sense‘ dictates every Miss America receives and were lost because her
    transportation breached the contract to take her to the contest.‖ (Fn. omitted.)
    In its concluding portion, the court stated that ―case law demands that to
    establish such lost profits through expert testimony, the expert must base his/her
    opinion on either historical performance of the company or a comparison to the
    profits of companies similar in terms of size, locality, sales, products, number of
    employees and other relevant financial factors. A party is not permitted to ‗make
    up‘ its own factors as a basis for comparison and invite the jury to decide whether
    the corporations are similar. To allow this is to invite proceedings where there are
    no objective standards as there will always be some way to argue that companies
    are ‗similar,‘ no matter how superficial or irrelevant. Here, for example, the
    factors Mr. Skorheim uses would lead to the absurd result that Sargon, one of the
    industry‘s smallest companies, was ‗similar‘ to the largest. In assessing lost profit
    damages in this context, there is a meaningful difference between biggest and
    smallest. [¶] Mr. Skorheim admittedly shunned historical performance and
    comparison to companies of similar size and financial situation, choosing instead
    to compare Plaintiff to multi-national industry giants based upon his own criteria
    of ‗similar.‘ His criteria, even assuming he has the qualifications to decide them,
    which he does not, are nebulous and legally irrelevant under case law.
    20
    Accordingly, there is no issue of similarity to give to the jury to compare and
    decide.‖
    The court concluded ―that Mr. Skorheim‘s opinions are not based upon
    matters upon which a reasonable expert would rely, and do not show the nature
    and occurrence of lost profits with evidence of reasonable reliability, because his
    opinion is not based on any historical data from Plaintiff or a comparison to
    similar businesses. The court also finds his ‗market drivers‘ meaningless for
    comparison purposes. Additionally, his opinion rests on speculation and
    unreasonable assumptions.‖
    Accordingly, the court granted USC‘s motion to exclude Skorheim‘s
    testimony.
    D. The Second Appeal
    After the court excluded Skorheim‘s testimony, the parties stipulated to
    entry of judgment for $433,000 on Sargon‘s breach of contract claim. Sargon
    appealed for the second time.
    By a two-to-one vote, the Court of Appeal reversed the judgment and
    remanded the matter for a new trial on lost profits. It concluded the trial court
    erred in excluding Skorheim‘s testimony.
    After reviewing in detail the facts, the parties‘ arguments, and the relevant
    law, the court found that ―Sargon has the better argument here. . . . In 1998,
    Sargon had about $1.8 million in revenues, roughly one-half of 1 percent of the
    global market for dental implants. Astra Tech, one of the companies relied on by
    Skorheim, had around $18.5 million in revenues, for a 4.8 percent market share.
    The other companies had greater revenues and market shares. At the very least,
    the jury was entitled to hear about Astra Tech because it was sufficiently similar to
    21
    Sargon, and a damages award based on a comparison to that company would have
    been supported by substantial evidence, not speculation.
    ―We acknowledge the difficulty in determining lost profits when an
    established business is built upon the sale of an innovative, revolutionary, or
    world-changing product. The factor of innovation — what the trial court
    described as a ‗beauty contest‘ — is not easily converted into dollars and cents.
    But exactitude is not required. None of Sargon‘s competitors used its implant,
    and, to that extent, they were different. But lost profits may be based on a
    comparison of similar companies; they need not be identical in all respects.
    Skorheim‘s expert opinion was based on ‗economic and financial data, market
    surveys and analyses, business records of similar enterprises, and the like.‘ (Kids’
    Universe v. In2Labs[ (2002) 
    95 Cal.App.4th 870
    , 884].) He also considered
    Sargon‘s historical financial data. The trial court‘s ruling is tantamount to a flat
    prohibition on lost profits in any case involving a revolutionary breakthrough in an
    industry.
    ―If USC had not sabotaged the clinical study of the Sargon implant, Sargon
    would have had a successful clinical trial to its credit and a prominent university
    using the implant at its dental school. But it was denied. Through its wrongful
    conduct, USC allegedly caused the loss of profits and has made the proof of lost
    profits all the more difficult, thereby rendering its evidentiary attack unconvincing.
    (GHK Associates v. Mayer Group, Inc.[ (1990) 
    224 Cal.App.3d 856
    , 874].) We
    have carefully reviewed the trial court‘s criticisms of Skorheim‘s proffered
    testimony and conclude they were better left for the jury‘s assessment.‖
    Justice Johnson dissented. He argued that ―[w]here, as here, the law does
    not offer precise parameters to the quantum of proof required to establish lost
    profit damages, a trial court must be permitted to draw the line in the sand, either
    letting the evidence in as meeting the certainty threshold, or excluding it as below
    22
    that threshold. The placement of that threshold is left to the trial court so long as it
    is within the bounds of the law.‖ He found the trial court‘s decision to be
    ―founded on a detailed, methodical and well-reasoned examination of the law of
    contracts and the limits on lost profits damages. . . . [¶] . . . [T]he task of
    determining the threshold measure of certainty to permit Skorheim‘s opinion to go
    to the jury should be left to the gatekeeping function of the trial court, in the
    context of its evidentiary rulings after an evaluation of all of the facts, evidence,
    and arguments. Here, the trial court drew a very reasonable line in the sand with
    its ruling excluding Sargon‘s evidence of lost profit damages. I see no
    justification for this court to overturn that decision.‖
    The dissent argued that ―Sargon was not similar to the Big Six under any
    relevant, objective business measure‖ and found ―nothing in this ruling that
    indicates the trial court acted in an arbitrary, capricious fashion, was guided by
    whim rather than the rule of law, or exceeded the bounds of reason.‖ Justice
    Johnson added that ―while I admittedly share with the trial court a healthy dose of
    skepticism over Skorheim‘s unyieldingly optimistic projections for Sargon‘s
    market share growth and while I struggle to see a nexus between those projections
    and business and economic reality, this dissent nonetheless does not stem from the
    havoc that Skorheim‘s methodology may wreak upon reasonable damage
    calculations but from the damage done to the trial judge‘s reasonable and
    prudently exercised judgment on an evidentiary issue over which he and he alone
    should have decisional authority, absent arbitrariness and capriciousness. Nothing
    in the trial judge‘s reasonable, straightforward and clearly articulated evidentiary
    ruling bears even a smidgeon of arbitrariness or capriciousness.‖ Accordingly,
    Justice Johnson would have affirmed the trial court‘s ruling excluding Skorheim‘s
    testimony.
    23
    We granted USC‘s petition for review to decide whether the trial court
    erred in excluding Skorheim‘s testimony.
    II. DISCUSSION
    This case stands at the intersection of two legal principles: (1) Expert
    testimony must not be speculative, and (2) lost profit damages must not be
    speculative. We will discuss both principles, then apply them to this case.
    A. Expert Testimony
    As did the trial court, we begin our consideration of expert testimony with
    words that Judge Friendly wrote half a century ago: ―There is no bright line that
    divides evidence worthy of consideration by a jury, although subject to heavy
    counter-attack, from evidence that is not. Especially because of the guaranty of
    the Seventh Amendment, a federal court must be exceedingly careful not to set the
    threshold to the jury room too high. Yet it is the jury system itself that requires the
    common law ‗judge, in his efforts to prevent the jury from being satisfied by
    matters of slight value, capable of being exaggerated by prejudice and hasty
    reasoning . . . to exclude matter which does not rise to a clearly sufficient degree
    of value‘; ‗something more than a minimum of probative value‘ is required. 1
    Wigmore, Evidence (3d ed. 1940), pp. 409-410. These comments are especially
    pertinent to an array of figures conveying a delusive impression of exactness in an
    area where a jury‘s common sense is less available than usual to protect it.‖
    (Herman Schwabe, Inc. v. United Shoe Machinery Corp., supra, 297 F.2d at p.
    912.)
    Although Judge Friendly was discussing federal law and federal courts, his
    comments, both in their cautionary note that, due to the jury trial right, courts
    should not set the admission bar too high, and in their stressing the need to exclude
    unreliable evidence, could just as well have described California law and
    24
    California courts. Under California law, trial courts have a substantial
    ―gatekeeping‖ responsibility.5
    Evidence Code section 801 provides: ―If a witness is testifying as an
    expert, his testimony in the form of an opinion is limited to such an opinion as is:
    [¶] (a) Related to a subject that is sufficiently beyond common experience that
    the opinion of an expert would assist the trier of fact; and [¶] (b) Based on matter
    . . . that is of a type that reasonably may be relied upon by an expert in forming an
    opinion upon the subject to which his testimony relates, unless an expert is
    precluded by law from using such matter as a basis for his opinion.‖ (Italics
    added.) Subdivision (b) clearly permits a court to determine whether the matter is
    of a type on which an expert may reasonably rely.
    In Lockheed Litigation Cases (2004) 
    115 Cal.App.4th 558
    , 563, the
    plaintiffs argued that under Evidence Code section 801, subdivision (b), ―a court
    should determine only whether the type of matter that an expert relies on in
    forming his or her opinion is the type of matter that an expert reasonably can rely
    on in forming an opinion, without regard to whether the matter relied on
    reasonably does support the particular opinion offered.‖ The Court of Appeal
    disagreed. ―An expert opinion has no value if its basis is unsound. [Citations.]
    Matter that provides a reasonable basis for one opinion does not necessarily
    provide a reasonable basis for another opinion. Evidence Code section 801,
    subdivision (b), states that a court must determine whether the matter that the
    expert relies on is of a type that an expert reasonably can rely on ‗in forming an
    5      Recent United States Supreme Court decisions have referred to the trial
    judge‘s ― ‗gatekeeper‘ role‖ (General Electric Co. v. Joiner (1997) 
    522 U.S. 136
    ,
    142) or ― ‗gatekeeping‘ obligation‖ (Kumho Tire Co. v. Carmichael (1999) 
    526 U.S. 137
    , 141). We have used the term ―gatekeeping responsibility.‖ (People v.
    Prince (2007) 
    40 Cal.4th 1179
    , 1225, fn. 8.)
    25
    opinion upon the subject to which his testimony relates.‘ (Italics added.) We
    construe this to mean that the matter relied on must provide a reasonable basis for
    the particular opinion offered, and that an expert opinion based on speculation or
    conjecture is inadmissible.‖ (Lockheed Litigation Cases, supra, at p. 564.)
    We agree with this analysis. Indeed, as the Court of Appeal in that case
    also noted (Lockheed Litigation Cases, supra, 115 Cal.App.4th at p. 564), the
    California Law Revision Commission comments to Evidence Code section 801
    explained that ―under existing law, irrelevant or speculative matters are not a
    proper basis for an expert‘s opinion. See Roscoe Moss Co. v. Jenkins [(1942) 
    55 Cal.App.2d 369
    ] (expert may not base opinion upon a comparison if the matters
    compared are not reasonably comparable) . . . .‖ (Cal. Law Revision Com. com.,
    29B pt. 3A West‘s Ann. Evid. Code (2009 ed.) foll. § 801, p. 25.) Comments of a
    commission that proposed a statute are entitled to substantial weight in construing
    the statute, especially when, as here, the Legislature adopted the statute without
    change. (Jevne v. Superior Court (2005) 
    35 Cal.4th 935
    , 947.) Thus, under
    Evidence Code section 801, the trial court acts as a gatekeeper to exclude
    speculative or irrelevant expert opinion. As we recently explained, ―[T]he
    expert‘s opinion may not be based ‗on assumptions of fact without evidentiary
    support [citation], or on speculative or conjectural factors . . . . [¶] Exclusion of
    expert opinions that rest on guess, surmise or conjecture [citation] is an inherent
    corollary to the foundational predicate for admission of the expert testimony: will
    the testimony assist the trier of fact to evaluate the issues it must decide?‘
    (Jennings v. Palomar Pomerado Health Systems, Inc. (2003) 
    114 Cal.App.4th 1108
    , 1117.)‖ (People v. Richardson (2008) 
    43 Cal.4th 959
    , 1008; accord, People
    v. Moore (2011) 
    51 Cal.4th 386
    , 405.)
    Additionally, as a recent law review article explains, Evidence Code section
    801 is not the only statute that governs the trial court‘s gatekeeping role. We must
    26
    also consider Evidence Code section 802. (See Imwinkelried & Faigman,
    Evidence Code Section 802: The Neglected Key to Rationalizing the California
    Law of Expert Testimony (2009) 42 Loyola L.A. L.Rev. 427 (hereafter
    Imwinkelried & Faigman).)
    Evidence Code section 802 provides: ―A witness testifying in the form of
    an opinion may state . . . the reasons for his opinion and the matter . . . upon which
    it is based, unless he is precluded by law from using such reasons or matter as a
    basis for his opinion. The court in its discretion may require that a witness before
    testifying in the form of an opinion be first examined concerning the matter upon
    which his opinion is based.‖ (Italics added.) This section indicates the court may
    inquire into the expert‘s reasons for an opinion. It expressly permits the court to
    examine experts concerning the matter on which they base their opinion before
    admitting their testimony. The reasons for the experts‘ opinions are part of the
    matter on which they are based just as is the type of matter. Evidence Code
    section 801 governs judicial review of the type of matter; Evidence Code section
    802 governs judicial review of the reasons for the opinion. ―The stark contrast
    between the wording of the two statutes strongly suggests that although under
    section 801(b) the judge may consider only the acceptability of the generic type of
    information the expert relies on, the judge is not so limited under section 802.‖
    (Imwinkelried & Faigman, supra, 42 Loyola L.A. L.Rev. at p. 441.)
    Evidence Code section 802 also permits the trial court to find the expert is
    precluded ―by law‖ from using the reasons or matter as a basis for the opinion.
    ― ‗Law‘ includes constitutional, statutory, and decisional law.‖ (Evid. Code,
    § 160.) Thus, ―construed in the context of section 160, section 802 authorizes a
    court to promulgate case law restrictions on an expert‘s ‗reasons‘ . . . .‖
    (Imwinkelried & Faigman, supra, 42 Loyola L.A. L.Rev, at p. 442.) This means
    that a court may inquire into, not only the type of material on which an expert
    27
    relies, but also whether that material actually supports the expert‘s reasoning. ―A
    court may conclude that there is simply too great an analytical gap between the
    data and the opinion proffered.‖ (General Electric Co. v. Joiner, 
    supra,
     522 U.S.
    at p. 146, quoted in Imwinkelried & Faigman, supra, 42 Loyola L.A. L.Rev., at p.
    448.)
    Thus, under Evidence Code sections 801, subdivision (b), and 802, the trial
    court acts as a gatekeeper to exclude expert opinion testimony that is (1) based on
    matter of a type on which an expert may not reasonably rely, (2) based on reasons
    unsupported by the material on which the expert relies, or (3) speculative. Other
    provisions of law, including decisional law, may also provide reasons for
    excluding expert opinion testimony.6
    But courts must also be cautious in excluding expert testimony. The trial
    court‘s gatekeeping role does not involve choosing between competing expert
    opinions. The high court warned that the gatekeeper‘s focus ―must be solely on
    principles and methodology, not on the conclusions that they generate.‖ (Daubert
    v. Merrell Dow Pharmaceuticals, Inc., supra, 509 U.S. at p. 595.) The advisory
    committee on the 2000 amendments to Federal Rules of Evidence, rule 702, which
    codified the rule established in Daubert, noted that the trial court‘s task is not to
    choose the most reliable of the offered opinions and exclude the others: ―When a
    trial court, applying this amendment, rules that an expert‘s testimony is reliable,
    this does not necessarily mean that contradictory expert testimony is unreliable.
    6      In People v. Leahy (1994) 
    8 Cal.4th 587
    , 604, this court held that the
    ―general acceptance‖ test for admissibility of expert testimony based on new
    scientific techniques (see People v. Kelly (1976) 
    17 Cal.3d 24
    ) still applies in
    California courts despite the United States Supreme Court‘s rejection, in Daubert
    v. Merrell Dow Pharmaceuticals, Inc. (1993) 
    509 U.S. 579
    , of a similar test in
    federal courts. Nothing we say in this case affects our holding in Leahy regarding
    new scientific techniques.
    28
    The amendment is broad enough to permit testimony that is the product of
    competing principles or methods in the same field of expertise.‖ (Advisory Com.
    Notes to Federal Rules Evid., rule 702, 28 U.S.C.)
    The trial court‘s preliminary determination whether the expert opinion is
    founded on sound logic is not a decision on its persuasiveness. The court must not
    weigh an opinion‘s probative value or substitute its own opinion for the expert‘s
    opinion. Rather, the court must simply determine whether the matter relied on can
    provide a reasonable basis for the opinion or whether that opinion is based on a
    leap of logic or conjecture. The court does not resolve scientific controversies.
    Rather, it conducts a ―circumscribed inquiry‖ to ―determine whether, as a matter
    of logic, the studies and other information cited by experts adequately support the
    conclusion that the expert‘s general theory or technique is valid.‖ (Imwinkelried
    & Faigman, supra, 42 Loyola L.A. L.Rev. at p. 449.) The goal of trial court
    gatekeeping is simply to exclude ―clearly invalid and unreliable‖ expert opinion.
    (Black et al., Science and the Law in the Wake of Daubert: A New Search for
    Scientific Knowledge (1994) 72 Tex. L.Rev. 715, 788.) In short, the gatekeeper‘s
    role ―is to make certain that an expert, whether basing testimony upon professional
    studies or personal experience, employs in the courtroom the same level of
    intellectual rigor that characterizes the practice of an expert in the relevant field.‖
    (Kumho Tire Co. v. Carmichael, 
    supra,
     526 U.S. at p. 152.)
    Except to the extent the trial court bases its ruling on a conclusion of law
    (which we review de novo), we review its ruling excluding or admitting expert
    testimony for abuse of discretion. (People v. McWhorter (2009) 
    47 Cal.4th 318
    ,
    362; People v. Gardeley (1996) 
    14 Cal.4th 605
    , 619; People v. Mickey (1991) 
    54 Cal.3d 612
    , 687-688; Lockheed Litigation Cases, supra, 115 Cal.App.4th at p.
    564.) A ruling that constitutes an abuse of discretion has been described as one
    that is ―so irrational or arbitrary that no reasonable person could agree with it.‖
    29
    (People v. Carmony (2004) 
    33 Cal.4th 367
    , 377.) But the court‘s discretion is not
    unlimited, especially when, as here, its exercise implicates a party‘s ability to
    present its case. Rather, it must be exercised within the confines of the applicable
    legal principles.
    ―The discretion of a trial judge is not a whimsical, uncontrolled power, but
    a legal discretion, which is subject to the limitations of legal principles governing
    the subject of its action, and to reversal on appeal where no reasonable basis for
    the action is shown.‖ (9 Witkin, Cal. Procedure (5th ed. 2008) Appeal, § 364, p.
    420; see Westside Community for Independent Living, Inc. v. Obledo (1983) 
    33 Cal.3d 348
    , 355 [quoting this language].) ―The scope of discretion always resides
    in the particular law being applied, i.e., in the ‗legal principles governing the
    subject of [the] action . . . .‘ Action that transgresses the confines of the applicable
    principles of law is outside the scope of discretion and we call such action an
    ‗abuse‘ of discretion. [Citation.] . . . [¶] The legal principles that govern the
    subject of discretionary action vary greatly with context. [Citation.] They are
    derived from the common law or statutes under which discretion is conferred.‖
    (City of Sacramento v. Drew (1989) 
    207 Cal.App.3d 1287
    , 1297-1298.) To
    determine if a court abused its discretion, we must thus consider ―the legal
    principles and policies that should have guided the court‘s actions.‖ (People v.
    Carmony, 
    supra,
     33 Cal.4th at p. 377.)
    In this case, we consider whether the trial court properly exercised its
    discretion to exclude expert opinion testimony. As we have explained, the trial
    court‘s discretion in this regard is circumscribed; it must be exercised within the
    limits the law permits. Accordingly, we must review the record to ensure that the
    ruling comes within the scope of that discretion.
    30
    B. Lost Profits
    Lost profits may be recoverable as damages for breach of a contract.
    ―[T]he general principle [is] that damages for the loss of prospective profits are
    recoverable where the evidence makes reasonably certain their occurrence and
    extent.‖ (Grupe v. Glick (1945) 
    26 Cal.2d 680
    , 693.) Such damages must ―be
    proven to be certain both as to their occurrence and their extent, albeit not with
    ‗mathematical precision.‘ ‖ (Lewis Jorge Construction Management, Inc. v.
    Pomona Unified School Dist. (2004) 
    34 Cal.4th 960
    , 975.) The rule that lost
    profits must be reasonably certain is a specific application of a more general
    statutory rule. ―No damages can be recovered for a breach of contract which are
    not clearly ascertainable in both their nature and origin.‖ (Civ. Code, § 3301; see
    Greenwich S.F., LLC v. Wong (2010) 
    190 Cal.App.4th 739
    , 760.)
    Regarding lost business profits, the cases have generally distinguished
    between established and unestablished businesses. ―[W]here the operation of an
    established business is prevented or interrupted, as by a . . . breach of contract . . . ,
    damages for the loss of prospective profits that otherwise might have been made
    from its operation are generally recoverable for the reason that their occurrence
    and extent may be ascertained with reasonable certainty from the past volume of
    business and other provable data relevant to the probable future sales.‖ (Grupe v.
    Glick, supra, 26 Cal.2d at p. 692.) ―Lost profits to an established business may be
    recovered if their extent and occurrence can be ascertained with reasonable
    certainty; once their existence has been so established, recovery will not be denied
    because the amount cannot be shown with mathematical precision. [Citations.]
    Historical data, such as past business volume, supply an acceptable basis for
    ascertaining lost future profits. [Citations.] In some instances, lost profits may be
    recovered where plaintiff introduces evidence of the profits lost by similar
    31
    businesses operating under similar conditions. [Citations.]‖ (Berge v.
    International Harvester Co. (1983) 
    142 Cal.App.3d 152
    , 161-162.)
    ―On the other hand, where the operation of an unestablished business is
    prevented or interrupted, damages for prospective profits that might otherwise
    have been made from its operation are not recoverable for the reason that their
    occurrence is uncertain, contingent and speculative. . . . But although generally
    objectionable for the reason that their estimation is conjectural and speculative,
    anticipated profits dependent upon future events are allowed where their nature
    and occurrence can be shown by evidence of reasonable reliability.‖ (Grupe v
    Glick, supra, 26 Cal.2d at pp. 692-693.)
    ―Where the fact of damages is certain, the amount of damages need not be
    calculated with absolute certainty. [Citations.] The law requires only that some
    reasonable basis of computation of damages be used, and the damages may be
    computed even of the result reached is an approximation. [Citation.] This is
    especially true where . . . it is the wrongful acts of the defendant that have created
    the difficulty in proving the amount of loss of profits [citation] or where it is the
    wrongful acts of the defendant that have caused the other party to not realize a
    profit to which that party is entitled.‖ (GHK Associates v. Mayer Group, Inc.
    (1990) 
    224 Cal.App.3d 856
    , 873-874 [permitting an award of profits calculated
    from a project‘s ―actual income‖].)
    A recent case provides an example of claimed lost profits that were found
    to be ―uncertain, hypothetical and entirely speculative.‖ (Greenwich S.F., LLC v.
    Wong, supra, 190 Cal.App.4th at p. 743.) There the plaintiffs sought lost profits
    for breach of a real property sales agreement. They ―presented evidence of lost
    profits through the testimony of [a] real estate appraiser,‖ who testified about what
    the property would have been worth had it been developed according to the
    intended plans and specifications. (Id. at p. 749.) The appellate court found the
    32
    resulting award of $600,000 in lost profits to be unsupported. ―[T]he occurrence
    and extent of the projected lost profits were not proven with the requisite
    reasonable certainty in this case.‖ (Id. at p. 760.) ―The evidence in this case was
    insufficient to show that [either plaintiff] was an established business or had a
    track record of successfully developing or redeveloping properties. . . . [¶] . . .
    The existence of plans for a development does not supply substantial evidence that
    the development is reasonably certain to be built, much less that it is reasonably
    certain to produce profits.‖ (Id. at p. 763.) ―The lost profits claim was based on
    the assumption that [plaintiffs] would have constructed the residence according to
    the plans and specifications without changes and that the venture would have been
    profitable. These assumptions were inherently uncertain, contingent,
    unforeseeable and speculative. The proposed real estate development project here
    involved numerous variables that made any calculation of lost profits inherently
    uncertain.‖ (Id. at p. 766.)
    Once again, we add a cautionary note. The lost profit inquiry is always
    speculative to some degree. Inevitably, there will always be an element of
    uncertainty. Courts must not be too quick to exclude expert evidence as
    speculative merely because the expert cannot say with absolute certainty what the
    profits would have been. Courts must not eviscerate the possibility of recovering
    lost profits by too broadly defining what is too speculative. A reasonable certainty
    only is required, not absolute certainty.
    C. Application to This Case
    We now apply these principles to this case. The issue before us is whether
    the court abused its discretion in excluding the expert testimony, not whether
    substantial evidence supports a lost profits award. But the substantive law
    regarding lost profits is relevant to help define the type of matter on which an
    33
    expert may reasonably rely. For example, as the trial court explained, ―While lost
    profits can be established with the aid of expert testimony, economic and financial
    data, market surveys and analysis, business records of similar enterprises and the
    like, the underlying requirement for each is ― ‗a substantial similarity between the
    facts forming the basis of the profit projections and the business opportunity that
    was destroyed.‖ ‘ ‖ (Quoting Kids’ Universe v. In2Labs, supra, 95 Cal.App.4th at
    p. 886.) But, as the trial court further found, Skorheim‘s analysis relied ―on data
    that in no way is analogous to Plaintiff.‖
    To the extent that the expert relied on data that is not relevant to the
    measure of lost profit damages, the trial court acted within its discretion to exclude
    the testimony because it was not ―[b]ased on matter . . . that is of a type that
    reasonably may be relied upon by an expert in forming an opinion upon the
    subject to which his testimony relates . . . .‖ (Evid. Code, § 801, subd. (b); see
    Westrec Marina Management, Inc. v. Jardine Ins. Brokers Orange County, Inc.
    (2000) 
    85 Cal.App.4th 1042
    , 1050-1051 [upholding the exclusion of expert
    testimony due in part to substantive law of lost profits].) Accordingly, although
    the issue is the admissibility of expert testimony, we will also consider the law of
    lost profits to the extent it is relevant to that issue.
    The trial court did not abuse its discretion in the sense of making a ruling
    that was irrational or arbitrary. It presided over a lengthy evidentiary hearing and
    provided a detailed ruling. The Court of Appeal majority identified no specific
    error in that ruling. As the dissenter in the Court of Appeal stated, ―Nothing in the
    trial judge‘s reasonable, straightforward and clearly articulated evidentiary ruling
    bears even a smidgeon of arbitrariness or capriciousness.‖ Indeed, the court could
    hardly have exercised its discretion more carefully.
    The trial court also excluded the expert testimony for proper reasons. It
    properly found the expert‘s methodology was too speculative for the evidence to
    34
    be admissible. The court assumed that Skorheim‘s market share approach would
    be appropriate in a proper case. We will do so also. An expert might be able to
    make reasonably certain lost profit estimates based on a company‘s share of the
    overall market. But Skorheim did not base his lost profit estimates on a market
    share Sargon had ever actually achieved. Instead, he opined that Sargon‘s market
    share would have increased spectacularly over time to levels far above anything it
    had ever reached. He based his lost profit estimates on that hypothetical increased
    share.
    Skorheim considered Sargon to be comparable to the Big Six dental
    implant companies rather than the smaller ones that appear to have far more
    closely resembled it. He admitted that by no objective business metric, such as
    sales or number of employees, was Sargon in fact comparable to the Big Six.
    Instead, he based his comparison solely on his belief that Sargon, like the Big Six,
    and unlike the rest, was innovative, and that innovation was the prime market
    driver. (He also testified that clinical studies and outreach to general practitioners
    were market drivers, but he recognized that all dental implant companies used
    them, thus making them essentially irrelevant for comparison purposes.) But, as
    the trial court noted, Skorheim‘s reasoning was circular. He concluded that the
    Big Six were innovative because they were successful, and that the smaller
    companies (excluding Sargon) were not innovative because they were less
    successful. In essence, he said that the smaller companies were smaller because
    they were not innovative. The trial court properly considered this circularity in the
    reasoning as a basis to exclude the testimony under Evidence Code section 802.
    Skorheim based his estimates on the belief that the more innovative a
    company was, the larger the market share it would achieve. Thus, he testified, if
    Sargon had a level of innovation equal to that of the smallest of the Big Six, it
    would have gained only its level of market share. He then testified to gradations
    35
    of innovation, with each increase in innovation equaling a step up in market share
    and thus in future profits. However, as the trial court explained, ―Implicit in this
    choice is that there is an evidentiary basis for this ranking; an ‗innovativeness‘
    pecking order where, in fact, Nobel Biocare is on top, others follow, with Astra
    Tech and Dentsply on the bottom. Likewise, there must be an evidentiary basis
    for degree of difference; evidence that shows not only that Nobel Biocare is more
    innovative, but, with 20% of the market, it must be twice as ‗innovative‘ as 3i, in
    the 10% group, and so on. Otherwise, ‗innovativeness‘ would not track the
    percentage market share for the findings he proposes the jury make.‖ But
    Skorheim also agreed that a company with a smaller market share could, in fact,
    be more innovative than a company with a larger share.
    As the trial court further explained, ―The only possible evidentiary support
    for the percentage difference in the pecking order comes from Mr. Skorheim‘s oft
    repeated observations of the marketplace. Certain smaller companies, who
    claimed to have innovative products, were excluded from his ‗industry leader‘
    market share list because ‗the market‘ disagreed with their claim of
    ‗innovativeness.‘ ‗The proof is in the pudding,‘ Mr. Skorheim explained. If their
    products were truly innovative, they would sell more and thus have larger market
    shares. [¶] . . . [¶] To the extent that this ranking of ‗innovativeness,‘ with
    Nobel Biocare on top with 20%, and Astra Tech on the bottom with 3.75%, rests
    on the fact that some have larger market shares, it rests on nothing more than a
    tautology. As there is no evidentiary basis that equates the degree of
    innovativeness with the degree of difference in market share, the question posed to
    the jury — to rank innovativeness and assign a market share, the sine qua non of
    Mr. Skorheim‘s opinion — has no rational basis.‖
    Sargon argues that the cases concerning an unestablished company do not
    apply here because it was an established company with a track record of having
    36
    made a profit. It had, for example, a net profit of $101,000 in 1998. But Sargon
    had no track record of being a global leader, one of the Big Six. An established
    company may base its claim to future profits on evidence of its past profits, but
    Skorheim did not do so. He tried to compare Sargon to the Big Six, but the
    companies were not comparable. In Parlour Enterprises, Inc. v. Kirin Group, Inc.
    (2007) 
    152 Cal.App.4th 281
     (Parlour Enterprises), a jury gave a small restaurant
    business called Farrell‘s a multimillion-dollar lost profit award. The Court of
    Appeal reversed the award, finding the claim of lost profits was improperly based
    on speculative expert testimony. The expert in that case had compared the
    company to ―a publicly traded restaurant chain called Friendly‘s, which he
    claimed was ‗relatively similar to the Farrell‘s concept.‘ ‖ (Id. at p. 290.) But the
    Court of Appeal found the two companies not comparable. ―Although one way to
    prove prospective profits is through the experience of comparable businesses, [the
    expert‘s] cursory description of Friendly‘s business model failed to establish its
    profit-and-loss experience is sufficiently similar to Farrell‘s to be relevant to the
    question of plaintiffs‘ alleged lost profits.‖ (Ibid.) The court explained that
    ―[b]efore evidence of similar businesses may be used to prove loss of prospective
    profits, there must be ‗ ―a substantial similarity between the facts forming the basis
    of the profit projections and the business opportunity that was destroyed.‖ ‘ ‖ (Id.
    at p. 291.)
    This case is like Parlour Enterprises, supra, 
    152 Cal.App.4th 281
    . Except
    for Skorheim‘s belief that, like the Big Six and unlike the rest of the smaller
    companies, Sargon was innovative, Sargon was dissimilar to all of the Big Six. As
    the trial court noted, ―Sargon is not similar to the industry leaders by any relevant,
    objective business measure.‖ Skorheim did not base his lost profits estimates on
    any objective evidence of ―past volume of business‖ or any ―other provable data
    relevant to the probable future sales.‖ (Grupe v. Glick, supra, 26 Cal.2d at p. 692.)
    37
    Instead, as the trial court further noted, Skorheim‘s lost profit projections were
    ―wildly beyond, by degrees of magnitude, anything Sargon had ever experienced
    in the past.‖
    In finding that the trial court should have admitted Skorheim‘s testimony,
    the majority below observed that ―exactitude is not required.‖ The observation is
    correct. If lost profits can be estimated with reasonable certainty, a court may not
    deny recovery merely because one cannot determine precisely what they would
    have been. But exactitude is not the problem here. Whether the actual profits
    could logically be estimated in the manner Skorheim claimed is the problem. As
    the trial court noted, a lost profit award of up to $1 billion may not be based on
    pure speculation.
    The Court of Appeal majority found that the case of Palm Medical Group,
    Inc. v. State Comp. Ins. Fund (2008) 
    161 Cal.App.4th 206
     ―is more on point‖ than
    Parlour Enterprises, supra, 
    152 Cal.App.4th 281
    . In Palm Medical, a medical
    clinic sued, claiming it was wrongly denied admission into a preferred provider
    network. The Court of Appeal upheld a lost profits award. But there the
    plaintiff‘s expert based his lost profits estimate on the plaintiff‘s own profit margin
    and a comparison to the profits of other clinics that had participated in the
    preferred provider network from which the plaintiff had been excluded. (Id. at p.
    227.) As far as the opinion indicates, the plaintiff and the other clinics were, in
    fact, comparable. The opinion gives no indication the defendant claimed
    otherwise. Nothing in Palm Medical suggests the trial court here abused its
    discretion in finding Sargon not to be comparable to the Big Six.
    Sargon also relies on Sanchez-Corea v. Bank of America (1985) 
    38 Cal.3d 892
    . The trial court considered and aptly distinguished that case: ―In Sanchez-
    Corea, the earnings of plaintiff‘s small company were compared to the earnings of
    ‗other companies, including Honeywell, which occupied the market after
    38
    [plaintiff‘s] departure . . . .‘ (Id. at p. 907.) On appeal, the defendant complained,
    as does USC, that the comparison was unfair because plaintiff had ‗far smaller
    financial resources.‘ (Id. at p. 908.) [¶] Sargon‘s reliance is misplaced. The
    Supreme Court held the evidence supported a $1,000,000 compensatory damage
    award because the damage award was based on Plaintiff‘s historical growth, as
    Plaintiff had experienced a ‗tenfold growth in contracts (sales) from $180,000 in
    1970 to $1.5 million in 1973.‘ (Id. at p. 907.) In that case, the Plaintiff‘s expert‘s
    projections were based on pre-litigation estimates, which underestimated
    Plaintiff‘s actual growth in the year before Defendant‘s wrongful act and the
    subsequent lawsuit. The court never discussed the comparison to Honeywell, and
    this case has never been cited as authority for comparing businesses of any size.‖
    As the trial court also noted, Skorheim‘s testimony was speculative in other
    ways as well. He assumed Sargon, which had virtually no marketing or research
    and development departments, would have developed such departments to permit
    it to compete with the Big Six, all of which had large ones. He assumed one of the
    Big Six would fall out of that group, and Sargon would replace it. He assumed the
    Big Six would have taken no steps to contend with their new competitor, Sargon.
    All of these factors also support the trial court‘s exclusion of Skorheim‘s
    testimony.
    Skorheim gave the opinion that, to a ―reasonable certainty,‖ Sargon would
    have become a market leader within 10 years. The quoted term derives from the
    law of lost profits. We stated in Grupe v. Glick, supra, 26 Cal.2d at page 693, that
    lost profits must be ―reasonably certain‖ to be recoverable. But, as the trial court
    found, this testimony was inherently speculative. It ―involved numerous variables
    that made any calculation of lost profits inherently uncertain.‖ (Greenwich S.F.,
    LLC v. Wong, supra, 190 Cal.App.4th at p. 766.) Skorheim‘s attempt to predict
    the future was in no way grounded in the past.
    39
    If a professional football team claims lost profits because a certain
    defensive lineman did not play for it the previous season, could an expert testify
    that in his opinion the key driver for success in the National Football League is
    quarterback sacks and, because the player was the best in the league in sacking the
    quarterback, the team would have won the Super Bowl had he played? Could
    another expert counter that testimony by expressing her opinion that the key to
    success is turnovers, and, because the player was not particularly adept at forcing
    turnovers, the team would not even have made the playoffs with that player?
    Should the court ask the jury to choose between the two experts? Or could the
    jury choose something in between and conclude the team would have reached, but
    lost, the Super Bowl? Or lost in the conference title game?
    Similarly, if a first-time author sues a publisher for breach of a contract to
    publish a novel, could a witness who was an expert on the publishing business,
    literature, and popular culture testify that the novel, if published, would have
    become a national bestseller, won the Pulitzer Prize, and spawned a megahit
    movie with several blockbuster sequels? Could a jury award lost profits based on
    that scenario? Or could it compromise by finding the book would have been a
    bestseller but would not have won the Pulitzer Prize, and would have spawned a
    moderately successful movie but no sequel?
    World history is replete with fascinating ―what ifs.‖ What if Alexander the
    Great had been killed early in his career at the Battle of the Granicus River, as he
    nearly was? What if the Saxon King Harold had prevailed at Hastings, and
    William, later called the Conqueror, had died in that battle rather than Harold?
    What if the series of Chinese overseas discovery expeditions that two Ming
    Dynasty emperors sponsored, and that reached at least the east coast of Africa by
    1432, had continued rather than stopped? Many serious, and not-so-serious,
    historians have enjoyed speculating about these what ifs. But few, if any, claim
    40
    they are considering what would have happened rather than what might have
    happened. Because it is inherently difficult to accurately predict the future or to
    accurately reconstruct a counterfactual past, it is appropriate that trial courts
    vigilantly exercise their gatekeeping function when deciding whether to admit
    testimony that purports to prove such claims.
    An accountant might be able to determine with reasonable precision what
    Sargon‘s profits would have been if it had achieved a market share comparable to
    one of the Big Six. The problem here, however, is that the expert‘s testimony
    provided no logical basis to infer that Sargon would have achieved that market
    share. The lack of sound methodology in the expert‘s testimony for determining
    what the future would have brought supported the trial court‘s ruling.
    The Court of Appeal majority was concerned that ―[t]he trial court‘s ruling
    is tantamount to a flat prohibition on lost profits in any case involving a
    revolutionary breakthrough in an industry.‖ We disagree. Other avenues might
    exist to show lost profits. An expert could use a company‘s actual profits, a
    comparison to the profits of similar companies, or other objective evidence to
    project lost profits. Sargon itself argues that the record in this case contains
    evidence of specific lost sales and canceled contracts due to USC‘s failure to
    complete the study. Evidence of this kind might support reasonably certain lost
    profit estimates.7 The trial court‘s ruling merely meant Sargon could not obtain a
    massive verdict based on speculative projections of future spectacular success.
    7       Sargon notes that the trial court had ruled that at least some of this evidence
    was insufficient to support a claim of intentional interference with prospective
    economic advantage. The court found no evidence the lost sales were related to
    USC‘s actions or omissions. It is not clear how this ruling would have affected a
    lost profit claim. What is clear is that the ruling is not before us on appeal.
    Moreover, even if this type of evidence would not have been sufficient to support
    (footnote continued on next page)
    41
    The trial court properly acted as a gatekeeper to exclude speculative expert
    testimony. Its ruling came within its discretion. The majority in the Court of
    Appeal erred in concluding otherwise.
    III. CONCLUSION
    We reverse the judgment of the Court of Appeal and remand the matter to
    that court for further proceedings consistent with this opinion.
    CHIN, J.
    WE CONCUR:
    CANTIL-SAKAUYE, C. J.
    KENNARD, J.
    BAXTER, J.
    WERDEGAR, J.
    CORRIGAN, J.
    LIU, J.
    (footnote continued from previous page)
    a lost profit claim in this case, similar evidence might support such a claim in
    some other case.
    42
    See next page for addresses and telephone numbers for counsel who argued in Supreme Court.
    Name of Opinion Sargon Enterprises, Inc. v. University of Southern California
    __________________________________________________________________________________
    Unpublished Opinion XXX NP opn. filed 2/9/11 – 2d Dist., Div. 1
    Original Appeal
    Original Proceeding
    Review Granted
    Rehearing Granted
    __________________________________________________________________________________
    Opinion No. S191550
    Date Filed: November 26, 2012
    __________________________________________________________________________________
    Court: Superior
    County: Los Angeles
    Judge: Terry A. Green
    __________________________________________________________________________________
    Counsel:
    Browne George Ross, Brown Woods George, Allan Browne, Eric M. George, Benjamin D. Scheibe, Ira
    Bibbero; Glaser Weil Fink Jacobs Howard Avchen & Shapiro, Patricia L. Glaser, Elizabeth G. Chilton and
    Andrew Baum for Plaintiff and Appellant.
    Quinn Emanuel Urquhart & Sullivan, Quinn Emanuel Urquhart Oliver & Hedges, Kathleen M. Sullivan,
    Daniel H. Bromberg, John B. Quinn, Michael E. Williams and Michael T. Lifrak for Defendants and
    Appellants.
    Cole Pedroza, Curtis A. Cole and Cassidy E. Cole for California Medical Association, California Hospital
    Association and California Dental Association as Amici Curiae on behalf of Defendants and Appellants.
    Daniel J. Popeo, Richard A. Samp; Bergeson and Mark E. Foster for Washington Legal Foundation and
    Allied Educational Foundation as Amici Curiae on behalf of Defendants and Appellants.
    Mayer Brown and Donald M. Falk for Actelion Pharmaceuticals U.S. as Amicus Curiae on behalf of
    Defendants and Appellants.
    Ada Meloy; Hogan Lovells US, Michael Shepard, Martin Michaelson, Alexander Dreier and David Ginn
    for American Council on Education and other Higher Education Associations and Institutions as Amici
    Curiae on behalf of Defendants and Appellants.
    Morgan, Lewis & Bockius, Thomas M. Peterson and Benjamin P. Smith for Asahi Kasei Pharma
    Corporation as Amicus Curiae on behalf of Defendants and Appellants.
    43
    Counsel who argued in Supreme Court (not intended for publication with opinion):
    Eric M. George
    Browne George Ross
    2121 Avenue of the Stars, Suite 2400
    Los Angeles, CA 90067
    (310) 274-7100
    Kathleen M. Sullivan
    Quinn Emanuel Urquhart & Sullivan
    555 Twin Dolphin Drive, 5th Floor
    Redwood Shores, CA 94065
    (650) 801-5000
    44
    

Document Info

Docket Number: S191550

Citation Numbers: 55 Cal. 4th 747, 288 P.3d 1237, 149 Cal. Rptr. 3d 614, 2012 Cal. LEXIS 10713

Judges: Chin

Filed Date: 11/26/2012

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 10/19/2024

Cited By (35)

Iloh v. The Regents of the U. of Cal. ( 2023 )

Bronte v. Albarez CA4/1 ( 2023 )

People v. Vielma CA4/2 ( 2023 )

Bader v. Johnson & Johnson ( 2023 )

Quarker v. City of Culver City CA2/1 ( 2023 )

Hopping v. Oppenheim CA1/2 ( 2023 )

In re C.C. CA6 ( 2023 )

Boer and Sons v. Gomes CA5 ( 2023 )

In re Berthelotte CA4/2 ( 2023 )

People v. Thongvilay CA4/2 ( 2023 )

In re Clare M. CA1/2 ( 2023 )

Mendoza v. Martinez CA2/3 ( 2023 )

Onglyza Product Cases ( 2023 )

Exteres Corp. v. The Connections Group CA4/2 ( 2023 )

People v. Gerardo CA4/2 ( 2023 )

Lincoln Pacific Builders v. Elecnor Belco Electric CA2/7 ( 2023 )

People v. Vierra CA2/3 ( 2023 )

Armstrong Townhomes v. Milgard Manufacturing CA1/2 ( 2023 )

Koganti v. PODS Enterprises CA4/1 ( 2023 )

Connolly Ranch v. Department of Parks and Recreation CA3 ( 2023 )

View All Citing Opinions »