NRG Power Marketing, LLC v. Maine Public Utilities Commission , 130 S. Ct. 693 ( 2010 )


Menu:
  • (Slip Opinion)              OCTOBER TERM, 2009                                       1
    Syllabus
    NOTE: Where it is feasible, a syllabus (headnote) will be released, as is
    being done in connection with this case, at the time the opinion is issued.
    The syllabus constitutes no part of the opinion of the Court but has been
    prepared by the Reporter of Decisions for the convenience of the reader.
    See United States v. Detroit Timber & Lumber Co., 
    200 U. S. 321
    , 337.
    SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES
    Syllabus
    NRG POWER MARKETING, LLC, ET AL. v. MAINE PUB-
    LIC UTILITIES COMMISSION ET AL.
    CERTIORARI TO THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR
    THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA CIRCUIT
    No. 08–674.      Argued November 3, 2009—Decided January 13, 2010
    The Mobile-Sierra doctrine—see United Gas Pipe Line Co. v. Mobile
    Gas Service Corp., 
    350 U. S. 332
    , and FPC v. Sierra Pacific Power
    Co., 
    350 U. S. 348
    —requires the Federal Energy Regulatory Commis
    sion (FERC) to presume that an electricity rate set by a freely negoti
    ated wholesale-energy contract meets the Federal Power Act’s (FPA)
    “just and reasonable” prescription, 16 U. S. C. §7824d(a); the pre
    sumption may be overcome only if FERC concludes that the contract
    seriously harms the public interest. Morgan Stanley Capital Group
    Inc. v. Public Util. Dist. No. 1 of Snohomish Cty., 554 U. S. ___, ___.
    For many years, New England’s supply of electricity capacity was
    barely sufficient to meet the region’s demand. FERC and New Eng
    land’s generators, electricity providers, and power customers made
    several attempts to address the problem. This case arises from the
    latest effort to design a solution. Concerned parties reached a com
    prehensive settlement agreement (Agreement) that, inter alia, estab
    lished rate-setting mechanisms for sales of energy capacity and pro
    vided that the Mobile-Sierra public interest standard would govern
    rate challenges. FERC approved the Agreement, finding that it pre
    sents a just and reasonable outcome that is consistent with the public
    interest. Objectors to the settlement sought review in the D. C. Cir
    cuit, which largely rejected their efforts to overturn FERC’s approval
    order, but agreed with them that when a challenge to a contract rate
    is brought by noncontracting third parties, Mobile-Sierra’s public in
    terest standard does not apply.
    Held: The Mobile-Sierra presumption does not depend on the identity of
    the complainant who seeks FERC investigation. The presumption is
    not limited to challenges to contract rates brought by contracting par
    2           NRG POWER MARKETING, LLC v. MAINE PUB.
    UTIL. COMM’N
    Syllabus
    ties. It applies, as well, to challenges initiated by noncontracting
    parties. Pp. 5–11.
    (a) Morgan Stanley did not reach the question presented here, but
    its reasoning strongly suggests that the D. C. Circuit’s holding mis
    perceives the aim, and diminishes the force, of the Mobile-Sierra doc
    trine. Announced three months after the Court of Appeals’ disposi
    tion in this case, Morgan Stanley reaffirmed Mobile-Sierra’s
    instruction to FERC to “presume that the rate set out in a freely ne
    gotiated . . . contract meets the ‘just and reasonable’ requirement”
    unless “FERC concludes that the contract seriously harms the public
    interest.” 554 U. S., at ___. The Morgan Stanley opinion makes it
    unmistakably clear that the public interest standard is not, as the
    D. C. Circuit suggested, independent of, and sometimes at odds with,
    the “just and reasonable” standard. Rather, the public interest stan
    dard defines “what it means for a rate to satisfy the just-and
    reasonable standard in the contract context.” Id., at ___. And if
    FERC itself must presume just and reasonable a contract rate result
    ing from fair, arms-length negotiations, noncontracting parties may
    not escape that presumption. Moreover, the Mobile-Sierra doctrine
    does not neglect third-party interests; it directs FERC to reject a con
    tract rate that “seriously harms the consuming public.” 554 U. S., at
    ___. Finally, the D. C. Circuit’s confinement of Mobile-Sierra to rate
    challenges by contracting parties diminishes the doctrine’s animating
    purpose: promotion of “the stability of supply arrangements which all
    agree is essential to the health of the [energy] industry.” Mobile, 350
    U. S., at 344. A presumption applicable to contracting parties only,
    and inoperative as to everyone else—consumers, advocacy groups,
    state utility commissions, elected officials acting parens patriae—
    could scarcely provide the stability Mobile-Sierra aimed to secure.
    Pp. 5–10.
    (b) Whether the rates at issue qualify as “contract rates” for Mo
    bile-Sierra purposes, and, if not, whether FERC had discretion to
    treat them analogously are questions raised before, but not ruled
    upon by, the D. C. Circuit. They remain open for that court’s consid
    eration on remand. Pp. 10–11.
    
    520 F. 3d 464
    , reversed in part and remanded.
    GINSBURG, J., delivered the opinion of the Court, in which ROBERTS,
    C. J., and SCALIA, KENNEDY, THOMAS, BREYER, ALITO, and SOTOMAYOR,
    JJ., joined. STEVENS, J., filed a dissenting opinion.
    Cite as: 558 U. S. ____ (2010)                              1
    Opinion of the Court
    NOTICE: This opinion is subject to formal revision before publication in the
    preliminary print of the United States Reports. Readers are requested to
    notify the Reporter of Decisions, Supreme Court of the United States, Wash­
    ington, D. C. 20543, of any typographical or other formal errors, in order
    that corrections may be made before the preliminary print goes to press.
    SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES
    _________________
    No. 08–674
    _________________
    NRG POWER MARKETING, LLC, ET AL., PETITIONERS
    v. MAINE PUBLIC UTILITIES COMMISSION ET AL.
    ON WRIT OF CERTIORARI TO THE UNITED STATES COURT OF
    APPEALS FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA CIRCUIT
    [January 13, 2010]
    JUSTICE GINSBURG delivered the opinion of the Court.
    The Federal Power Act (FPA or Act), 
    41 Stat. 1063
    , as
    amended, 16 U. S. C. §791a et seq., authorizes the Federal
    Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC or Commission) to
    superintend the sale of electricity in interstate commerce
    and provides that all wholesale-electricity rates must be
    “just and reasonable,” §824d(a). Under this Court’s Mo
    bile-Sierra doctrine, FERC must presume that a rate set
    by “a freely negotiated wholesale-energy contract” meets
    the statutory “just and reasonable” requirement. Morgan
    Stanley Capital Group Inc. v. Public Util. Dist. No. 1 of
    Snohomish Cty., 554 U. S. ___, ___ (2008) (slip op., at 1).
    “The presumption may be overcome only if FERC con­
    cludes that the contract seriously harms the public inter­
    est.” Ibid.
    This case stems from New England’s difficulties in
    maintaining the reliability of its energy grid. In 2006,
    after several attempts by the Commission and concerned
    parties to address the problems, FERC approved a com­
    prehensive settlement agreement (hereinafter Settlement
    Agreement or Agreement).         Most relevant here, the
    2       NRG POWER MARKETING, LLC v. MAINE PUB.
    UTIL. COMM’N
    Opinion of the Court
    Agreement established rate-setting mechanisms for sales
    of energy capacity, and provided that the Mobile-Sierra
    public interest standard would govern rate challenges.
    Parties who opposed the settlement petitioned for review
    in the United States Court of Appeals for the D. C. Circuit.
    Among multiple objections to FERC’s order approving the
    Agreement, the settlement opponents urged that the rate
    challenges of nonsettling parties should not be controlled
    by the restrictive Mobile-Sierra public interest standard.
    The Court of Appeals agreed, holding that “when a rate
    challenge is brought by a non-contracting third party, the
    Mobile-Sierra doctrine simply does not apply.” Maine Pub.
    Util. Comm’n v. FERC, 
    520 F. 3d 464
    , 478 (2008) (per
    curiam).
    We reverse the D. C. Circuit’s judgment to the extent
    that it rejects the application of Mobile-Sierra to noncon­
    tracting parties. Our decision in Morgan Stanley, an­
    nounced three months after the D. C. Circuit’s disposition,
    made clear that the Mobile-Sierra public interest standard
    is not an exception to the statutory just-and-reasonable
    standard; it is an application of that standard in the con­
    text of rates set by contract. The “venerable Mobile-Sierra
    doctrine” rests on “the stabilizing force of contracts.”
    Morgan Stanley, 554 U. S., at ___ (slip op., at 19); see id.,
    at 22 (describing contract rates as “a key source of stabil­
    ity”). To retain vitality, the doctrine must control FERC
    itself, and, we hold, challenges to contract rates brought
    by noncontracting as well as contracting parties.
    I
    In a capacity market, in contrast to a wholesale energy
    market, an electricity provider purchases from a generator
    an option to buy a quantity of energy, rather than pur­
    chasing the energy itself. To maintain the reliability of
    the grid, electricity providers generally purchase more
    capacity, i.e., rights to acquire energy, than necessary to
    Cite as: 558 U. S. ____ (2010)                    3
    Opinion of the Court
    meet their customers’ anticipated demand. For many
    years in New England, the supply of capacity was barely
    sufficient to meet the region’s demand. FERC and New
    England’s generators, electricity providers, and power
    customers made several attempts to address this problem.
    This case stems from the latest effort to design a solution.
    In 2003, a group of generators sought to enter into
    “reliability must-run” agreements with the New England
    Independent System Operator (ISO), which operates the
    region’s transmission system.1 In its orders addressing
    those agreements, FERC directed the ISO to develop a
    new market mechanism that would set prices separately
    for various geographical sub-regions. Devon Power LLC,
    
    103 FERC ¶61,082
    , pp. 61,266, 61,271 (2003).
    In March 2004, the ISO proposed a market structure
    responsive to FERC’s directions. See Devon Power LLC,
    
    107 FERC ¶61,240
    , p. 62,020 (2004). FERC set the matter
    for hearing before an Administrative Law Judge (ALJ),
    who issued a 177-page order largely accepting the ISO’s
    proposal. Devon Power LLC, 
    111 FERC ¶63,063
    , p. 65,205
    (2005). Several parties filed exceptions to the ALJ’s order;
    on September 20, 2005, the full Commission heard argu­
    ments on the proposed market structure, and thereafter
    established settlement procedures. Devon Power LLC, 
    113 FERC ¶61,075
    , p. 61,271 (2005).
    After four months of negotiations, on March 6, 2006, a
    settlement was reached. Of the 115 negotiating parties,
    only 8 opposed the settlement.
    The Settlement Agreement installed a “forward capacity
    market” under which annual auctions would set capacity
    ——————
    1 An ISO is an independent company that has operational control, but
    not ownership, of the transmission facilities owned by member utilities.
    ISOs “provide open access to the regional transmission system to all
    electricity generators at rates established in a single, unbundled, grid­
    wide tariff . . . .” Midwest ISO Transmission Owners v. FERC, 
    373 F. 3d 1361
    , 1364 (CADC 2004) (internal quotation marks omitted).
    4             NRG POWER MARKETING, LLC v. MAINE PUB.
    UTIL. COMM’N
    Opinion of the Court
    prices; auctions would be conducted three years in ad­
    vance of the time when the capacity would be needed.
    Devon Power LLC, 
    115 FERC ¶61,340
    , pp. 62,304, 62,306–
    62,308 (2006). Each energy provider would be required to
    purchase enough capacity to meet its share of the “in­
    stalled capacity requirement,” i.e., the minimum level of
    capacity needed to maintain reliability on the grid, as
    determined by the ISO. Id., at 62,307. For the three-year
    gap between the first auction and the time when the ca­
    pacity procured in that auction would be provided,2 the
    Agreement prescribed a series of fixed, transition-period
    payments to capacity-supplying generators.           Id., at
    62,308–62,309.
    The issue before us centers on §4.C of the Agreement
    (hereinafter Mobile-Sierra provision). Under that provi­
    sion, challenges to both transition-period payments and
    auction-clearing prices would be adjudicated under “the
    ‘public interest’ standard of review set forth in United Gas
    Pipe Line Co. v. Mobile Gas Service Corp., 
    350 U. S. 332
    (1956)[,] and [FPC] v. Sierra Pacific Power Co., 
    350 U. S. 348
     (1956) (the ‘Mobile-Sierra’ doctrine).” App. 95. Mo
    bile-Sierra applies, §4.C instructs, “whether the [price is
    challenged] by a Settling Party, a non-Settling Party, or
    [by] the FERC acting sua sponte.” Ibid.
    FERC approved the Settlement Agreement, “finding
    that as a package, it presents a just and reasonable out­
    come for this proceeding consistent with the public inter­
    est.” 115 FERC, at 62,304. The Mobile-Sierra provision,
    FERC explicitly determined, “appropriately balances the
    need for rate stability and the interests of the diverse
    entities who will be subject to the [forward capacity mar­
    ket’s auction system].” Id., at 62,335.
    Six of the eight objectors to the settlement sought re­
    view in the D. C. Circuit. For the most part, the Court of
    ——————
    2 The   transition period runs from December 1, 2006 to June 1, 2010.
    Cite as: 558 U. S. ____ (2010)             5
    Opinion of the Court
    Appeals rejected the objectors’ efforts to overturn FERC’s
    order approving the settlement. 520 F. 3d, at 467. But
    the objectors prevailed on the Mobile-Sierra issue: The
    D. C. Circuit held that Mobile-Sierra applies only to con­
    tracting parties. Id., at 478. In this Court, the parties
    have switched places. Defenders of the settlement, includ­
    ing the Mobile-Sierra provision, are petitioners; objectors
    to the settlement, victorious in the Court of Appeals only
    on the Mobile-Sierra issue, are respondents.
    Because of the importance of the issue, and in light of
    our recent decision in Morgan Stanley, we granted certio­
    rari, 556 U. S. ___ (2009), to resolve this question: “[Does]
    Mobile-Sierra’s public-interest standard appl[y] when a
    contract rate is challenged by an entity that was not a
    party to the contract[?]” Brief for Petitioners i. Satisfied
    that the answer to that question is yes, we reverse the
    D. C. Circuit’s judgment insofar as it rejected application
    of Mobile-Sierra to noncontracting parties.
    II
    The FPA gives FERC authority to regulate the “sale of
    electric energy at wholesale in interstate commerce.” See
    
    16 U. S. C. §824
    (b)(1). The Act allows regulated utilities
    to set rates unilaterally by tariff; alternatively, sellers and
    buyers may agree on rates by contract. See §824d(c), (d).
    Whether set by tariff or contract, however, all rates must
    be “just and reasonable.” §824d(a). Rates may be exam­
    ined by the Commission, upon complaint or on its own
    initiative, when a new or altered tariff or contract is filed
    or after a rate goes into effect. §§824d(e), 824e(a). Follow­
    ing a hearing, the Commission may set aside any rate
    found “unjust, unreasonable, unduly discriminatory or
    preferential,” and replace it with a just and reasonable
    rate. §824e(a).
    The Mobile-Sierra doctrine originated in twin decisions
    announced on the same day in 1956: United Gas Pipe Line
    6       NRG POWER MARKETING, LLC v. MAINE PUB.
    UTIL. COMM’N
    Opinion of the Court
    Co. v. Mobile Gas Service Corp., 
    350 U. S. 332
    , and FPC v.
    Sierra Pacific Power Co., 
    350 U. S. 348
    . Both concerned
    rates set by contract rather than by tariff. Mobile involved
    the Natural Gas Act, which, like the FPA, requires utili­
    ties to file all new rates with the regulatory commission.
    15 U. S. C. §717c(c). In Mobile, we rejected a gas utility’s
    argument that the file-all-new-rates requirement author­
    ized the utility to abrogate a lawful contract with a pur­
    chaser simply by filing a new tariff. 350 U. S., at 336–337.
    Filing, we explained, was a precondition to changing a
    rate, not an authorization to do so in violation of a lawful
    contract. Id., at 339–344; see Morgan Stanley, 554 U. S.,
    at ___ (slip op., at 4).
    The Sierra case involved a further issue. Not only had
    the Commission erroneously concluded that a newly filed
    tariff superseded a contract rate. In addition, the Com­
    mission had suggested that, in any event, the contract
    rate, which the utility sought to escape, was itself unjust
    and unreasonable. The Commission thought that was so
    “solely because [the contract rate] yield[ed] less than a fair
    return on the [utility’s] net invested capital.” 350 U. S., at
    355.
    The Commission’s suggestion prompted this Court to
    home in on “the question of how the Commission may
    evaluate whether a contract rate is just and reasonable.”
    Morgan Stanley, 554 U. S., at ___ (slip op., at 4). The
    Sierra Court answered the question this way:
    “[T]he Commission’s conclusion appears on its face to
    be based on an erroneous standard. . . . [W]hile it may
    be that the Commission may not normally impose
    upon a public utility a rate which would produce less
    than a fair return, it does not follow that the public
    utility may not itself agree by contract to a rate af­
    fording less than a fair return or that, if it does so, it
    is entitled to be relieved of its improvident bar­
    Cite as: 558 U. S. ____ (2010)                     7
    Opinion of the Court
    gain. . . . In such circumstances the sole concern of the
    Commission would seem to be whether the rate is so
    low as to adversely affect the public interest—as where
    it might impair the financial ability of the public util­
    ity to continue its service, cast upon other consumers
    an excessive burden, or be unduly discriminatory.”
    350 U. S., at 354–355 (some emphasis added).
    In a later case, we similarly explained: “The regulatory
    system created by the [FPA] is premised on contractual
    agreements voluntarily devised by the regulated compa­
    nies; it contemplates abrogation of these agreements only
    in circumstances of unequivocal public necessity.” Per
    mian Basin Area Rate Cases, 
    390 U. S. 747
    , 822 (1968).3
    Two Terms ago, in Morgan Stanley, 554 U. S. ___, the
    Court reaffirmed and clarified the Mobile-Sierra doctrine.
    That case presented two questions: First, does the Mobile-
    Sierra presumption (that contract rates freely negotiated
    between sophisticated parties meet the just and reason­
    able standard imposed by 16 U. S. C. §824d(a)) “apply only
    when FERC has had an initial opportunity to review a
    contract rate without the presumption?” 554 U. S., at ___
    (slip op., at 1). “Second, does the presumption [generally]
    impose as high a bar to challenges by purchasers of whole­
    sale electricity as it does to challenges by sellers?” Id., at
    ——————
    3 Consistent with the lead role of contracts recognized in Mobile-
    Sierra, we held in United Gas Pipe Line Co. v. Memphis Light, Gas and
    Water Div., 
    358 U. S. 103
    , 110–113 (1958), that parties may contract
    out of the Mobile-Sierra presumption. They could do so, we ruled, by
    specifying in their contracts that a new rate filed with the Commission
    would supersede the contract rate. Courts of Appeals have approved an
    option midway between Mobile-Sierra and Memphis Light: A contract
    that does not allow the seller to supersede the contract rate by filing a
    new rate may nonetheless permit the Commission to set aside the
    contract rate if it results in an unfair rate of return, without a further
    showing that it adversely affects the public interest. See, e.g., Papago
    Tribal Util. Auth. v. FERC, 
    723 F. 2d 950
    , 953 (CADC 1983); Louisiana
    Power & Light Co. v. FERC, 
    587 F. 2d 671
    , 675–676 (CA5 1979).
    8       NRG POWER MARKETING, LLC v. MAINE PUB.
    UTIL. COMM’N
    Opinion of the Court
    ___ (slip op., at 1–2); see 
    id.,
     at 19–20. Answering no to
    the first question and yes to the second, the Court empha­
    sized the essential role of contracts as a key factor foster­
    ing stability in the electricity market, to the longrun bene­
    fit of consumers. 
    Id.,
     at ___, ___ (slip op., at 19, 22); see,
    e.g., Market-Based Rates ¶6, 
    72 Fed. Reg. 39906
     (2007)
    (noting chilling effect on investments caused by “uncer­
    tainties regarding rate stability and contract sanctity”);
    Nevada Power Co. v. Duke Energy Trading & Marketing,
    L. L. C., 
    99 FERC ¶61,047
    , pp. 61,184, 61,190 (2002)
    (“Competitive power markets simply cannot attract the
    capital needed to build adequate generating infrastructure
    without regulatory certainty, including certainty that the
    Commission will not modify market-based contracts
    unless there are extraordinary circumstances.”).
    Morgan Stanley did not reach the question presented
    here: Does Mobile-Sierra’s public interest standard apply
    to challenges to contract rates brought by noncontracting
    parties? But Morgan Stanley’s reasoning strongly sug­
    gests that the D. C. Circuit’s negative answer misperceives
    the aim, and diminishes the force, of the Mobile-Sierra
    doctrine.
    In unmistakably plain language, Morgan Stanley re­
    stated Mobile-Sierra’s instruction to the Commission:
    FERC “must presume that the rate set out in a freely
    negotiated wholesale-energy contract meets the ‘just and
    reasonable’ requirement imposed by law. The presump­
    tion may be overcome only if FERC concludes that the
    contract seriously harms the public interest.” 554 U. S., at
    ___ (slip op., at 1). As our instruction to FERC in Morgan
    Stanley conveys, the public interest standard is not, as the
    D. C. Circuit presented it, a standard independent of, and
    sometimes at odds with, the “just and reasonable” stan­
    dard, see 520 F. 3d, at 478; rather, the public interest
    standard defines “what it means for a rate to satisfy the
    just-and-reasonable standard in the contract context.”
    Cite as: 558 U. S. ____ (2010)                   9
    Opinion of the Court
    Morgan Stanley, 554 U. S., at ___ (slip op., at 17). And if
    FERC itself must presume just and reasonable a contract
    rate resulting from fair, arms-length negotiations, how can
    it be maintained that noncontracting parties nevertheless
    may escape that presumption? 4
    Moreover, the Mobile-Sierra doctrine does not overlook
    third-party interests; it is framed with a view to their
    protection. The doctrine directs the Commission to reject
    a contract rate that “seriously harms the consuming pub­
    lic.” Morgan Stanley, 554 U. S., at ___ (slip op., at 17); see
    Verizon Communications Inc. v. FCC, 
    535 U. S. 467
    , 479
    (2002) (When a buyer and a seller agree upon a rate, “the
    principal regulatory responsibility [i]s not to relieve a
    contracting party of an unreasonable rate, . . . but to pro­
    tect against potential discrimination by favorable contract
    rates between allied businesses to the detriment of other
    wholesale customers.” (Emphasis added.)).
    Finally, as earlier indicated, see supra, at 7–8, the D. C.
    Circuit’s confinement of Mobile-Sierra to rate challenges
    by contracting parties diminishes the animating purpose
    of the doctrine: promotion of “the stability of supply ar­
    rangements which all agree is essential to the health of
    the [energy] industry.” Mobile, 
    350 U. S., at 344
    . That
    dominant concern was expressed by FERC in the order on
    review: “Stability is particularly important in this case,
    ——————
    4 The D. C. Circuit emphasized a point no doubt true, but hardly dis­
    positive: Contracts bind parties, not nonparties. Maine Pub. Util.
    Comm’n v. FERC, 
    520 F. 3d 464
    , 478 (2008) (per curiam). Mobile-
    Sierra holds sway, however, because well-informed wholesale-market
    participants of approximately equal bargaining power generally can be
    expected to negotiate just-and-reasonable rates, see Morgan Stanley
    Capital Group Inc. v. Public Util. Dist. No. 1 of Snohomish Cty., 554
    U. S. ___, ___ (2008) (slip op., at 17), and because “contract stability
    ultimately benefits consumers,” 
    id.,
     at ___ (slip op., at 22). These
    reasons for the presumption explain why FERC, surely not legally
    bound by a contract rate, must apply the presumption and, correspond­
    ingly, why third parties are similarly controlled by it.
    10        NRG POWER MARKETING, LLC v. MAINE PUB.
    UTIL. COMM’N
    Opinion of the Court
    which was initiated in part because of the unstable nature
    of [installed capacity] revenues and the effect that has on
    generating units, particularly those . . . critical to main­
    taining reliability.” 115 FERC, at 62,335. A presumption
    applicable to contracting parties only, and inoperative as
    to everyone else—consumers, advocacy groups, state
    utility commissions, elected officials acting parens pa
    triae—could scarcely provide the stability Mobile-Sierra
    aimed to secure.5
    We therefore hold that the Mobile-Sierra presumption
    does not depend on the identity of the complainant who
    seeks FERC investigation. The presumption is not limited
    to challenges to contract rates brought by contracting
    parties. It applies, as well, to challenges initiated by third
    parties.
    III
    The objectors to the settlement appearing before us
    maintain that the rates at issue in this case—the auction
    rates and the transition payments—are prescriptions of
    general applicability rather than “contractually negotiated
    rates,” hence Mobile-Sierra is inapplicable. See Brief for
    Respondents 15–17, and n. 1 (internal quotation marks
    omitted). FERC agrees that the rates covered by the
    settlement “are not themselves contract rates to which the
    Commission was required to apply Mobile-Sierra.” Brief
    for 
    FERC 15
    . But, FERC urges, “the Commission had
    discretion to do so,” id., at 28; furthermore, “[t]he court of
    appeals’ error in creating a third-party exception to the
    Mobile-Sierra presumption is a sufficient basis for revers­
    ing its judgment,” id., at 22. Whether the rates at issue
    ——————
    5 The FPA authorizes “[a]ny person, electric utility, State, municipal­
    ity, or State commission” to complain. 16 U. S. C. §825e (emphasis
    added). FERC regulations similarly permit “[a]ny person [to] file a
    complaint seeking Commission action.” 
    18 CFR §385.206
    (a) (2009)
    (emphasis added).
    Cite as: 558 U. S. ____ (2010)           11
    Opinion of the Court
    qualify as “contract rates,” and, if not, whether FERC had
    discretion to treat them analogously are questions raised
    before, but not ruled upon by, the Court of Appeals. They
    remain open for that court’s consideration on remand. See
    Tr. of Oral Arg. 16.
    *     *     *
    For the reasons stated, the judgment of the Court of Ap­
    peals for the D. C. Circuit is reversed to the extent that it
    rejects the application of Mobile-Sierra to noncontracting
    parties, and the case is remanded for further proceedings
    consistent with this opinion.
    It is so ordered.
    Cite as: 558 U. S. ____ (2010)            1
    STEVENS, J., dissenting
    SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES
    _________________
    No. 08–674
    _________________
    NRG POWER MARKETING, LLC, ET AL., PETITIONERS
    v. MAINE PUBLIC UTILITIES COMMISSION ET AL.
    ON WRIT OF CERTIORARI TO THE UNITED STATES COURT OF
    APPEALS FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA CIRCUIT
    [January 13, 2010]
    JUSTICE STEVENS, dissenting.
    The opinion that the Court announces today is the third
    chapter in a story about how a reasonable principle, ex
    tended beyond its foundation, becomes bad law.
    In the first chapter the Court wisely and correctly held
    that a seller who is a party to a long-term contract to
    provide energy to a wholesaler could not unilaterally
    repudiate its contract obligations in response to changes in
    market conditions by simply filing a new rate schedule
    with the regulatory commission. Only if the rate was so
    low that the seller might be unable to stay in business,
    thereby impairing the public interest, could the seller be
    excused from performing its contract. That is what the
    Court held in United Gas Pipe Line Co. v. Mobile Gas
    Service Corp., 
    350 U. S. 332
     (1956), and FPC v. Sierra
    Pacific Power Co., 
    350 U. S. 348
     (1956).
    In the second chapter the Court unwisely and incor
    rectly held that the same rule should apply to a buyer who
    had been forced by unprecedented market conditions to
    enter into a long-term contract to buy energy at abnor
    mally high prices. The Court held the Federal Energy
    Regulatory Commission (FERC) could not set aside such a
    contract as unjust and unreasonable, even though it sad
    dled consumers with a duty to pay prices that would be
    considered unjust and unreasonable under normal market
    2         NRG POWER MARKETING, LLC v. MAINE PUB.
    UTIL. COMM’N
    STEVENS, J., dissenting
    conditions, unless the purchaser could also prove that “the
    contract seriously harms the public interest.” Morgan
    Stanley Capital Group Inc. v. Public Util. Dist. No. 1 of
    Snohomish Cty., 554 U. S. ___, ___ (2008) (slip op., at 1).
    The Court held in Morgan Stanley that Mobile-Sierra
    established a presumption: FERC “must presume that the
    rate set out in a freely negotiated wholesale-energy con
    tract meets the ‘just and reasonable’ requirement imposed
    by law.” 554 U. S., at ___ (slip op., at 1). And that pre
    sumption, according to the Court, is a simple application
    of the just-and-reasonable standard to contract rates, not
    a different standard of review. 
    Id.,
     at ___ (slip op., at 6)
    (rejecting the “obviously indefensible proposition that a
    standard different from the statutory just-and-reasonable
    standard applies to contract rates”). But applying the
    presumption nonetheless sets a higher bar for a rate chal
    lenge.1 FERC may abrogate the rate only if the public
    interest is seriously harmed. 
    Id.,
     at ___ (slip op., at 22)
    (“[U]nder the Mobile-Sierra presumption, setting aside a
    contract rate requires a finding of ‘unequivocal public
    necessity,’ ” Permian Basin Area Rate Cases, 
    390 U. S. 747
    ,
    822 (1968), “or ‘extraordinary circumstances,’ Arkansas
    Louisiana Gas Co. v. Hall, 
    453 U. S. 571
    , 582 (1981)”).
    As I explained in my dissent in Morgan Stanley, the
    imposition of this additional burden on purchasers chal
    lenging rates was not authorized by the governing statute.
    Under the Federal Power Act (FPA), all wholesale electric
    ity rates must be “just and reasonable.” 16 U. S. C.
    §824d(a). “[N]othing in the statute mandates differing
    application of the statutory standard to rates set by con
    ——————
    1 Whether the Court explains the Mobile-Sierra doctrine as a pre
    sumption or as a different standard of review, “[t]here is no significant
    difference between requiring a heightened showing to overcome an
    otherwise conclusive presumption and imposing a heightened standard
    of review.” Morgan Stanley, 554 U. S., at ___ (slip op., at 3) (STEVENS,
    J., dissenting).
    Cite as: 558 U. S. ____ (2010)                   3
    STEVENS, J., dissenting
    tract.” Morgan Stanley, 554 U. S., at ___ (slip op., at 3)
    (STEVENS, J., dissenting) (internal quotation marks omit
    ted; emphasis deleted). And the Mobile-Sierra line of
    cases did not “mandate a ‘serious harm’ standard of re
    view,” much less “require any assumption that high rates
    and low rates impose symmetric burdens on the public
    interest.” Morgan Stanley, 554 U. S., at ___ (slip op., at 7)
    (STEVENS, J., dissenting). Instead, “the statement in
    Permian Basin about ‘unequivocal public necessity,’ 
    390 U. S., at 822
    , speaks to the difficulty of establishing injury
    to the public interest in the context of a low-rate chal
    lenge,” i.e., one brought by sellers of electricity. 
    Id.,
     at ___
    (slip op., at 8). It does not establish a new standard that
    applies as well to a “high-rate challenge” brought by pur
    chasers. 
    Ibid.
    But even accepting Morgan Stanley as the law, the
    Court unwisely goes further today. In this third chapter of
    the Mobile-Sierra story, the Court applies a rule—one
    designed initially to protect the enforceability of freely
    negotiated contracts against parties who seek a release
    from their obligations—to impose a special burden on
    third parties exercising their statutory right to object to
    unjust and unreasonable rates. This application of the
    rule represents a quantum leap from the modest origin set
    forth in the first chapter of this tale. As the Court of
    Appeals correctly concluded in the opinion that the Court
    sets aside today: “This case is clearly outside the scope of
    the Mobile-Sierra doctrine.” Maine Pub. Util. Comm’n v.
    FERC, 
    520 F. 3d 464
    , 477 (CADC 2008) (per curiam).
    As the D. C. Circuit noted,2 “[c]ourts have rarely men
    ——————
    2 Because the D. C. Circuit’s opinion was written before this Court’s
    decision in Morgan Stanley, that court’s purported error in describing
    the Mobile-Sierra doctrine as an “exception” to the just-and-reasonable
    standard, 520 F. 3d, at 477, is understandable. As that court recog
    nized, and the majority does not change today, the Mobile-Sierra
    standard in fact “makes it harder for [respondents] to successfully
    4         NRG POWER MARKETING, LLC v. MAINE PUB.
    UTIL. COMM’N
    STEVENS, J., dissenting
    tioned the Mobile-Sierra doctrine without reiterating that
    it is premised on the existence of a voluntary contract
    between the parties.” Ibid. But, the Court asks, “[I]f
    FERC itself must presume just and reasonable a contract
    rate resulting from fair, arms-length negotiations, how can
    it be maintained that noncontracting parties nevertheless
    may escape that presumption?” Ante, at 9. This Court’s
    understanding of Sierra provides an answer. “Sierra was
    grounded in the commonsense notion that ‘[i]n wholesale
    markets, the party charging the rate and the party
    charged [are] often sophisticated businesses enjoying
    presumptively equal bargaining power, who could be
    expected to negotiate a “just and reasonable” rate as be
    tween the two of them.’ ” Morgan Stanley, 554 U. S., at ___
    (slip op., at 17) (quoting Verizon Communications Inc. v.
    FCC, 
    535 U. S. 467
    , 479 (2002); emphasis added). This
    “commonsense notion” supports the rule requiring FERC
    to apply a presumption against letting a party out of its
    own contract, as the D. C. Circuit recognized. 520 F. 3d,
    at 478 (“The Mobile-Sierra doctrine applies a more defer
    ential standard of review to preserve the terms of the
    bargain as between the contracting parties”). It does not,
    however, support a rule requiring FERC to apply a pre
    sumption against abrogating any rate set by contract,
    even when, as in this case, a noncontracting party may be
    required in practice to pay a rate it did not agree to.
    The Court further reasons that “confinement of Mobile-
    Sierra to rate challenges by contracting parties diminishes
    the animating purpose of the doctrine,” which is ensuring
    the stability of contract-based supply arrangements. Ante,
    at 9. Maybe so, but applying Mobile-Sierra to rate chal
    lenges by noncontracting parties loses sight of the animat
    ing purpose of the FPA, which is “the protection of the
    public interest.” Sierra, 
    350 U. S., at 355
    . That interest is
    ——————
    challenge rates.” 520 F. 3d, at 478.
    Cite as: 558 U. S. ____ (2010)                     5
    STEVENS, J., dissenting
    “the interest of consumers in paying ‘ “the lowest possible
    reasonable rate consistent with the maintenance of ade
    quate service in the public interest.” ’ ” Morgan Stanley,
    554 U. S., at ___ (slip op., at 7) (STEVENS, J., dissenting)
    (quoting Permian Basin, 
    390 U. S., at 793
    ). I do not doubt
    that stable energy markets are important to the public
    interest, but “under the FPA, Congress has charged
    FERC, not the courts, with balancing the short-term and
    long-term interests of consumers” under the just-and
    reasonable standard of review. Morgan Stanley, 554 U. S.,
    at ___ (slip op., at 9) (STEVENS, J., dissenting). The Court
    today imposes additional limits upon FERC’s ability to
    protect that interest. If a third-party wholesale buyer can
    show a rate harms the public interest (perhaps because it
    is too high to be just and reasonable under normal review),
    but cannot show it seriously harms the public, FERC may
    do nothing about it.3
    The Court assures respondents that the “public interest
    standard” does not “overlook third-party interests” and is
    “framed with a view to their protection.” Ante, at 8, 9.
    Perhaps in practice the Mobile-Sierra doctrine will protect
    third parties’ interests, and the public interest, just as
    well as the so-called “ordinary” just-and-reasonable stan
    dard. But respondents are rightly skeptical. The Mobile-
    Sierra doctrine, as interpreted by the Court in Morgan
    Stanley, must pose a higher bar to respondents’ rate chal
    lenge—that is, it requires them to show greater harm to
    ——————
    3 FERC agrees with petitioners that the public interest standard
    “govern[s] all challenges to the rates set by contract, regardless of the
    identity of the challenger.” Reply Brief for 
    FERC 4
    . But “not even
    FERC has the authority to endorse [this] rule.” Morgan Stanley, 554
    U. S., at ___ (slip op., at 9) (STEVENS, J., dissenting). “The FPA does not
    indulge, much less require, a ‘practically insurmountable’ presumption,
    see Papago Tribal Util. Auth. v. FERC, 
    723 F. 2d 950
    , 954 (CADC 1983)
    (opinion for the court by Scalia, J.), that all rates set by contract com
    port with the public interest and are therefore just and reasonable.”
    
    Id.,
     at ___ (slip op., at 9–10).
    6          NRG POWER MARKETING, LLC v. MAINE PUB.
    UTIL. COMM’N
    STEVENS, J., dissenting
    the public.4 Otherwise, it would hardly serve to protect
    contract stability better than the plain vanilla just-and
    reasonable standard and the Court’s decision in Morgan
    Stanley would have little effect. Furthermore, the Court
    today reiterates that the doctrine poses a high bar. See
    ante, at 7–8.
    It was sensible to require a contracting party to show
    something more than its own desire to get out of what
    proved to be a bad bargain before FERC could abrogate
    the parties’ bargain. It is not sensible, nor authorized by
    the statute, for the Court to change the de facto standard
    of review whenever a rate is set by private contract, based
    solely on the Court’s view that contract stability should be
    ——————
    4 In my view, “whether a rate is ‘just and reasonable’ is measured
    against the public interest, not the private interests of regulated
    [parties].” 
    Id.,
     at ___ (slip op., at 7). But I note the Court’s assertion
    that the Mobile-Sierra doctrine protects “third-party interests,” ante, at
    9, is a new twist on the “public interest standard” as traditionally
    understood. As the Court recognized in Morgan Stanley, one conse
    quence of applying Mobile-Sierra is that “ ‘the sole concern of the
    Commission’ ” is the public interest, and FERC cannot consider, for
    example, whether a rate guarantees a sufficient rate of return to a
    regulated entity. 554 U. S., at ___ (slip op., at 4) (quoting FPC v. Sierra
    Pacific Power Co., 
    350 U. S. 348
    , 355 (1956)); see also Morgan Stanley,
    554 U. S., at ___ (slip op., at 17, n. 3). In addition to requiring that
    FERC find some greater degree of harm to the public than would be
    required under the ordinary just-and-reasonable standard, therefore,
    the Mobile-Sierra doctrine leaves little room for respondents—at least
    one of which did not negotiate the rate but must nonetheless purchase
    electricity at that price in the forward capacity market unless it self
    supplies its capacity—to assert their private interest in making a rate
    challenge. The Court suggests that FERC could set aside a rate under
    the public interest standard if the contract established favorable rates
    between allied businesses to the detriment of other wholesale custom
    ers, ante, at 9, but has not spelled out whether a challenger would still
    have to show that circumstance harmed the public interest. It remains
    unclear whether a noncontracting party that must purchase or sell
    electricity at a rate it did not negotiate could argue that a rate fails the
    “public interest standard” because the rate is detrimental to that
    entity’s private interest.
    Cite as: 558 U. S. ____ (2010)          7
    STEVENS, J., dissenting
    preserved unless there is extraordinary harm to the public
    interest.
    For these reasons, I respectfully dissent.
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 08-674

Citation Numbers: 175 L. Ed. 2d 642, 130 S. Ct. 693, 558 U.S. 165, 2010 U.S. LEXIS 532, 22 Fla. L. Weekly Fed. S 41, 78 U.S.L.W. 4038

Judges: Ginsburg, Roberts, Scalia, Kennedy, Thomas, Breyer, Auto, Sotomayor, Stevens

Filed Date: 1/13/2010

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 10/19/2024

Cited By (31)

Waste Management of Texas, Inc. and Rigoberto Zelaya v. ... ( 2021 )

New Jersey Board of Public Utilities v. Federal Energy ... , 744 F.3d 74 ( 2014 )

New England Power Generators Ass'n v. Federal Energy ... , 757 F.3d 283 ( 2014 )

Transcanada Power Marketing Ltd. v. Federal Energy ... , 811 F.3d 1 ( 2015 )

Oklahoma Gas & Electric Co. v. Federal Energy Regulatory ... , 827 F.3d 75 ( 2016 )

Emera Maine v. Federal Energy Regulatory Commission , 854 F.3d 662 ( 2017 )

Pseg Energy Resources & Trade v. Ferc ( 2011 )

Delaware Department of Natural Resources & Environmental ... , 785 F.3d 1 ( 2015 )

DE Department of Natural Res. v. EPA ( 2015 )

New England Power Gen. Assoc. v. FERC ( 2014 )

The People of the State of Ca v. Ferc ( 2015 )

Allco Fin. Ltd. v. Robert J. Klee , 861 F.3d 82 ( 2017 )

Firstenergy Service Co. v. Federal Energy Regulatory ... , 758 F.3d 346 ( 2014 )

Esi Energy, LLC v. Fed. Energy Regulatory Comm'n , 892 F.3d 321 ( 2018 )

Nextera Energy Res., LLC v. Fed. Energy Regulatory Comm'n , 898 F.3d 14 ( 2018 )

Simon v. KEYSPAN CORP. , 785 F. Supp. 2d 120 ( 2011 )

In re: FirstEnergy Solutions Corp. ( 2019 )

Monticello v. Public Service Commn , 2019 UT 43 ( 2019 )

Transm. Agency of Northern CA v. FERC ( 2010 )

Braintree Electric Light Department v. Federal Energy ... , 667 F.3d 1284 ( 2012 )

View All Citing Opinions »