E.P.A. v. EME Homer City Generation, L.P. , 134 S. Ct. 1584 ( 2014 )


Menu:
  • (Slip Opinion)              OCTOBER TERM, 2013                                       1
    Syllabus
    NOTE: Where it is feasible, a syllabus (headnote) will be released, as is
    being done in connection with this case, at the time the opinion is issued.
    The syllabus constitutes no part of the opinion of the Court but has been
    prepared by the Reporter of Decisions for the convenience of the reader.
    See United States v. Detroit Timber & Lumber Co., 
    200 U.S. 321
    , 337.
    SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES
    Syllabus
    ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION AGENCY ET AL. v.
    EME HOMER CITY GENERATION, L. P., ET AL.
    CERTIORARI TO THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR
    THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA CIRCUIT
    No. 12–1182. Argued December 10, 2013—Decided April 29, 2014*
    Congress and the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA or Agency)
    have, over the course of several decades, made many efforts to deal
    with the complex challenge of curtailing air pollution emitted in up-
    wind States, but causing harm in other, downwind States. As rele-
    vant here, the Clean Air Act (CAA or Act) directs EPA to establish
    national ambient air quality standards (NAAQS) for pollutants at
    levels that will protect public health. 
    42 U.S. C
    . §§7408, 7409. Once
    EPA settles on a NAAQS, the Agency must designate “nonattain-
    ment” areas, i.e., locations where the concentration of a regulated pol-
    lutant exceeds the NAAQS. §7407(d). Each State must submit a
    State Implementation Plan, or SIP, to EPA within three years of any
    new or revised NAAQS. §7410(a)(1). From the date EPA determines
    that a State SIP is inadequate, the Agency has two years to promul-
    gate a Federal Implementation Plan, or FIP. §7410(c)(1). Among
    other components, the CAA mandates SIP compliance with the Good
    Neighbor Provision, which requires SIPs to “contain adequate provi-
    sions . . . prohibiting . . . any source or other type of emissions activity
    within the State from emitting any air pollutant in amounts which
    will . . . contribute significantly to nonattainment in, or interfere with
    maintenance by, any other State with respect to any . . . [NAAQS].”
    §7410(a)(2)(D)(i).
    Several times over the past two decades, EPA has attempted to
    delineate the Good Neighbor Provision’s scope by identifying when
    ——————
    * Together with No. 12–1183, American Lung Association et al. v.
    EME Homer City Generation, L. P., et al., also on certiorari to the same
    court.
    2            EPA v. EME HOMER CITY GENERATION, L. P.
    Syllabus
    upwind States “contribute significantly” to nonattainment downwind.
    The D. C. Circuit found fault with the Agency’s 2005 attempt, the
    Clean Air Interstate Rule, or CAIR, which regulated both nitrogen
    oxide (NOX) and sulfur dioxide (SO2) emissions, the gasses at issue
    here. The D. C. Circuit nevertheless left CAIR temporarily in place,
    while encouraging EPA to act with dispatch in dealing with problems
    the court had identified.
    EPA’s response to that decision is the Cross-State Air Pollution
    Rule (Transport Rule), which curbs NOX and SO2 emissions in 27 up-
    wind States to achieve downwind attainment of three NAAQS. Un-
    der the Transport Rule, an upwind State “contribute[d] significantly”
    to downwind nonattainment to the extent its exported pollution both
    (1) produced one percent or more of a NAAQS in at least one down-
    wind State and (2) could be eliminated cost-effectively, as determined
    by EPA. Upwind States are obliged to eliminate only emissions
    meeting both of these criteria. Through complex modeling, EPA cre-
    ated an annual emissions “budget” for each regulated State upwind,
    representing the total quantity of pollution an upwind State could
    produce in a given year under the Transport Rule. Having earlier de-
    termined each regulated State’s SIP to be inadequate, EPA, contem-
    poraneous with the Transport Rule, promulgated FIPs allocating
    each State’s emissions budgets among its in-state pollution sources.
    A group of state and local governments (State respondents), joined
    by industry and labor groups (Industry respondents), petitioned for
    review of the Transport Rule in the D. C. Circuit. The court vacated
    the rule in its entirety, holding that EPA’s actions exceeded the
    Agency’s statutory authority in two respects. Acknowledging that
    EPA’s FIP authority is generally triggered when the Agency disap-
    proves a SIP, the court was nevertheless concerned that States would
    be incapable of fulfilling the Good Neighbor Provision without prior
    EPA guidance. The court thus concluded that EPA must give States
    a reasonable opportunity to allocate their emission budgets before is-
    suing FIPs. The court also found the Agency’s two-part interpreta-
    tion of the Good Neighbor Provision unreasonable, concluding that
    EPA must disregard costs and consider exclusively each upwind
    State’s physically proportionate responsibility for air quality prob-
    lems downwind.
    Held:
    1. The CAA does not command that States be given a second oppor-
    tunity to file a SIP after EPA has quantified the State’s interstate
    pollution obligations. Pp. 13–18.
    (a) The State respondents do not challenge EPA’s disapproval of
    any particular SIP. Instead, they argue that, notwithstanding these
    disapprovals, the Agency was still obliged to grant upwind States an
    Cite as: 572 U. S. ____ (2014)                     3
    Syllabus
    additional opportunity to promulgate adequate SIPs after EPA had
    set the State’s emission budget. This claim does not turn on the va-
    lidity of the prior SIP disapprovals, but on whether the CAA requires
    EPA do more than disapprove a SIP to trigger the Agency’s authority
    to issue a FIP. Pp. 13–14.
    (b) The CAA’s plain text supports the Agency: Disapproval of a
    SIP, without more, triggers EPA’s obligation to issue a FIP. The
    statute sets precise deadlines for the States and EPA. Once EPA is-
    sues any new or revised NAAQS, a State “shall” propose a SIP within
    three years, 
    42 U.S. C
    . §7410(a)(1), and that SIP “shall” include, in-
    ter alia, provisions adequate to satisfy the Good Neighbor Provision,
    §7410(a)(2). If the EPA finds a SIP inadequate, the Agency has a
    statutory duty to issue a FIP “at any time” within two years.
    §7410(c)(1). However sensible the D. C. Circuit’s exception to this
    strict time prescription may be, a reviewing court’s “task is to apply
    the text [of the statute], not to improve upon it.” Pavelic & LeFlore v.
    Marvel Entertainment Group, Div. of Cadence Industries Corp., 
    493 U.S. 120
    , 126. Nothing in the Act differentiates the Good Neighbor
    Provision from the several other matters a State must address in its
    SIP. Nor does the Act condition the duty to promulgate a FIP on
    EPA’s having first quantified an upwind State’s good neighbor obliga-
    tions. By altering Congress’ SIP and FIP schedule, the D. C. Circuit
    allowed a delay Congress did not order and placed an information
    submission obligation on EPA Congress did not impose. Pp. 14–17.
    (c) The fact that EPA had previously accorded upwind States a
    chance to allocate emission budgets among their in-state sources does
    not show that the Agency acted arbitrarily by refraining to do so
    here. EPA retained discretion to alter its course provided it gave a
    reasonable explanation for doing so. Motor Vehicle Mfrs. Assn. of
    United States, Inc. v. State Farm Mut. Automobile Ins. Co., 
    463 U.S. 29
    , 42. Here, the Agency had been admonished by the D. C. Circuit
    to act with dispatch in amending or replacing CAIR. Endeavoring to
    satisfy that directive, EPA acted speedily, issuing FIPs and the
    Transport Rule contemporaneously. Pp. 17–18.
    2. EPA’s cost-effective allocation of emission reductions among up-
    wind States is a permissible, workable, and equitable interpretation
    of the Good Neighbor Provision. Pp. 18–31.
    (a) Respondents’ attack on EPA’s interpretation of the Good
    Neighbor Provision is not foreclosed by §7607(d)(7)(B), which pro-
    vides that “[o]nly an objection to a rule . . . raised with reasonable
    specificity during the period for public comment . . . may be raised
    during judicial review.” Even assuming that respondents failed to
    object to the Transport Rule with “reasonable specificity,” that lapse
    is not jurisdictional. Section 7607(d)(7)(B) is a “mandatory,” but not
    4            EPA v. EME HOMER CITY GENERATION, L. P.
    Syllabus
    “jurisdictional,” rule, see Arbaugh v. Y & H Corp., 
    546 U.S. 500
    , 510,
    which speaks to a party’s procedural obligations, not a court’s author-
    ity, see Kontrick v. Ryan, 
    540 U.S. 443
    , 455. Because EPA did not
    press this argument unequivocally before the D. C. Circuit, it does
    not pose an impassable hindrance to this Court’s review. Pp. 18–19.
    (b) This Court routinely accords dispositive effect to an agency’s
    reasonable interpretation of ambiguous statutory language. The
    Good Neighbor Provision delegates authority to EPA at least as cer-
    tainly as the CAA provisions involved in Chevron U. S. A. Inc. v.
    Natural Resources Defense Council, Inc., 
    467 U.S. 837
    . EPA’s au-
    thority to reduce upwind pollution extends only to those “amounts” of
    pollution that “contribute significantly to nonattainment” in down-
    wind States. §7410(a)(2)(D)(i). Because a downwind State’s excess
    pollution is often caused by multiple upwind States, however, EPA
    must address how to allocate responsibility among multiple contribu-
    tors. The Good Neighbor Provision does not dictate a method of ap-
    portionment. Nothing in the provision, for example, directs the pro-
    portional allocation method advanced by the D. C. Circuit, a method
    that works neither mathematically nor in practical application. Un-
    der Chevron, Congress’ silence effectively delegates authority to EPA
    to select from among reasonable options. See United States v. Mead
    Corp., 
    533 U.S. 218
    , 229.
    EPA’s chosen allocation method is a “permissible construction of
    the statute.” 
    Chevron, 467 U.S., at 843
    . The Agency, tasked with
    choosing which among equal “amounts” to eliminate, has chosen sen-
    sibly to reduce the amount easier, i.e., less costly, to eradicate. The
    Industry respondents argue that the final calculation cannot rely on
    costs, but nothing in the Good Neighbor Provision’s text precludes
    that choice. And using costs in the Transport Rule calculus is an effi-
    cient and equitable solution to the allocation problem the Good
    Neighbor Provision compels the Agency to address. Efficient because
    EPA can achieve the same levels of attainment, i.e., of emission re-
    ductions, the proportional approach aims to achieve, but at a much
    lower overall cost. Equitable because, by imposing uniform cost
    thresholds on regulated States, EPA’s rule subjects to stricter regula-
    tion those States that have done less in the past to control their pol-
    lution. Pp. 20–28.
    (c) Wholesale invalidation of the Transport Rule is not justified
    by either of the D. C. Circuit’s remaining objections: that the
    Transport Rule leaves open the possibility that a State might be
    compelled to reduce emissions beyond the point at which every af-
    fected downwind State is in attainment, so-called “over-control”; and
    that EPA’s use of costs does not foreclose the possibility that an up-
    wind State would be required to reduce its emissions by so much that
    Cite as: 572 U. S. ____ (2014)                     5
    Syllabus
    the State would be placed below the one-percent mark EPA set as the
    initial threshold of “significan[ce].” First, instances of “over-control”
    in particular downwind locations may be incidental to reductions
    necessary to ensure attainment elsewhere. As the Good Neighbor
    Provision seeks attainment in every downwind State, however, ex-
    ceeding attainment in one State cannot rank as “over-control” unless
    unnecessary to achieving attainment in any downwind State. Sec-
    ond, the EPA must have leeway in fulfilling its statutory mandate to
    balance the possibilities of over-control and “under-control,” i.e., to
    maximize achievement of attainment downwind. Finally, in a volu-
    minous record, involving thousands of upwind-to-downwind linkages,
    respondents point to only a few instances of “unnecessary” emission
    reductions, and even those are contested by EPA. Pp. 28–31.
    
    696 F.3d 7
    , reversed and remanded.
    GINSBURG, J., delivered the opinion of the Court, in which ROBERTS,
    C. J., and KENNEDY, BREYER, SOTOMAYOR, and KAGAN, JJ., joined. SCAL-
    IA, J., filed a dissenting opinion, in which THOMAS, J., joined. ALITO, J.,
    took no part in the consideration or decision of the cases.
    Cite as: 572 U. S. ____ (2014)                              1
    Opinion of the Court
    NOTICE: This opinion is subject to formal revision before publication in the
    preliminary print of the United States Reports. Readers are requested to
    notify the Reporter of Decisions, Supreme Court of the United States, Wash­
    ington, D. C. 20543, of any typographical or other formal errors, in order
    that corrections may be made before the preliminary print goes to press.
    SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES
    _________________
    Nos. 12–1182 and 12–1183
    _________________
    ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION AGENCY ET AL.,
    PETITIONERS
    12–1182             v.
    EME HOMER CITY GENERATION, L. P., ET AL.; AND
    AMERICAN LUNG ASSOCIATION ET AL.,
    PETITIONERS
    12–1183              v.
    EME HOMER CITY GENERATION, L. P., ET AL.
    ON WRITS OF CERTIORARI TO THE UNITED STATES COURT OF
    APPEALS FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA CIRCUIT
    [April 29, 2014]
    JUSTICE GINSBURG delivered the opinion of the Court.
    These cases concern the efforts of Congress and the
    Environmental Protection Agency (EPA or Agency) to cope
    with a complex problem: air pollution emitted in one
    State, but causing harm in other States. Left unregulated,
    the emitting or upwind State reaps the benefits of the
    economic activity causing the pollution without bearing all
    the costs. See Revesz, Federalism and Interstate Envi­
    ronmental Externalities, 144 U. Pa. L. Rev. 2341, 2343
    (1996). Conversely, downwind States to which the pollu­
    tion travels are unable to achieve clean air because of the
    influx of out-of-state pollution they lack authority to con­
    trol. See S. Rep. No. 101–228, p. 49 (1989). To tackle the
    2        EPA v. EME HOMER CITY GENERATION, L. P.
    Opinion of the Court
    problem, Congress included a Good Neighbor Provision in
    the Clean Air Act (Act or CAA). That provision, in its
    current phrasing, instructs States to prohibit in-state
    sources “from emitting any air pollutant in amounts which
    will . . . contribute significantly” to downwind States’
    “nonattainment . . . , or interfere with maintenance,” of
    any EPA-promulgated national air quality standard. 
    42 U.S. C
    . §7410(a)(2)(D)(i).
    Interpreting the Good Neighbor Provision, EPA adopted
    the Cross-State Air Pollution Rule (commonly and herein­
    after called the Transport Rule). The rule calls for consid­
    eration of costs, among other factors, when determining
    the emission reductions an upwind State must make to
    improve air quality in polluted downwind areas. The
    Court of Appeals for the D. C. Circuit vacated the rule in
    its entirety. It held, 2 to 1, that the Good Neighbor Provi­
    sion requires EPA to consider only each upwind State’s
    physically proportionate responsibility for each downwind
    State’s air quality problem. That reading is demanded,
    according to the D. C. Circuit, so that no State will be
    required to decrease its emissions by more than its ratable
    share of downwind-state pollution.
    In Chevron U. S. A. Inc. v. Natural Resources Defense
    Council, Inc., 
    467 U.S. 837
    (1984), we reversed a D. C.
    Circuit decision that failed to accord deference to EPA’s
    reasonable interpretation of an ambiguous Clean Air Act
    provision. Satisfied that the Good Neighbor Provision
    does not command the Court of Appeals’ cost-blind con­
    struction, and that EPA reasonably interpreted the provi­
    sion, we reverse the D. C. Circuit’s judgment.
    I
    A
    Air pollution is transient, heedless of state boundaries.
    Pollutants generated by upwind sources are often trans­
    ported by air currents, sometimes over hundreds of miles,
    Cite as: 572 U. S. ____ (2014)                 3
    Opinion of the Court
    to downwind States. As the pollution travels out of state,
    upwind States are relieved of the associated costs. Those
    costs are borne instead by the downwind States, whose
    ability to achieve and maintain satisfactory air quality is
    hampered by the steady stream of infiltrating pollution.
    For several reasons, curtailing interstate air pollution
    poses a complex challenge for environmental regulators.
    First, identifying the upwind origin of downwind air pollu­
    tion is no easy endeavor. Most upwind States propel
    pollutants to more than one downwind State, many
    downwind States receive pollution from multiple upwind
    States, and some States qualify as both upwind and
    downwind. See Brief for Federal Petitioners 6. The over­
    lapping and interwoven linkages between upwind and
    downwind States with which EPA had to contend number
    in the thousands.1
    Further complicating the problem, pollutants do not
    emerge from the smokestacks of an upwind State and
    uniformly migrate downwind. Some pollutants stay with­
    in upwind States’ borders, the wind carries others to
    downwind States, and some subset of that group drifts to
    States without air quality problems. “The wind bloweth
    where it listeth, and thou hearest the sound thereof, but
    canst not tell whence it cometh, and whither it goeth.”
    The Holy Bible, John 3:8 (King James Version). In craft­
    ing a solution to the problem of interstate air pollution,
    regulators must account for the vagaries of the wind.
    Finally, upwind pollutants that find their way down­
    wind are not left unaltered by the journey. Rather, as the
    gases emitted by upwind polluters are carried downwind,
    they are transformed, through various chemical processes,
    into altogether different pollutants. The offending gases
    ——————
    1 For the rule challenged here, EPA evaluated 2,479 separate link­
    ages between downwind and upwind States. Brief for Federal Petition­
    ers 6.
    4        EPA v. EME HOMER CITY GENERATION, L. P.
    Opinion of the Court
    at issue in these cases—nitrogen oxide (NOX) and sulfur
    dioxide (SO2)—often develop into ozone and fine particu­
    late matter (PM2.5) by the time they reach the atmos­
    pheres of downwind States. See 76 Fed. Reg. 48222–
    48223 (2011). See also 69 Fed. Reg. 4575–4576 (2004)
    (describing the components of ozone and PM2.5). Down­
    wind air quality must therefore be measured for ozone and
    PM2.5 concentrations. EPA’s chore is to quantify the
    amount of upwind gases (NOX and SO2) that must be
    reduced to enable downwind States to keep their levels of
    ozone and PM2.5 in check.
    B
    Over the past 50 years, Congress has addressed inter­
    state air pollution several times and with increasing rigor.
    In 1963, Congress directed federal authorities to “encour­
    age cooperative activities by the States and local govern­
    ments for the prevention and control of air pollution.” 77
    Stat. 393, 
    42 U.S. C
    . §1857a (1964 ed.). In 1970, Congress
    made this instruction more concrete, introducing features
    still key to the Act. For the first time, Congress directed
    EPA to establish national ambient air quality standards
    (NAAQS) for pollutants at levels that will protect public
    health. See 84 Stat. 1679–1680, as amended, 
    42 U.S. C
    .
    §§7408, 7409 (2006 ed.). Once EPA settles on a NAAQS,
    the Act requires the Agency to designate “nonattainment”
    areas, i.e., locations where the concentration of a regulated
    pollutant exceeds the NAAQS. §7407(d).
    The Act then shifts the burden to States to propose
    plans adequate for compliance with the NAAQS. Each
    State must submit a State Implementation Plan, or SIP,
    to EPA within three years of any new or revised NAAQS.
    §7410(a)(1). If EPA determines that a State has failed to
    submit an adequate SIP, either in whole or in part, the Act
    requires the Agency to promulgate a Federal Implementa­
    tion Plan, or FIP, within two years of EPA’s determina­
    Cite as: 572 U. S. ____ (2014)                 5
    Opinion of the Court
    tion, “unless the State corrects the deficiency” before a FIP
    is issued. §7410(c)(1).2
    The Act lists the matters a SIP must cover. Among SIP
    components, the 1970 version of the Act required SIPs to
    include “adequate provisions for intergovernmental coop­
    eration” concerning interstate air pollution. §110(a)(2)(E),
    84 Stat. 1681, 
    42 U.S. C
    . §1857c–5(a)(2)(E). This statutory
    requirement, with its text altered over time, has come
    to be called the Good Neighbor Provision.
    In 1977, Congress amended the Good Neighbor Provi­
    sion to require more than “cooperation.” It directed States
    to submit SIPs that included provisions “adequate” to
    “prohibi[t] any stationary source within the State from
    emitting any air pollutant in amounts which will . . .
    prevent attainment or maintenance [of air quality stand­
    ards] by any other State.” §108(a)(4), 91 Stat. 693, 
    42 U.S. C
    . §7410(a)(2)(E) (1976 ed., Supp. II). The amended
    provision thus explicitly instructed upwind States to
    reduce emissions to account for pollution exported beyond
    their borders. As then written, however, the provision
    regulated only individual sources that, considered alone,
    emitted enough pollution to cause nonattainment in a
    downwind State. Because it is often “impossible to say
    that any single source or group of sources is the one which
    actually prevents attainment” downwind, S. Rep. No. 101–
    228, p. 21 (1989), the 1977 version of the Good Neighbor
    Provision proved ineffective, see 
    ibid. (noting the provi­
    sion’s inability to curb the collective “emissions [of] multi­
    ple sources”).
    Congress most recently amended the Good Neighbor
    Provision in 1990. The statute, in its current form, re­
    quires SIPs to “contain adequate provisions . . . prohibiting
    ——————
    2 FIPs and SIPs were introduced in the 1970 version of the Act; the
    particular deadlines discussed here were added in 1990. See 104 Stat.
    2409, 2422–2423, 
    42 U.S. C
    . §§7401(a)(1), 7410(c) (2006 ed.).
    6        EPA v. EME HOMER CITY GENERATION, L. P.
    Opinion of the Court
    . . . any source or other type of emissions activity within
    the State from emitting any air pollutant in amounts
    which will . . . contribute significantly to nonattainment
    in, or interfere with maintenance by, any other State with
    respect to any . . . [NAAQS].” 
    42 U.S. C
    . §7410(a)(2)(D)(i)
    (2006 ed.). The controversy before us centers on EPA’s
    most recent attempt to construe this provision.
    C
    Three times over the past two decades, EPA has at­
    tempted to delineate the Good Neighbor Provision’s scope
    by identifying when upwind States “contribute significantly”
    to nonattainment downwind. In 1998, EPA issued a
    rule known as the “NOX SIP Call.” That regulation lim­
    ited NOX emissions in 23 upwind States to the extent such
    emissions contributed to nonattainment of ozone stand­
    ards in downwind States. See 63 Fed. Reg. 57356, 57358.
    In Michigan v. EPA, 
    213 F.3d 663
    (2000), the D. C. Cir­
    cuit upheld the NOX SIP Call, specifically affirming EPA’s
    use of costs to determine when an upwind State’s contri­
    bution was “significan[t]” within the meaning of the stat­
    ute. 
    Id., at 674–679.
       In 2005, EPA issued the Clean Air Interstate Rule, or
    CAIR. 70 Fed. Reg. 25162. CAIR regulated both NOX and
    SO2 emissions, insofar as such emissions contributed to
    downwind nonattainment of two NAAQS, both set in 1997,
    one concerning the permissible annual measure of PM2.5,
    and another capping the average ozone level gauged over
    an 8-hour period. See 
    id., at 25171.
    The D. C. Circuit
    initially vacated CAIR as arbitrary and capricious. See
    North Carolina v. EPA, 
    531 F.3d 896
    , 921 (2008) (per
    curiam). On rehearing, the court decided to leave the rule
    in place, while encouraging EPA to act with dispatch in
    dealing with problems the court had identified. See North
    Carolina v. EPA, 
    550 F.3d 1176
    , 1178 (2008) (per curiam).
    The rule challenged here—the Transport Rule—is EPA’s
    Cite as: 572 U. S. ____ (2014)                   7
    Opinion of the Court
    response to the D. C. Circuit’s North Carolina decision.
    Finalized in August 2011, the Transport Rule curtails NOX
    and SO2 emissions of 27 upwind States to achieve down­
    wind attainment of three different NAAQS: the two 1997
    NAAQS previously addressed by CAIR, and the 2006
    NAAQS for PM2.5 levels measured on a daily basis. See 76
    Fed. Reg. 48208–48209.
    Under the Transport Rule, EPA employed a “two-step
    approach” to determine when upwind States “contribute[d]
    significantly to nonattainment,” 
    id., at 48254,
    and there­
    fore in “amounts” that had to be eliminated. At step one,
    called the “screening” analysis, the Agency excluded as de
    minimis any upwind State that contributed less than one
    percent of the three NAAQS3 to any downwind State
    “receptor,” a location at which EPA measures air quality.
    See 
    id., at 48236–48237.4
    If all of an upwind State’s con­
    tributions fell below the one-percent threshold, that State
    would be considered not to have “contribute[d] signifi-
    cantly” to the nonattainment of any downwind State. 
    Id., at 48236.
    States in that category were screened out and
    exempted from regulation under the rule.
    The remaining States were subjected to a second in­
    quiry, which EPA called the “control” analysis. At this
    stage, the Agency sought to generate a cost-effective allo­
    cation of emission reductions among those upwind States
    “screened in” at step one.
    The control analysis proceeded this way. EPA first
    calculated, for each upwind State, the quantity of emis­
    sions the State could eliminate at each of several cost
    ——————
    3 With respect to each NAAQS addressed by the rule, the one-percent
    threshold corresponded to levels of 0.15 micrograms per cubic meter
    (µg/m3) for annual PM2.5, 0.35 µg/m3 for daily PM2.5, and 0.8 parts per
    billion (ppb) for 8-hour ozone. See 76 Fed. Reg. 48236–48237.
    4 If, for example, the NAAQS for ozone were 100 ppb, a contribution of
    less than 1 ppb to any downwind location would fall outside EPA’s
    criteria for significance.
    8          EPA v. EME HOMER CITY GENERATION, L. P.
    Opinion of the Court
    thresholds. See 
    id., at 48248–48249.
    Cost for these pur­
    poses is measured as cost per ton of emissions prevented,
    for instance, by installing scrubbers on powerplant smoke­
    stacks.5 EPA estimated, for example, the amount each
    upwind State’s NOX emissions would fall if all pollution
    sources within each State employed every control measure
    available at a cost of $500 per ton or less. See 
    id., at 48249–48251.
    The Agency then repeated that analysis at
    ascending cost thresholds. See ibid.6
    Armed with this information, EPA conducted complex
    modeling to establish the combined effect the upwind
    reductions projected at each cost threshold would have on
    air quality in downwind States. See 
    id., at 48249.
    The
    Agency then identified “significant cost threshold[s],”
    points in its model where a “noticeable change occurred in
    downwind air quality, such as . . . where large upwind
    emission reductions become available because a certain
    type of emissions control strategy becomes cost-effective.”
    
    Ibid. For example, reductions
    of NOX sufficient to resolve
    or significantly curb downwind air quality problems could
    be achieved, EPA determined, at a cost threshold of $500
    per ton (applied uniformly to all regulated upwind States).
    “Moving beyond the $500 cost threshold,” EPA concluded,
    “would result in only minimal additional . . . reductions [in
    emissions].” 
    Id., at 48256.7
      Finally, EPA translated the cost thresholds it had se­
    ——————
    5 Toillustrate, a technology priced at $5,000 and capable of eliminat­
    ing two tons of pollution would be stated to “cost” $2,500 per ton.
    6 For SO2, EPA modeled reductions that would be achieved at cost
    levels of $500, $1,600, $2,300, $2,800, $3,300, and $10,000 per ton
    eliminated. See 
    id., at 48251–48253.
       7 For SO2, EPA determined that, for one group of upwind States, all
    downwind air quality problems would be resolved at the $500 per ton
    threshold. See 
    id., at 48257.
    For another group of States, however,
    this level of controls would not suffice. For those States, EPA found
    that pollution controls costing $2,300 per ton were necessary. See 
    id., at 48259.
                         Cite as: 572 U. S. ____ (2014)                   9
    Opinion of the Court
    lected into amounts of emissions upwind States would be
    required to eliminate. For each regulated upwind State,
    EPA created an annual emissions “budget.” These budg­
    ets represented the quantity of pollution an upwind State
    would produce in a given year if its in-state sources im­
    plemented all pollution controls available at the chosen
    cost thresholds. See 
    id., at 48249.
    8 If EPA’s projected
    improvements to downwind air quality were to be realized,
    an upwind State’s emissions could not exceed the level this
    budget allocated to it, subject to certain adjustments not
    relevant here.
    Taken together, the screening and control inquiries
    defined EPA’s understanding of which upwind emissions
    were within the Good Neighbor Provision’s ambit. In
    short, under the Transport Rule, an upwind State “con­
    tribute[d] significantly” to downwind nonattainment to the
    extent its exported pollution both (1) produced one percent
    or more of a NAAQS in at least one downwind State (step
    one) and (2) could be eliminated cost-effectively, as deter­
    mined by EPA (step two). See 
    id., at 48254.
    Upwind
    States would be obliged to eliminate all and only emis­
    sions meeting both of these criteria.9
    For each State regulated by the Transport Rule, EPA
    contemporaneously promulgated a FIP allocating that
    State’s emission budget among its in-state sources. See
    
    id., at 48271,
    48284–48287.10 For each of these States,
    ——————
    8 In  2014, for example, pollution sources within Texas would be per­
    mitted to emit no more than 243,954 tons of SO2, subject to variations
    specified by EPA. See 
    id., at 48269
    (Table VI.F–1).
    9 Similarly, upwind States EPA independently determined to be “in­
    terfer[ing] with [the] maintenance” of NAAQS downwind were required
    to eliminate pollution only to the extent their emissions satisfied both
    of these criteria. See 
    id., at 48254.
       10 These FIPs specified the maximum amount of pollution each in­
    state pollution source could emit. Sources below this ceiling could sell
    unused “allocations” to sources that could not reduce emissions to the
    necessary level as cheaply. See 
    id., at 48271–48272.
    This type of “cap­
    10         EPA v. EME HOMER CITY GENERATION, L. P.
    Opinion of the Court
    EPA had determined that the State had failed to submit
    a SIP adequate for compliance with the Good Neighbor
    Provision. These determinations regarding SIPs became
    final after 60 days, see 
    42 U.S. C
    . §7607(b)(1)(2006 ed.,
    Supp. V ), and many went unchallenged.11 EPA views the
    SIP determinations as having triggered its statutory
    obligation to promulgate a FIP within two years, see
    §7410(c), a view contested by respondents, see Part II,
    infra.
    D
    A group of state and local governments (State respond­
    ents), joined by industry and labor groups (Industry re­
    spondents), petitioned for review of the Transport Rule in
    the U. S. Court of Appeals for the D. C. Circuit. Over the
    dissent of Judge Rogers, the Court of Appeals vacated the
    rule in its entirety. See 
    696 F.3d 7
    , 37 (2012).
    EPA’s actions, the appeals court held, exceeded the
    Agency’s statutory authority in two respects. By promul­
    gating FIPs before giving States a meaningful opportunity
    to adopt their own implementation plans, EPA had, in the
    court’s view, upset the CAA’s division of responsibility
    between the States and the Federal Government. In the
    main, the Court of Appeals acknowledged, EPA’s FIP
    authority is triggered at the moment the Agency disap­
    proves a SIP. See 
    id., at 30.
    Thus, when a State proposes
    ——————
    and-trade” system cuts costs while still reducing pollution to target
    levels.
    11 Three States did challenge EPA’s determinations. See Petition for
    Review in Ohio v. EPA, No. 11–3988 (CA6); Petition for Review in
    Kansas v. EPA, No. 12–1019 (CADC); Notice in Georgia v. EPA, No. 11–
    1427 (CADC). Those challenges were not consolidated with this pro­
    ceeding, and they remain pending (held in abeyance for these cases) in
    the Sixth and D. C. Circuits. See Twelfth Joint Status Report in Ohio
    v. EPA, No. 11–3988 (CA6); Order in Kansas v. EPA, No. 11–1333
    (CADC, May 10, 2013); Order in Georgia v. EPA, No. 11–1427 (CADC,
    May 10, 2013).
    Cite as: 572 U. S. ____ (2014)            11
    Opinion of the Court
    a SIP inadequate to achieve a NAAQS, EPA could promul­
    gate a FIP immediately after disapproving that SIP. See
    
    id., at 32.
       But the Court of Appeals ruled that a different regime
    applies to a State’s failure to meet its obligations under
    the Good Neighbor Provision. While a NAAQS was a
    “clear numerical target,” a State’s good neighbor obligation
    remained “nebulous and unknown,” the court observed,
    until EPA calculated the State’s emission budget. 
    Ibid. Without these budgets,
    the Court of Appeals said, upwind
    States would be compelled to take a “stab in the dark” at
    calculating their own significant contribution to interstate
    air pollution. 
    Id., at 35.
    The D. C. Circuit read the Act to
    avoid putting States in this position: EPA had an implicit
    statutory duty, the court held, to give upwind States a
    reasonable opportunity to allocate their emission budgets
    among in-state sources before the Agency’s authority to
    issue FIPs could be triggered. 
    Id., at 37.
       The D. C. Circuit also held that the Agency’s two-part
    interpretation of the Good Neighbor Provision ignored
    three “red lines . . . cabin[ing the] EPA’s authority.” 
    Id., at 19.
    First, the D. C. Circuit interpreted the Good Neighbor
    Provision to require upwind States to reduce emissions in
    “a manner proportional to their contributio[n]” to pollution
    in downwind States. 
    Id., at 21.
    The Transport Rule,
    however, treated all regulated upwind States alike, re­
    gardless of their relative contribution to the overall prob­
    lem. See 
    id., at 23.
    It required all upwind States
    “screened in” at step one to reduce emissions in accord
    with the uniform cost thresholds set during the step two
    control analysis. Imposing these uniform cost thresholds,
    the Court of Appeals observed, could force some upwind
    States to reduce emissions by more than their “fair share.”
    
    Id., at 27.
       According to the Court of Appeals, EPA had also failed
    to ensure that the Transport Rule did not mandate up­
    12       EPA v. EME HOMER CITY GENERATION, L. P.
    Opinion of the Court
    wind States to reduce pollution unnecessarily. The Good
    Neighbor Provision, the D. C. Circuit noted, “targets [only]
    those emissions from upwind States that ‘contribute sig­
    nificantly to nonattainment’ ” of a NAAQS in downwind
    States. 
    Id., at 22.
    Pollution reduction beyond that goal
    was “unnecessary over-control,” outside the purview of the
    Agency’s statutory mandate. 
    Ibid. Because the emission
    budgets were calculated by reference to cost alone, the
    court concluded that EPA had done nothing to guard
    against, or even measure, the “over-control” potentially
    imposed by the Transport Rule. See 
    ibid. Finally, by deciding,
    at the screening analysis, that
    upwind contributions below the one-percent threshold
    were insignificant, EPA had established a “floor” on the
    Agency’s authority to act. See 
    id., at 20,
    and n. 13. Again
    pointing to the rule’s reliance on costs, the Court of Ap­
    peals held that EPA had failed to ensure that upwind
    States were not being forced to reduce emissions below the
    one-percent threshold. See 
    ibid. In dissent, Judge
    Rogers criticized the majority for
    deciding two questions that were not, in her view, properly
    before the court. See 
    id., at 40–46,
    51–58. First, she
    addressed the majority’s insistence that FIPs abide a
    State’s opportunity to allocate its emission budget among
    in-state sources. She regarded the respondents’ plea to
    that effect as an untimely attack on EPA’s previous SIP
    disapprovals. See 
    id., at 40–46.
    Second, in Judge Rogers’
    assessment, the respondents had failed to raise their
    substantive objections to the Transport Rule with the
    specificity necessary to preserve them for review. See 
    id., at 51–58.
    On the merits, Judge Rogers found nothing in
    the Act to require, or even suggest, that EPA must quan-
    tify a State’s good neighbor obligations before it promul­
    gated a FIP. See 
    id., at 46–51.
    She also disagreed with
    the court’s conclusion that the Transport Rule unreasona­
    bly interpreted the Act. See 
    id., at 58–60.
                     Cite as: 572 U. S. ____ (2014)          13
    Opinion of the Court
    We granted certiorari to decide whether the D. C. Cir­
    cuit had accurately construed the limits the CAA places on
    EPA’s authority. See 570 U. S. ___ (2013).
    II
    A
    Once EPA has calculated emission budgets, the D. C.
    Circuit held, the Agency must give upwind States the
    opportunity to propose SIPs allocating those budgets
    among in-state sources before issuing a 
    FIP. 696 F.3d, at 37
    . As the State respondents put it, a FIP allocating a
    State’s emission budget “must issue after EPA has quanti­
    fied the States’ good-neighbor obligations [in an emission
    budget] and given the States a reasonable opportunity to
    meet those obligations in SIPs.” Brief for State Respond­
    ents 20.
    Before reaching the merits of this argument, we first
    reject EPA’s threshold objection that the claim is untimely.
    According to the Agency, this argument—and the D. C.
    Circuit’s opinion accepting it—rank as improper collateral
    attacks on EPA’s prior SIP disapprovals. As earlier re­
    counted, 
    see supra, at 9
    –10, EPA, by the time it issued the
    Transport Rule, had determined that each regulated
    upwind State had failed to submit a SIP adequate to
    satisfy the Good Neighbor Provision. Many of those de­
    terminations, because unchallenged, became final after 60
    days, see 
    42 U.S. C
    . §7607(b)(1), and did so before the
    petitions here at issue were filed. EPA argues that the
    Court cannot question exercise of the Agency’s FIP author­
    ity without subjecting these final SIP disapprovals to
    untimely review.
    We disagree. The gravamen of the State respondents’
    challenge is not that EPA’s disapproval of any particular
    SIP was erroneous. Rather, respondents urge that, not­
    withstanding these disapprovals, the Agency was obliged
    to grant an upwind State a second opportunity to promul­
    14         EPA v. EME HOMER CITY GENERATION, L. P.
    Opinion of the Court
    gate adequate SIPs once EPA set the State’s emission
    budget. This claim does not depend on the validity of the
    prior SIP disapprovals. Even assuming the legitimacy of
    those disapprovals, the question remains whether EPA
    was required to do more than disapprove a SIP, as the
    State respondents urge, to trigger the Agency’s statutory
    authority to issue a FIP.12
    B
    Turning to the merits, we hold that the text of the stat­
    ute supports EPA’s position. As earlier noted, 
    see supra, at 4
    –5, the CAA sets a series of precise deadlines to which
    the States and EPA must adhere. Once EPA issues any
    new or revised NAAQS, a State has three years to adopt a
    SIP adequate for compliance with the Act’s requirements.
    See 
    42 U.S. C
    . §7410(a)(1). Among those requirements is
    the Act’s mandate that SIPs “shall” include provisions
    sufficient to satisfy the Good Neighbor Provision.
    §7410(a)(2).
    If EPA determines a SIP to be inadequate, the Agency’s
    mandate to replace it with a FIP is no less absolute:
    “[EPA] shall promulgate a [FIP] at any time within
    2 years after the [Agency]
    “(A) finds that a State has failed to make a required
    submission or finds that the plan or plan revision
    submitted by the State does not satisfy the minimum
    [relevant] criteria . . . , or
    ——————
    12 The State respondents make a second argument we do not reach.
    They urge that EPA could not impose FIPs on several upwind States
    whose SIPs had been previously approved by the Agency under CAIR.
    EPA changed those approvals to disapprovals when it issued the
    Transport Rule, see 76 Fed. Reg. 48220, and the States assert that the
    process by which EPA did so was improper. That argument was not
    passed on by the D. C. Circuit, see 
    696 F.3d 7
    , 31, n. 29 (2012), and we
    leave it for the Court of Appeals to consider in the first instance on
    remand.
    Cite as: 572 U. S. ____ (2014)                    15
    Opinion of the Court
    “(B) disapproves a [SIP] in whole or in part,
    “unless the State corrects the deficiency, and [EPA]
    approves the plan or plan revision, before the [Agency]
    promulgates such [FIP].” §7410(c)(1).
    In other words, once EPA has found a SIP inadequate, the
    Agency has a statutory duty to issue a FIP “at any time”
    within two years (unless the State first “corrects the defi­
    ciency,” which no one contends occurred here).
    The D. C. Circuit, however, found an unwritten excep­
    tion to this strict time prescription for SIPs aimed at
    implementing the Good Neighbor Provision. Expecting
    any one State to develop a “comprehensive solution” to the
    “collective problem” of interstate air pollution without first
    receiving EPA’s guidance was, in the Court of Appeals’
    assessment, “set[ting] the States up to 
    fail.” 696 F.3d, at 36
    –37. The D. C. Circuit therefore required EPA, after
    promulgating each State’s emission budget, to give the
    State a “reasonable” period of time to propose SIPs im­
    plementing its budget. See 
    id., at 37.
       However sensible (or not) the Court of Appeals’ posi­
    tion,13 a reviewing court’s “task is to apply the text [of the
    statute], not to improve upon it.” Pavelic & LeFlore v.
    Marvel Entertainment Group, Div. of Cadence Industries
    Corp., 
    493 U.S. 120
    , 126 (1989). Nothing in the Act dif­
    ——————
    13 On this point, the dissent argues that it is “beyond responsible
    debate that the States cannot possibly design FIP-proof SIPs without
    knowing the EPA-prescribed targets at which they must aim.” Post, at
    18. Many of the State respondents thought otherwise, however, when
    litigating the matter in Michigan v. EPA, 
    213 F.3d 663
    (CADC 2000).
    See Final Brief for Petitioning States in No. 98–1497 (CADC), p. 34
    (“EPA has the responsibility to establish NAAQS,” but without further
    intervention by EPA, “States [have] the duty and right to develop . . .
    SIPs . . . to meet those NAAQS.”). See also 
    id., at 37
    (“EPA’s role is to
    determine whether the SIP submitted is ‘adequate’ . . . not to dictate
    contents of the submittal in the first instance. . . . [E]ach State has the
    right and the obligation to write a SIP that complies with §[74]10(a)(2),
    including the ‘good neighbor’ provision.”).
    16       EPA v. EME HOMER CITY GENERATION, L. P.
    Opinion of the Court
    ferentiates the Good Neighbor Provision from the several
    other matters a State must address in its SIP. Rather, the
    statute speaks without reservation: Once a NAAQS has
    been issued, a State “shall” propose a SIP within three
    years, §7410(a)(1), and that SIP “shall” include, among
    other components, provisions adequate to satisfy the Good
    Neighbor Provision, §7410(a)(2).
    Nor does the Act condition the duty to promulgate a FIP
    on EPA’s having first quantified an upwind State’s good
    neighbor obligations. As Judge Rogers observed in her
    dissent from the D. C. Circuit’s decision, the Act does not
    require EPA to furnish upwind States with information of
    any kind about their good neighbor obligations before a
    FIP issues. 
    See 696 F.3d, at 47
    . Instead, a SIP’s failure
    to satisfy the Good Neighbor Provision, without more,
    triggers EPA’s obligation to issue a federal plan within
    two years. §7410(c). After EPA has disapproved a SIP,
    the Agency can wait up to two years to issue a FIP, during
    which time the State can “correc[t] the deficiency” on its
    own. 
    Ibid. But EPA is
    not obliged to wait two years or
    postpone its action even a single day: The Act empowers
    the Agency to promulgate a FIP “at any time” within the
    two-year limit. 
    Ibid. Carving out an
    exception to the Act’s
    precise deadlines, as the D. C. Circuit did, “rewrites a
    decades-old statute whose plain text and structure estab­
    lish a clear chronology of federal and State responsibili­
    
    ties.” 696 F.3d, at 47
    (Rogers, J., dissenting).
    The practical difficulties cited by the Court of Appeals
    do not justify departure from the Act’s plain text. See
    Barnhart v. Sigmon Coal Co., 
    534 U.S. 438
    , 461–462
    (2002) (We “must presume that a legislature says in a
    statute what it means and means in a statute what it says
    there.” (internal quotation marks omitted)). When Con­
    gress elected to make EPA’s input a prerequisite to state
    action under the Act, it did so expressly. States develop­
    ing vehicle inspection and maintenance programs under
    Cite as: 572 U. S. ____ (2014)           17
    Opinion of the Court
    the CAA, for example, must await EPA guidance before
    issuing SIPs. 
    42 U.S. C
    . §7511a(c)(3)(B). A State’s obli­
    gation to adopt a SIP, moreover, arises only after EPA has
    first set the NAAQS the State must meet. §7410(a)(1).
    Had Congress intended similarly to defer States’ discharge
    of their obligations under the Good Neighbor Provision,
    Congress, we take it, would have included a similar direc­
    tion in that section. See Jama v. Immigration and Cus-
    toms Enforcement, 
    543 U.S. 335
    , 341 (2005) (“We do not
    lightly assume that Congress has omitted from its adopted
    text requirements that it nonetheless intends to apply,
    and our reluctance is even greater when Congress has
    shown elsewhere in the same statute that it knows how to
    make such a requirement manifest.”).
    In short, nothing in the statute places EPA under an
    obligation to provide specific metrics to States before they
    undertake to fulfill their good neighbor obligations. By
    altering the schedule Congress provided for SIPs and
    FIPs, the D. C. Circuit stretched out the process. It al­
    lowed a delay Congress did not order and placed an infor­
    mation submission obligation on EPA Congress did not
    impose. The D. C. Circuit, we hold, had no warrant thus
    to revise the CAA’s action-ordering prescriptions.
    C
    At oral argument, the State respondents emphasized
    EPA’s previous decisions, in the NOX SIP Call and CAIR,
    to quantify the emission reductions required of upwind
    States before the window to propose a SIP closed. See Tr.
    of Oral Arg. 37–39, 42–43, 45–46. In their view, by failing
    to accord States a similar grace period after issuing States’
    emission budgets, EPA acted arbitrarily. See 
    ibid. Whatever pattern the
    Agency followed in its NOX SIP
    call and CAIR proceedings, EPA retained discretion to
    alter its course provided it gave a reasonable explanation
    for doing so. Motor Vehicle Mfrs. Assn. of United States,
    18         EPA v. EME HOMER CITY GENERATION, L. P.
    Opinion of the Court
    Inc. v. State Farm Mut. Automobile Ins. Co., 
    463 U.S. 29
    ,
    42 (1983). The Agency presented such an explanation in
    the Transport Rule. As noted, 
    see supra, at 6
    , the D. C.
    Circuit’s North Carolina decision admonished EPA to act
    with dispatch in amending or replacing CAIR, the
    Transport Rule’s predecessor. 
    See 550 F.3d, at 1178
    (warning EPA that the stay of the court’s decision to va­
    cate CAIR would not persist “indefinite[ly]”). Given North
    Carolina’s stress on expeditious action to cure the infir-
    mities the court identified in CAIR, EPA thought
    it “[in]appropriate to establish [the] lengthy transition
    period” entailed in allowing States time to propose new or
    amended SIPs implementing the Transport Rule emission
    budgets. See 76 Fed. Reg. 48220 (citing North Carolina,
    
    550 F.3d 1176
    ). Endeavoring to satisfy the D. C. Circuit’s
    directive, EPA acted speedily, issuing FIPs contemporane­
    ously with the Transport Rule. In light of the firm dead­
    lines imposed by the Act, which we hold the D. C. Circuit
    lacked authority to alter, we cannot condemn EPA’s deci­
    sion as arbitrary or capricious.14
    III
    A
    The D. C. Circuit also held that the Transport Rule’s
    two-step interpretation of the Good Neighbor Provision
    conflicts with the Act. Before addressing this holding, we
    take up a jurisdictional objection raised by EPA.
    The CAA directs that “[o]nly an objection to a rule . . .
    ——————
    14 Inlight of the CAA’s “core principle” of cooperative federalism, the
    dissent believes EPA abused its discretion by failing to give States an
    additional opportunity to submit SIPs in satisfaction of the Good
    Neighbor Provision. Post, at 19. But nothing in the statute so restricts
    EPA. To the contrary, as earlier observed, 
    see supra, at 16
    , the plain
    text of the CAA grants EPA plenary authority to issue a FIP “at any
    time” within the two-year period that begins the moment EPA deter­
    mines a SIP to be inadequate. §7410(c)(1) (emphasis added).
    Cite as: 572 U. S. ____ (2014)          19
    Opinion of the Court
    raised with reasonable specificity during the period for
    public comment . . . may be raised during judicial review.”
    
    42 U.S. C
    . §7607(d)(7)(B). Respondents failed to state
    their objections to the Transport Rule during the comment
    period with the “specificity” required for preservation,
    EPA argues. See Brief for Federal Petitioners 34–42.
    This failure at the administrative level, EPA urges, fore­
    closes judicial review. 
    Id., at 34.
      Assuming, without deciding, that respondents did not
    meet the Act’s “reasonable specificity” requirement during
    the comment period, we do not regard that lapse as “juris­
    dictional.” This Court has cautioned against “profligate
    use” of the label “jurisdictional.” Sebelius v. Auburn Re-
    gional Medical Center, 568 U. S. ___, ___ (2013) (slip op.,
    at 6). A rule may be “mandatory,” yet not “jurisdictional,”
    we have explained. See Arbaugh v. Y & H Corp., 
    546 U.S. 500
    , 510 (2006). Section 7607(d)(7)(B), we hold, is of that
    character. It does not speak to a court’s authority, but
    only to a party’s procedural obligations. See Kontrick v.
    Ryan, 
    540 U.S. 443
    , 455 (2004). Had EPA pursued the
    “reasonable specificity” argument vigorously before the
    D. C. Circuit, we would be obligated to address the merits
    of the argument. See Gonzalez v. Thaler, 565 U. S. ___,
    ___ (2012) (slip op., at 10). But EPA did not press the
    argument unequivocally. Before the D. C. Circuit, it indi­
    cated only that the “reasonable specificity” prescription
    might bar judicial review. Brief for Respondent EPA et al.
    in No. 11–1302 (CADC), p. 30. See also 
    id., at 32.
    We
    therefore do not count the prescription an impassable
    hindrance to our adjudication of the respondents’ attack
    on EPA’s interpretation of the Transport Rule. We turn to
    that attack mindful of the importance of the issues re­
    spondents raise to the ongoing implementation of the Good
    Neighbor Provision.
    20       EPA v. EME HOMER CITY GENERATION, L. P.
    Opinion of the Court
    B
    We routinely accord dispositive effect to an agency’s
    reasonable interpretation of ambiguous statutory lan­
    guage. Chevron U. S. A. Inc. v. Natural Resources Defense
    Council, Inc., 
    467 U.S. 837
    (1984), is the pathmarking
    decision, and it bears a notable resemblance to the cases
    before us. Chevron concerned EPA’s definition of the term
    “source,” as used in the 1977 Amendments to the CAA.
    
    Id., at 840,
    n. 1. Those amendments placed additional
    restrictions on companies’ liberty to add new pollution
    “sources” to their factories. See 
    id., at 840.
    Although
    “source” might have been interpreted to refer to an indi­
    vidual smokestack, EPA construed the term to refer to an
    entire plant, thereby “treat[ing] all of the pollution­
    emitting devices within the [plant] as though they were
    encased within a single ‘bubble.’” 
    Ibid. Under the Agency’s
    interpretation, a new pollution-emitting device would not
    subject a plant to the additional restrictions if the “altera­
    tion [did] not increase the total emissions [produced by]
    the plant.” 
    Ibid. This Court held
    EPA’s interpretation of “source” a rea­
    sonable construction of an ambiguous statutory term.
    When “Congress has not directly addressed the precise
    [interpretative] question at issue,” we cautioned, a review­
    ing court cannot “simply impose its own construction o[f]
    the statute.” 
    Id., at 843.
    Rather, the agency is charged
    with filling the “gap left open” by the ambiguity. 
    Id., at 866.
    Because “ ‘a full understanding of the force of the
    statutory policy . . . depend[s] upon more than ordinary
    knowledge’ ” of the situation, the administering agency’s
    construction is to be accorded “controlling weight unless
    . . . arbitrary, capricious, or manifestly contrary to the
    statute.” 
    Id., at 844
    (quoting United States v. Shimer, 
    367 U.S. 374
    , 382 (1961)). Determining that none of those
    terms fit EPA’s interpretation of “source,” the Court de­
    ferred to the Agency’s judgment.
    Cite as: 572 U. S. ____ (2014)                 21
    Opinion of the Court
    We conclude that the Good Neighbor Provision delegates
    authority to EPA at least as certainly as the CAA provi­
    sions involved in Chevron. The statute requires States to
    eliminate those “amounts” of pollution that “contribute
    significantly to nonattainment” in downwind States. 
    42 U.S. C
    . §7410(a)(2)(D)(i) (emphasis added). Thus, EPA’s
    task15 is to reduce upwind pollution, but only in “amounts”
    that push a downwind State’s pollution concentrations
    above the relevant NAAQS. As noted earlier, however, the
    nonattainment of downwind States results from the collec­
    tive and interwoven contributions of multiple upwind
    States. 
    See supra, at 3
    . The statute therefore calls
    upon the Agency to address a thorny causation problem:
    How should EPA allocate among multiple contributing up-
    wind States responsibility for a downwind State’s excess
    pollution?
    A simplified example illustrates the puzzle EPA faced.
    Suppose the Agency sets a NAAQS, with respect to a
    particular pollutant, at 100 parts per billion (ppb), and
    that the level of the pollutant in the atmosphere of down­
    wind State A is 130 ppb. Suppose further that EPA has
    determined that each of three upwind States—X, Y, and
    Z—contributes the equivalent of 30 ppb of the relevant
    pollutant to State A’s airspace. The Good Neighbor Provi­
    sion, as just observed, prohibits only upwind emissions
    that contribute significantly to downwind nonattainment.
    EPA’s authority under the provision is therefore limited to
    eliminating a total of 30 ppb,16 i.e., the overage caused by
    ——————
    15 Though we speak here of “EPA’s task,” the Good Neighbor Provi­
    sion is initially directed to upwind States. As earlier explained, see
    Part 
    II–B, supra
    , only after a State has failed to propose a SIP ade­
    quate for compliance with the provision is EPA called upon to act.
    16 Because of the uncertainties inherent in measuring interstate air
    pollution, 
    see supra, at 3
    –4, reductions of exactly 30 ppb likely are
    unattainable. See infra, at 30–31.
    22         EPA v. EME HOMER CITY GENERATION, L. P.
    Opinion of the Court
    the collective contribution of States X, Y, and Z.17
    How is EPA to divide responsibility among the three
    States? Should the Agency allocate reductions propor­
    tionally (10 ppb each), on a per capita basis, on the basis of
    the cost of abatement, or by some other metric? See Brief
    for Federal Petitioners 50 (noting EPA’s consideration of
    different approaches). The Good Neighbor Provision does
    not answer that question for EPA. Cf. 
    Chevron, 467 U.S., at 860
    (“[T]he language of [the CAA] simply does not
    compel any given interpretation of the term ‘source.’ ”).
    Under Chevron, we read Congress’ silence as a delegation
    of authority to EPA to select from among reasonable op­
    tions. See United States v. Mead Corp., 
    533 U.S. 218
    , 229
    (2001).18
    Yet the Court of Appeals believed that the Act speaks
    clearly, requiring EPA to allocate responsibility for reduc­
    ing emissions in “a manner proportional to” each State’s
    “contributio[n]” to the 
    problem. 696 F.3d, at 21
    . Nothing
    ——————
    17 For  simplicity’s sake, the hypothetical assumes that EPA has not
    required any emission reductions by the downwind State itself.
    18 The statutory gap identified also exists in the Good Neighbor Provi­
    sion’s second instruction. That instruction requires EPA to eliminate
    amounts of upwind pollution that “interfere with maintenance” of a
    NAAQS by a downwind State. §7410(a)(2)(D)(i). This mandate con­
    tains no qualifier analogous to “significantly,” and yet it entails a
    delegation of administrative authority of the same character as the one
    discussed above. Just as EPA is constrained, under the first part of the
    Good Neighbor Provision, to eliminate only those amounts that “con­
    tribute . . . to nonattainment,” EPA is limited, by the second part of the
    provision, to reduce only by “amounts” that “interfere with mainte-
    nance,” i.e., by just enough to permit an already-attaining State to
    maintain satisfactory air quality. (Emphasis added.) With multiple
    upwind States contributing to the maintenance problem, however, EPA
    confronts the same challenge that the “contribute significantly” man­
    date creates: How should EPA allocate reductions among multiple
    upwind States, many of which contribute in amounts sufficient to
    impede downwind maintenance? Nothing in either clause of the Good
    Neighbor Provision provides the criteria by which EPA is meant to
    apportion responsibility.
    Cite as: 572 U. S. ____ (2014)           23
    Opinion of the Court
    in the text of the Good Neighbor Provision propels EPA
    down this path. Understandably so, for as EPA notes, the
    D. C. Circuit’s proportionality approach could scarcely be
    satisfied in practice. See App. in No. 11–1302 etc.
    (CADC), p. 2312 (“[W]hile it is possible to determine an
    emission reduction percentage if there is a single down­
    wind [receptor], most upwind states contribute to multiple
    downwind [receptors] (in multiple states) and would have
    a different reduction percentage for each one.”).
    To illustrate, consider a variation on the example set out
    above. Imagine that States X and Y now contribute air
    pollution to State A in a ratio of one to five, i.e., State Y
    contributes five times the amount of pollution to State A
    than does State X. If State A were the only downwind
    State to which the two upwind States contributed, the
    D. C. Circuit’s proportionality requirement would be easy
    to meet: EPA could require State Y to reduce its emissions
    by five times the amount demanded of State X.
    The realities of interstate air pollution, however, are not
    so simple. Most upwind States contribute pollution to
    multiple downwind States in varying amounts. See 76
    Fed. Reg. 48239–48246. See also Brief for Respondent
    Calpine Corp. et al. in Support of Petitioners 48–49 (offer­
    ing examples). Suppose then that States X and Y also
    contribute pollutants to a second downwind State (State
    B), this time in a ratio of seven to one. Though State Y
    contributed a relatively larger share of pollution to State
    A, with respect to State B, State X is the greater offender.
    Following the proportionality approach with respect to
    State B would demand that State X reduce its emissions
    by seven times as much as State Y. Recall, however, that
    State Y, as just hypothesized, had to effect five times as
    large a reduction with respect to State A. The Court of
    Appeals’ proportionality edict with respect to both State A
    and State B appears to work neither mathematically nor
    in practical application. Proportionality as to one down­
    24         EPA v. EME HOMER CITY GENERATION, L. P.
    Opinion of the Court
    wind State will not achieve proportionality as to others.
    Quite the opposite. And where, as is generally true, up­
    wind States contribute pollution to more than two down­
    wind receptors, proportionality becomes all the more
    elusive.
    Neither the D. C. Circuit nor respondents face up to this
    problem. The dissent, for its part, strains to give meaning
    to the D. C. Circuit’s proportionality constraint as applied
    to a world in which multiple upwind States contribute
    emissions to multiple downwind locations. In the dissent’s
    view, upwind States must eliminate emissions by “what­
    ever minimum amount reduces” their share of the overage
    in each and every one of the downwind States to which
    they are linked. See post, at 8. In practical terms, this
    means each upwind State will be required to reduce emis­
    sions by the amount necessary to eliminate that State’s
    largest downwind contribution. The dissent’s formulation,
    however, does not account for the combined and cumu-
    lative effect of each upwind State’s reductions on attain­
    ment in multiple downwind locations. See 
    ibid. (“Under a proportional-reduction
    approach, State X would be required
    to eliminate emissions of that pollutant by whatever min­
    imum amount reduces both State A’s level by 0.2 unit and
    State B’s by 0.7 unit.” (emphasis added)). The result
    would be costly overregulation unnecessary to, indeed
    in conflict with, the Good Neighbor Provision’s goal of
    attainment.19
    ——————
    19 To see why, one need only slightly complicate the world envisioned
    by the dissent. Assume the world is made up of only four States—two
    upwind (States X and Y), and two downwind (States A and B). Suppose
    also, as the dissent allows, see post, at 9, that the reductions State X
    must make to eliminate its share of the amount by which State A is in
    nonattainment are more than necessary for State X to eliminate its
    share of State B’s nonattainment. As later explained, see infra, at 29–
    30, this kind of “over-control,” we agree with the dissent, is acceptable
    under the statute. Suppose, however, that State Y also contributes to
    pollution in both State A and State B such that the reductions it must
    Cite as: 572 U. S. ____ (2014)                  25
    Opinion of the Court
    In response, the dissent asserts that EPA will “simply
    be required to make allowance for” the overregulation
    caused by its “proportional-reduction” approach. Post, at
    11. What criterion should EPA employ to determine
    which States will have to make those “allowance[s]” and
    by how much? The dissent admits there are “multiple
    ways” EPA might answer those questions. 
    Ibid. But proportionality cannot
    be one of those ways, for the
    proportional-reduction approach is what led to the over­
    regulation in the first place. And if a nonproportional
    approach can play a role in setting the final allocation of
    reduction obligations, then it is hardly apparent why EPA,
    free to depart from proportionality at the back end, cannot
    do so at the outset.
    Persuaded that the Good Neighbor Provision does not
    dictate the particular allocation of emissions among con­
    tributing States advanced by the D. C. Circuit, we must
    next decide whether the allocation method chosen by EPA
    is a “permissible construction of the statute.” 
    Chevron, 467 U.S., at 843
    . As EPA interprets the statute, upwind
    emissions rank as “amounts [that] . . . contribute signifi­
    cantly to nonattainment” if they (1) constitute one percent
    ——————
    make to eliminate its proportion of State B’s overage exceed the reduc­
    tions it must make to bring State A into attainment. In this case, the
    dissent would have State X reduce by just enough to eliminate its share
    of State A’s nonattainment and more than enough to eliminate its
    share of State B’s overage. The converse will be true as to State Y:
    Under the dissent’s approach, State Y would have to reduce by the
    “minimum” necessary to eliminate its proportional share of State B’s
    nonattainment and more than enough to eliminate its proportion of
    State A’s overage. The result is that the total amount by which both
    States X and Y are required to reduce will exceed what is necessary for
    attainment in all downwind States involved (i.e., in both State A and
    State B). Over-control thus unnecessary to achieving attainment in all
    involved States is impermissible under the Good Neighbor Provision.
    See infra, at 30, n. 23. The problem would worsen were the hypothet­
    ical altered to include more than two downwind States and two upwind
    States, the very real circumstances EPA must address.
    26       EPA v. EME HOMER CITY GENERATION, L. P.
    Opinion of the Court
    or more of a relevant NAAQS in a nonattaining downwind
    State and (2) can be eliminated under the cost threshold
    set by the Agency. See 76 Fed. Reg. 48254. In other
    words, to identify which emissions were to be eliminated,
    EPA considered both the magnitude of upwind States’
    contributions and the cost associated with eliminating
    them.
    The Industry respondents argue that, however EPA
    ultimately divides responsibility among upwind States,
    the final calculation cannot rely on costs. The Good
    Neighbor Provision, respondents and the dissent empha­
    size, “requires each State to prohibit only those ‘amounts’
    of air pollution emitted within the State that ‘contribute
    significantly’ to another State’s nonattaintment.” Brief for
    Industry Respondents 23 (emphasis added). See also post,
    at 6. The cost of preventing emissions, they urge, is
    wholly unrelated to the actual “amoun[t]” of air pollution
    an upwind State contributes. Brief for Industry Respond­
    ents 23. Because the Transport Rule considers costs,
    respondents argue, “States that contribute identical
    ‘amounts’ . . . may be deemed [by EPA] to have [made]
    substantially different” contributions. 
    Id., at 30.
       But, as just explained, 
    see supra, at 21
    –22, the Agency
    cannot avoid the task of choosing which among equal
    “amounts” to eliminate. The Agency has chosen, sensibly
    in our view, to reduce the amount easier, i.e., less costly, to
    eradicate, and nothing in the text of the Good Neighbor
    Provision precludes that choice.
    Using costs in the Transport Rule calculus, we agree
    with EPA, also makes good sense. Eliminating those
    amounts that can cost-effectively be reduced is an efficient
    and equitable solution to the allocation problem the Good
    Neighbor Provision requires the Agency to address. Effi­
    cient because EPA can achieve the levels of attainment,
    i.e., of emission reductions, the proportional approach
    aims to achieve, but at a much lower overall cost. Equita­
    Cite as: 572 U. S. ____ (2014)                    27
    Opinion of the Court
    ble because, by imposing uniform cost thresholds on regu­
    lated States, EPA’s rule subjects to stricter regulation
    those States that have done relatively less in the past to
    control their pollution. Upwind States that have not yet
    implemented pollution controls of the same stringency as
    their neighbors will be stopped from free riding on their
    neighbors’ efforts to reduce pollution. They will have to
    bring down their emissions by installing devices of the
    kind in which neighboring States have already invested.
    Suppose, for example, that the industries of upwind
    State A have expended considerable resources installing
    modern pollution-control devices on their plants. Facto­
    ries in upwind State B, by contrast, continue to run old,
    dirty plants. Yet, perhaps because State A is more popu­
    lous and therefore generates a larger sum of pollution
    overall, the two States’ emissions have equal effects on
    downwind attainment. If State A and State B are re­
    quired to eliminate emissions proportionally (i.e., equally),
    sources in State A will be compelled to spend far more per
    ton of reductions because they have already utilized lower
    cost pollution controls. State A’s sources will also have to
    achieve greater reductions than would have been required
    had they not made the cost-effective reductions in the first
    place. State A, in other words, will be tolled for having
    done more to reduce pollution in the past.20 EPA’s cost­
    based allocation avoids these anomalies.
    Obligated to require the elimination of only those
    “amounts” of pollutants that contribute to the nonattain­
    ment of NAAQS in downwind States, EPA must decide
    how to differentiate among the otherwise like contribu­
    tions of multiple upwind States. EPA found decisive the
    ——————
    20 The dissent’s approach is similarly infirm. It, too, would toll those
    upwind States that have already invested heavily in means to reduce
    the pollution their industries cause, while lightening the burden on
    States that have done relatively less to control pollution emanating
    from local enterprises.
    28         EPA v. EME HOMER CITY GENERATION, L. P.
    Opinion of the Court
    difficulty of eliminating each “amount,” i.e., the cost in­
    curred in doing so. Lacking a dispositive statutory in­
    struction to guide it, EPA’s decision, we conclude, is a
    “reasonable” way of filling the “gap left open by Congress.”
    
    Chevron, 467 U.S., at 866
    .21
    C
    The D. C. Circuit stated two further objections to EPA’s
    cost-based method of defining an upwind State’s contribu­
    tion. Once a State was screened in at step one of EPA’s
    analysis, its emission budget was calculated solely with
    reference to the uniform cost thresholds the Agency selected
    at step two. The Transport Rule thus left open the
    possibility that a State might be compelled to reduce
    emissions beyond the point at which every affected down­
    wind State is in attainment, a phenomenon the Court of
    Appeals termed 
    “over-control.” 696 F.3d, at 22
    ; 
    see supra, at 12
    . Second, EPA’s focus on costs did not foreclose, as
    the D. C. Circuit accurately observed, the possibility that
    an upwind State would be required to reduce its emissions
    by so much that the State no longer contributed one per­
    ——————
    21 The dissent, see post, at 12–13, relies heavily on our decision in
    Whitman v. American Trucking Assns., Inc., 
    531 U.S. 457
    (2001). In
    Whitman, we held that the relevant text of the CAA “unambiguously
    bars” EPA from considering costs when determining a NAAQS. 
    Id., at 471.
    Section 7409(b)(1) commands EPA to set NAAQS at levels “requi­
    site to protect the public health” with “an adequate margin of safety.”
    This mandate, we observed in Whitman, was “absolute,” and precluded
    any other consideration (e.g., cost) in the NAAQS calculation. 
    Id., at 465
    (internal quotation marks omitted). Not so of the Good Neighbor
    Provision, which grants EPA discretion to eliminate “amounts [of
    pollution that] . . . contribute significantly to nonattainment” down­
    wind. On the particular “amounts” that should qualify for elimination,
    the statute is silent. Unlike the provision at issue in Whitman, which
    provides express criteria by which EPA is to set NAAQS, the Good
    Neighbor Provision, as earlier explained, fails to provide any metric by
    which EPA can differentiate among the contributions of multiple
    upwind States. 
    See supra, at 21
    –22.
    Cite as: 572 U. S. ____ (2014)                  29
    Opinion of the Court
    cent or more of a relevant NAAQS to any downwind State.
    This would place the State below the mark EPA had set,
    during the screening phase, as the initial threshold of
    “significan[ce].” See 
    id., at 20,
    and n. 13.
    We agree with the Court of Appeals to this extent: EPA
    cannot require a State to reduce its output of pollution by
    more than is necessary to achieve attainment in every
    downwind State or at odds with the one-percent threshold
    the Agency has set. If EPA requires an upwind State to
    reduce emissions by more than the amount necessary to
    achieve attainment in every downwind State to which it is
    linked, the Agency will have overstepped its authority,
    under the Good Neighbor Provision, to eliminate those
    “amounts [that] contribute . . . to nonattainment.” Nor
    can EPA demand reductions that would drive an upwind
    State’s contribution to every downwind State to which it is
    linked below one percent of the relevant NAAQS. Doing
    so would be counter to step one of the Agency’s interpreta­
    tion of the Good Neighbor Provision. See 76 Fed. Reg.
    48236 (“[S]tates whose contributions are below th[e]
    thresholds do not significantly contribute to nonattain­
    ment . . . of the relevant NAAQS.”).
    Neither possibility, however, justifies wholesale invali­
    dation of the Transport Rule. First, instances of “over­
    control” in particular downwind locations, the D. C. Cir­
    cuit acknowledged, 
    see 696 F.3d, at 22
    , may be incidental
    to reductions necessary to ensure attainment elsewhere.
    Because individual upwind States often “contribute signif­
    icantly” to nonattainment in multiple downwind locations,
    the emissions reduction required to bring one linked
    downwind State into attainment may well be large enough
    to push other linked downwind States over the attainment
    line.22 As the Good Neighbor Provision seeks attainment
    ——————
    22 The following example, based on the record, is offered in Brief for
    Respondent Calpine Corp. et al. in Support of Petitioners 52–54. Ohio,
    30         EPA v. EME HOMER CITY GENERATION, L. P.
    Opinion of the Court
    in every downwind State, however, exceeding attainment
    in one State cannot rank as “over-control” unless unneces­
    sary to achieving attainment in any downwind State.
    Only reductions unnecessary to downwind attainment
    anywhere fall outside the Agency’s statutory authority.23
    Second, while EPA has a statutory duty to avoid over­
    control, the Agency also has a statutory obligation to avoid
    “under-control,” i.e., to maximize achievement of attain­
    ment downwind. For reasons earlier explained, 
    see supra, at 3
    –4, a degree of imprecision is inevitable in tackling the
    problem of interstate air pollution. Slight changes in wind
    patterns or energy consumption, for example, may vary
    downwind air quality in ways EPA might not have antici­
    pated. The Good Neighbor Provision requires EPA to seek
    ——————
    West Virginia, Pennsylvania, and Indiana each contribute in varying
    amounts to five different nonattainment areas in three downwind
    States. 
    Id., at 52.
    Implementation of the Transport Rule, EPA model­
    ing demonstrates, will bring three of these five areas into attainment
    by a comfortable margin, and a fourth only barely. See 
    id., at 53,
    fig. 2.
    The fifth downwind receptor, however, will still fall short of attainment
    despite the reductions the rule requires. See 
    ibid. But if EPA
    were to
    lower the emission reductions required of the upwind States to reduce
    over-attainment in the first three areas, the area barely achieving
    attainment would no longer do so, and the area still in nonattainment
    would fall even further behind. Thus, “over-control” of the first three
    downwind receptors is essential to the attainment achieved by the
    fourth and to the fifth’s progress toward that goal.
    23 The dissent suggests that our qualification of the term “over­
    control” is tantamount to an admission that “nothing stands in the way
    of [a] proportional-reduction approach.” Post, at 9. Not so. Permitting
    “over-control” as to one State for the purpose of achieving attainment in
    another furthers the stated goal of the Good Neighbor Provision, i.e.,
    attainment of NAAQS. By contrast, a proportional-reduction scheme is
    neither necessary to achieve downwind attainment, nor mandated by
    the terms of the statute, as earlier discussed, 
    see supra, at 21
    –25.
    Permitting “over-control” for the purpose of achieving proportionality
    would thus contravene the clear limits the statute places on EPA’s good
    neighbor authority, i.e., to eliminate only those “amounts” of upwind
    pollutants essential to achieving attainment downwind.
    Cite as: 572 U. S. ____ (2014)           31
    Opinion of the Court
    downwind attainment of NAAQS notwithstanding the
    uncertainties. Hence, some amount of over-control, i.e.,
    emission budgets that turn out to be more demanding
    than necessary, would not be surprising. Required to
    balance the possibilities of under-control and over-control,
    EPA must have leeway in fulfilling its statutory mandate.
    Finally, in a voluminous record, involving thousands of
    upwind-to-downwind linkages, respondents point to only a
    few instances of “unnecessary” emission reductions, and
    even those are contested by EPA. Compare Brief for
    Industry Respondents 19 with Reply Brief for Federal
    Petitioners 21–22. EPA, for its part, offers data, contested
    by respondents, purporting to show that few (if any) up­
    wind States have been required to limit emissions below
    the one-percent threshold of significance. Compare Brief
    for Federal Petitioners 37, 54–55, with Brief for Industry
    Respondents 40.
    If any upwind State concludes it has been forced to
    regulate emissions below the one-percent threshold or
    beyond the point necessary to bring all downwind States
    into attainment, that State may bring a particularized, as­
    applied challenge to the Transport Rule, along with any
    other as-applied challenges it may have. Cf. Babbitt v.
    Sweet Home Chapter, Communities for Great Ore., 
    515 U.S. 687
    , 699–700 (1995) (approving agency’s reasonable
    interpretation of statute despite possibility of improper
    applications); American Hospital Assn. v. NLRB, 
    499 U.S. 606
    , 619 (1991) (rejecting facial challenge to National
    Labor Relations Board rule despite possible arbitrary
    applications). Satisfied that EPA’s cost-based methodol-
    ogy, on its face, is not “arbitrary, capricious, or manifestly
    contrary to the statute,” 
    Chevron, 467 U.S., at 844
    , we
    uphold the Transport Rule. The possibility that the rule,
    in uncommon particular applications, might exceed EPA’s
    statutory authority does not warrant judicial condemna­
    tion of the rule in its entirety.
    32       EPA v. EME HOMER CITY GENERATION, L. P.
    Opinion of the Court
    In sum, we hold that the CAA does not command that
    States be given a second opportunity to file a SIP after
    EPA has quantified the State’s interstate pollution obliga­
    tions. We further conclude that the Good Neighbor Provi­
    sion does not require EPA to disregard costs and consider
    exclusively each upwind State’s physically proportionate
    responsibility for each downwind air quality problem.
    EPA’s cost-effective allocation of emission reductions
    among upwind States, we hold, is a permissible, work-
    able, and equitable interpretation of the Good Neighbor
    Provision.
    *   *    *
    For the reasons stated, the judgment of the United
    States Court of Appeals for the D. C. Circuit is reversed,
    and the cases are remanded for further proceedings con­
    sistent with this opinion.
    It is so ordered.
    JUSTICE ALITO took no part in the consideration or
    decision of these cases.
    Cite as: 572 U. S. ____ (2014)           1
    SCALIA, J., dissenting
    SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES
    _________________
    Nos. 12–1182 and 12–1183
    _________________
    ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION AGENCY ET AL.,
    PETITIONERS
    12–1182             v.
    EME HOMER CITY GENERATION, L. P., ET AL.; AND
    AMERICAN LUNG ASSOCIATION ET AL.,
    PETITIONERS
    12–1183              v.
    EME HOMER CITY GENERATION, L. P., ET AL.
    ON WRITS OF CERTIORARI TO THE UNITED STATES COURT OF
    APPEALS FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA CIRCUIT
    [April 29, 2014]
    JUSTICE SCALIA, with whom JUSTICE THOMAS joins,
    dissenting.
    Too many important decisions of the Federal Govern­
    ment are made nowadays by unelected agency officials
    exercising broad lawmaking authority, rather than by the
    people’s representatives in Congress. With the statute
    involved in the present cases, however, Congress did it
    right. It specified quite precisely the responsibility of an
    upwind State under the Good Neighbor Provision: to
    eliminate those amounts of pollutants that it contributes
    to downwind problem areas. But the Environmental
    Protection Agency was unsatisfied with this system.
    Agency personnel, perhaps correctly, thought it more
    efficient to require reductions not in proportion to the
    amounts of pollutants for which each upwind State is
    responsible, but on the basis of how cost-effectively each
    can decrease emissions.
    2          EPA v. EME HOMER CITY GENERATION, L. P.
    SCALIA, J., dissenting
    Today, the majority approves that undemocratic revi­
    sion of the Clean Air Act. The Agency came forward with
    a textual justification for its action, relying on a farfetched
    meaning of the word “significantly” in the statutory text.
    That justification is so feeble that today’s majority does
    not even recite it, much less defend it. The majority
    reaches its result (“Look Ma, no hands!”) without benefit
    of text, claiming to have identified a remarkable “gap” in
    the statute, which it proceeds to fill (contrary to the plain
    logic of the statute) with cost-benefit analysis—and then,
    with no pretended textual justification at all, simply ex­
    tends cost-benefit analysis beyond the scope of the alleged
    gap.
    Additionally, the majority relieves EPA of any obligation
    to announce novel interpretations of the Good Neighbor
    Provision before the States must submit plans that are
    required to comply with those interpretations. By accord­
    ing the States primacy in deciding how to attain the gov­
    erning air-quality standards, the Clean Air Act is preg­
    nant with an obligation for the Agency to set those
    standards before the States can be expected to achieve
    them. The majority nonetheless approves EPA’s promul­
    gation of federal plans implementing good-neighbor
    benchmarks before the States could conceivably have met
    those benchmarks on their own.
    I would affirm the judgment of the D. C. Circuit that
    EPA violated the law both in crafting the Transport Rule
    and in implementing it.1
    I. The Transport Rule
    “It is axiomatic that an administrative agency’s power to
    promulgate legislative regulations is limited to the author­
    ity delegated by Congress.” Bowen v. Georgetown Univ.
    ——————
    1 I agree with the majority’s analysis turning aside EPA’s threshold
    objections to judicial review. See ante, at 13–14, 18–19.
    Cite as: 572 U. S. ____ (2014)            3
    SCALIA, J., dissenting
    Hospital, 
    488 U.S. 204
    , 208 (1988). Yet today the major-
    ity treats the text of the Clean Air Act not as the source
    and ceiling of EPA’s authority to regulate interstate air
    pollution, but rather as a difficulty to be overcome in
    pursuit of the Agency’s responsibility to “craf[t] a solution
    to the problem of interstate air pollution.” Ante, at 3. In
    reality, Congress itself has crafted the solution. The Good
    Neighbor Provision requires each State to eliminate what­
    ever “amounts” of “air pollutant[s]” “contribute significantly
    to nonattainment” or “interfere with maintenance” of
    national ambient air-quality standards (NAAQS) in other
    States. 
    42 U.S. C
    . §7410(a)(2)(D)(i)(I). The statute ad­
    dresses solely the environmental consequences of emis­
    sions, not the facility of reducing them; and it requires
    States to shoulder burdens in proportion to the size of
    their contributions, not in proportion to the ease of bearing
    them. EPA’s utterly fanciful “from each according to its
    ability” construction sacrifices democratically adopted text
    to bureaucratically favored policy. It deserves no defer­
    ence under Chevron U. S. A. Inc. v. Natural Resources
    Defense Council, Inc., 
    467 U.S. 837
    (1984).
    A. Alleged Textual Support: “Significantly”
    In the Government’s argument here, the asserted tex­
    tual support for the efficient-reduction approach adopted by
    EPA in the Transport Rule is the ambiguity of the word
    “significantly” in the statutory requirement that each
    State eliminate those “amounts” of pollutants that “con­
    tribute significantly to nonattainment” in downwind
    States. §7410(a)(2)(D)(i)(I) (emphasis added). As de­
    scribed in the Government’s briefing:
    “[T]he term ‘significantly’ . . . is ambiguous, and . . .
    EPA may permissibly determine the amount of a
    State’s ‘significant’ contribution by reference to the
    amount of emissions reductions achievable through
    application of highly cost-effective controls.” Reply
    4        EPA v. EME HOMER CITY GENERATION, L. P.
    SCALIA, J., dissenting
    Brief for Federal Petitioners 15–16 (emphasis added;
    some internal quotation marks omitted).
    And as the Government stated at oral argument:
    “[I]n terms of the language, ‘contribute significantly,’
    . . . EPA reasonably construed that term to include a
    component of difficulty of achievement [i.e., cost]; that
    is, in common parlance, we might say that dunking a
    basketball is a more significant achievement for
    somebody who is 5 feet 10 than for somebody who is 6
    feet 10.” Tr. of Oral Arg. 9 (emphasis added).
    But of course the statute does not focus on whether the
    upwind State has “achieved significantly”; it asks whether
    the State has “contributed significantly” to downwind
    pollution. The provision addresses the physical effects of
    physical causes, and it is only the magnitude of the rela­
    tionship sufficient to trigger regulation that admits of
    some vagueness. Stated differently, the statute is ambig­
    uous as to how much of a contribution to downwind pollu­
    tion is “significant,” but it is not at all ambiguous as to
    whether factors unrelated to the amounts of pollutants
    that make up a contribution affect the analysis. Just as
    “[i]t does not matter whether the word ‘yellow’ is ambigu­
    ous when the agency has interpreted it to mean ‘purple,’ ”
    United States v. Home Concrete & Supply, LLC, 566 U. S.
    ___, ___, n. 1 (2012) (SCALIA, J., concurring in part and
    concurring in judgment) (slip op., at 2, n. 1), it does not
    matter whether the phrase “amounts which . . . contribute
    significantly [to downwind NAAQS nonattainment]” is
    ambiguous when EPA has interpreted it to mean
    “amounts which are inexpensive to eliminate.”
    It would be extraordinary for Congress, by use of the
    single word “significantly,” to transmogrify a statute that
    assigns responsibility on the basis of amounts of pollut­
    ants emitted into a statute authorizing EPA to reduce
    interstate pollution in the manner that it believes most
    Cite as: 572 U. S. ____ (2014)            5
    SCALIA, J., dissenting
    efficient. We have repeatedly said that Congress “does not
    alter the fundamental details of a regulatory scheme in
    vague terms or ancillary provisions—it does not, one
    might say, hide elephants in mouseholes.” Whitman v.
    American Trucking Assns., Inc., 
    531 U.S. 457
    , 468 (2001)
    (citing MCI Telecommunications Corp. v. American Tele-
    phone & Telegraph Co., 
    512 U.S. 218
    , 231 (1994); FDA v.
    Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 
    529 U.S. 120
    , 159–
    160 (2000)).
    The statute’s history demonstrates that “significantly” is
    not code for “feel free to consider compliance costs.” The
    previous version of the Good Neighbor Provision required
    each State to prohibit emissions that would “prevent at­
    tainment or maintenance by any other State of any
    [NAAQS].” 91 Stat. 693 (emphasis added). It is evident
    that the current reformulation (targeting “any air pollut-
    ant in amounts which will . . . contribute significantly to
    nonattainment in, or interfere with maintenance by, any
    other State with respect to any [NAAQS]”) was meant
    simply to eliminate any implication that the polluting
    State had to be a but-for rather than merely a contributing
    cause of the downwind nonattainment or maintenance
    problem—not to allow cost concerns to creep in through
    the back door.
    In another respect also EPA’s reliance upon the word
    “significantly” is plainly mistaken. The Good Neighbor
    Provision targets for elimination not only those emissions
    that “contribute significantly to nonattainment [of
    NAAQS] in . . . any other State,” but also those that “inter­
    fere with maintenance [of NAAQS] by . . . any other
    State.” §7410(a)(2)(D)(i)(I). The wiggle-word “significantly”
    is absent from the latter phrase.         EPA does not—
    cannot—provide any textual justification for the conclu­
    sion that, when the same amounts of a pollutant travel
    downwind from States X and Y to a single area in State A,
    the emissions from X but not Y can be said to “interfere
    6        EPA v. EME HOMER CITY GENERATION, L. P.
    SCALIA, J., dissenting
    with maintenance” of the NAAQS in A just because they
    are cheaper to eliminate. Yet EPA proposes to use the
    “from each according to its ability” approach for nonat­
    tainment areas and maintenance areas.
    To its credit, the majority does not allude to, much less
    try to defend, the Government’s “significantly” argument.
    But there is a serious downside to this. The sky-hook of
    “significantly” was called into service to counter the crite­
    rion of upwind-state responsibility plainly provided in the
    statute’s text: amounts of pollutants contributed to down­
    wind problem areas. See Brief for Federal Petitioners 42–
    45. Having forsworn reliance on “significantly” to convert
    responsibility for amounts of pollutants into responsibility
    for easy reduction of pollutants, the majority is impaled
    upon the statutory text.
    B. The Alleged “Gap”
    To fill the void created by its abandonment of EPA’s
    “significantly” argument, the majority identifies a sup­
    posed gap in the text, which EPA must fill: While the text
    says that each upwind State must be responsible for its
    own contribution to downwind pollution, it does not say
    how responsibility is to be divided among multiple States
    when the total of their combined contribution to downwind
    pollution in a particular area exceeds the reduction that
    the relevant NAAQS requires. In the example given by
    the majority, ante, at 21–22, when each of three upwind
    States contributes 30 units of a pollutant to a downwind
    State but the reduction required for that State to comply
    with the NAAQS is only 30 units, how will responsibility
    for that 30 units be apportioned? Wow, that’s a hard
    one—almost the equivalent of asking who is buried in
    Grant’s Tomb. If the criterion of responsibility is amounts
    of pollutants, then surely shared responsibility must be
    based upon relative amounts of pollutants—in the major­
    ity’s example, 10 units for each State. The statute makes
    Cite as: 572 U. S. ____ (2014)            7
    SCALIA, J., dissenting
    no sense otherwise. The Good Neighbor Provision con-
    tains a gap only for those who blind themselves to the
    obvious in order to pursue a preferred policy.
    But not only does the majority bring in cost-benefit
    analysis to fill a gap that does not really exist. Having
    filled that “gap,” it then extends the efficiency-based prin-
    ciple to situations beyond the imaginary gap—that is,
    situations where no apportionment is required. Even
    where only a single upwind State contributes pollutants to
    a downwind State, its annual emissions “budget” will be
    based not upon the amounts of pollutants it contributes,
    but upon what “pollution controls [are] available at the
    chosen cost thresholds.” Ante, at 9. EPA’s justification
    was its implausible (and only half-applicable) notion that
    “significantly” imports cost concerns into the provision.
    The majority, having abandoned that absurdity, is left to
    deal with the no-apportionment situation with no de-
    fense—not even an imaginary gap—against a crystal-clear
    statutory text.
    C. The Majority’s Criticisms of Proportional Reduction
    1. Impossibility
    The majority contends that a proportional-reduction
    approach “could scarcely be satisfied in practice” and
    “appears to work neither mathematically nor in practical
    application,” ante, at 23—in essence, that the approach is
    impossible of application. If that were true, I know of no
    legal authority and no democratic principle that would
    derive from it the consequence that EPA could rewrite the
    statute, rather than the consequence that the statute
    would be inoperative. “There are sometimes statutes
    which no rule or canon of interpretation can make effec-
    tive or applicable to the situations of fact which they
    purport to govern. In such cases the statute must simply
    fail.” 3 R. Pound, Jurisprudence 493 (1959) (footnote
    omitted). In other words, the impossibility argument has
    8         EPA v. EME HOMER CITY GENERATION, L. P.
    SCALIA, J., dissenting
    no independent force: It is relevant only if the majority’s
    textual interpretation is permissible. But in any event,
    the argument is wrong.
    The impossibility theorem rests upon the following
    scenario: “Imagine that States X and Y . . . contribute air
    pollution to State A in a ratio of one to five . . . .” Ante, at
    23. And suppose that “States X and Y also contribute
    pollutants to a second downwind State (State B), this time
    in a ratio of seven to one.” 
    Ibid. The majority concludes
    that “[t]he Court of Appeals’ proportionality edict with
    respect to both State A and State B appears to work nei­
    ther mathematically nor in practical application.” 
    Ibid. But why not?
    The majority’s model relies on two faulty
    premises—one an oversimplification and the other a mis­
    apprehension.
    First, the majority’s formulation suggests that EPA
    measures the comparative downwind drift of pollutants in
    free-floating proportions between States. In reality, how­
    ever, EPA assesses quantities (in physical units), not
    proportions. So, the majority’s illustration of a 1-to-5 ratio
    describing the relative contributions of States X and Y to
    State A’s pollution might mean (for example) that X is
    responsible for 0.2 unit of some pollutant above the
    NAAQS in A and that Y is responsible for 1 unit. And
    the second example, assuming a 7-to-1 ratio underlying
    State X’s and Y’s contributions to State B’s pollution,
    might mean that State X supplies 0.7 unit of the same pol­
    lutant above the NAAQS and State Y, 0.1 unit. Under a
    proportional-reduction approach, State X would be re­
    quired to eliminate emissions of that pollutant by what-
    ever minimum amount reduces both State A’s level by 0.2
    unit and State B’s by 0.7 unit. State Y, in turn, would be
    required to curtail its emissions by whatever minimum
    amount decreases both State A’s measure by 1 unit and
    State B’s by 0.1 unit.
    But, the majority objects, the reductions that State X
    Cite as: 572 U. S. ____ (2014)            9
    SCALIA, J., dissenting
    must make to help bring State B into compliance may be
    more than those necessary for it to help bring State A into
    compliance, resulting in “over-control” of X with respect to
    A. See ante, at 23–25, and n. 19. This objection discloses
    the second flaw in the impossibility theorem. Echoing
    EPA, see Brief for Federal Petitioners 47–48, the majority
    believes that the D. C. Circuit’s interpretation of the Good
    Neighbor Provision forbids over-control with respect to
    even a single downwind receptor. That is the only way in
    which the proportional-reduction approach could be
    deemed “to work neither mathematically nor in practical
    application” on its face. Ante, at 23. But the premise is
    incorrect. Although some of the D. C. Circuit’s simplified
    examples might support that conclusion, its opinion explic­
    itly acknowledged that the complexity of real-world condi­
    tions demands the contrary: “To be sure, . . . there may be
    some truly unavoidable over-control in some downwind
    States that occurs as a byproduct of the necessity of reduc­
    ing upwind States’ emissions enough to meet the NAAQS
    in other downwind States.” 
    696 F.3d 7
    , 22 (2012). More­
    over, the majority itself recognizes that the Good Neighbor
    Provision does not categorically prohibit over-control. “As
    the Good Neighbor Provision seeks attainment in every
    downwind State, . . . exceeding attainment in one State
    cannot rank as ‘over-control’ unless unnecessary to achiev­
    ing attainment in any downwind State.” Ante, at 29–30.
    The majority apparently fails to appreciate that, having
    cleared up that potential point of confusion, nothing
    stands in the way of the proportional-reduction approach.
    The majority relies on an EPA document preceding the
    Transport Rule to establish the Agency’s supposed belief
    that the proportional-reduction approach “could scarcely
    be satisfied in practice.” Ante, at 23. But the document
    says no such thing. Rather, it shows that the Agency
    rejected a proportion-based, “air[-]quality-only” methodol­
    ogy not because it was impossible of application, but be­
    10       EPA v. EME HOMER CITY GENERATION, L. P.
    SCALIA, J., dissenting
    cause it failed to account for costs. See App. in No. 11–
    1302 etc. (CADC), pp. 2311–2312. The document labels as
    a “technical difficulty” (not an impossibility) the fact that
    “most upwind states contribute to multiple downwind
    [receptors] (in multiple states) and would have a different
    reduction percentage for each one.” 
    Id., at 2312.
    The
    Clean Air Act is full of technical difficulties, and this one
    is overcome by requiring each State to make the greatest
    reduction necessary with respect to any downwind area.
    2. Over-Control
    Apparently conceding that the proportional-reduction
    approach may not be impossible of application after all,
    the majority alternatively asserts that it would cause
    “costly overregulation unnecessary to, indeed in conflict
    with, the Good Neighbor Provision’s goal of attainment.”
    Ante, at 24. This assertion of massive overregulation
    assumes that a vast number of downwind States will be
    the accidental beneficiaries of collateral pollution reduc­
    tions—that is, nontargeted reductions that occur as a
    consequence of required reductions targeted at neighbor­
    ing downwind States. (Collateral pollution reduction is
    the opposite of collateral damage, so to speak.) The major­
    ity contends that the collateral pollution reductions en­
    joyed by a downwind State will cause the required upwind
    reductions actually targeting that State to exceed the level
    necessary to assure attainment or maintenance, thus
    producing unnecessary over-control. I have no reason to
    believe that the problem of over-control is as extensive and
    thus “costly” as the majority alleges, and the majority
    provides none.
    But never mind that. It suffices to say that over-control
    is no more likely to occur when the required reductions are
    apportioned among upwind States on the basis of amounts
    of pollutants contributed than when they are apportioned
    on the basis of cost. There is no conceivable reason why
    Cite as: 572 U. S. ____ (2014)                 11
    SCALIA, J., dissenting
    the efficient-reduction States that bear the brunt of the
    majority’s (and EPA’s) approach are less likely to be over­
    controlled than the major-pollution-causing States that
    would bear the brunt of my (and the statute’s) approach.
    Indeed, EPA never attempted to establish that the
    Transport Rule did not produce gross over-control. 
    See 696 F.3d, at 27
    . What causes the problem of over-control
    is not the manner of apportioning the required reductions,
    but the composite volume of the required reductions in
    each downwind State. If the majority’s approach reduces
    over-control (it admittedly does not entirely eliminate it),
    that is only because EPA applies its cost-effectiveness
    principle not just to determining the proportions of re­
    quired reductions that each upwind State must bear, but
    to determining the volume of those required reductions.
    
    See supra, at 7
    .
    In any case, the solution to over-control under a propor­
    tional-reduction system is not difficult to discern. In
    calculating good-neighbor responsibilities, EPA would
    simply be required to make allowance for what I have
    called collateral pollution reductions. The Agency would
    set upwind States’ obligations at levels that, after taking
    into account those reductions, suffice to produce attain­
    ment in all downwind States. Doubtless, there are multi­
    ple ways for the Agency to accomplish that task in accord­
    ance with the statute’s amounts-based, proportional
    focus.2 The majority itself invokes an unexplained device
    to prevent over-control “in uncommon particular applica­
    tions” of its scheme. Ante, at 31. Whatever that device is,
    it can serve just as well to prevent over-control under the
    approach I have outlined.
    ——————
    2 The majority insists that “proportionality cannot be one of those
    ways.” Ante, at 25. But it is easy to imagine precluding unnecessary
    over-control by reducing in a percent-based manner the burdens of each
    upwind State linked to a given downwind area, which would retain the
    proportionality produced by my approach.
    12       EPA v. EME HOMER CITY GENERATION, L. P.
    SCALIA, J., dissenting
    I fully acknowledge that the proportional-reduction
    approach will demand some complicated computations
    where one upwind State is linked to multiple downwind
    States and vice versa. I am confident, however, that
    EPA’s skilled number-crunchers can adhere to the stat-
    ute’s quantitative (rather than efficiency) mandate by
    crafting quantitative solutions. Indeed, those calculations
    can be performed at the desk, whereas the “from each
    according to its ability” approach requires the unwieldy
    field examination of many pollution-producing sources
    with many sorts of equipment.
    D. Our Precedent
    The majority agrees with EPA’s assessment that
    “[u]sing costs in the Transport Rule calculus . . . makes
    good sense.” Ante, at 26. Its opinion declares that
    “[e]liminating those amounts that can cost-effectively be
    reduced is an efficient and equitable solution to the alloca-
    tion problem the Good Neighbor Provision requires the
    Agency to address.” 
    Ibid. Efficient, probably. Equitable?
    Perhaps so, but perhaps not. See Brief for Industry Re-
    spondents 35–36. But the point is that whether efficiency
    should have a dominant or subordinate role is for Con-
    gress, not this Court, to determine.
    This is not the first time parties have sought to convert
    the Clean Air Act into a mandate for cost-effective regula-
    tion. Whitman v. American Trucking Assns., Inc., 
    531 U.S. 457
    (2001), confronted the contention that EPA
    should consider costs in setting NAAQS. The provision at
    issue there, like this one, did not expressly bar cost-based
    decisionmaking—and unlike this one, it even contained
    words that were arguably ambiguous in the relevant
    respect. Specifically, §7409(b)(1) instructed EPA to set
    primary NAAQS “the attainment and maintenance of
    which . . . are requisite to protect the public health” with
    “an adequate margin of safety.” One could hardly over-
    Cite as: 572 U. S. ____ (2014)                  13
    SCALIA, J., dissenting
    state the capaciousness of the word “adequate,” and the
    phrase “public health” was at least equally susceptible
    (indeed, much more susceptible) of permitting cost-benefit
    analysis as the word “significantly” is here. As the re-
    spondents in American Trucking argued, setting NAAQS
    without considering costs may bring about failing indus-
    tries and fewer jobs, which in turn may produce poorer
    and less healthy citizens. See 
    id., at 466.
    But we conclud-
    ed that “in the context of ” the entire provision, that inter-
    pretation “ma[de] no sense.” 
    Ibid. As quoted earlier,
    we
    said that Congress “does not alter the fundamental details
    of a regulatory scheme in vague terms or ancillary provi-
    sions—it does not . . . hide elephants in mouseholes.” 
    Id., at 468.
       In American Trucking, the Court “refused to find im-
    plicit in ambiguous sections of the [Clear Air Act] an
    authorization to consider costs that has elsewhere, and so
    often, been expressly granted,” 
    id., at 467,
    citing a tradition
    dating back to Union Elec. Co. v. EPA, 
    427 U.S. 246
    , 257,
    and n. 5 (1976). There are, indeed, numerous Clean Air
    Act provisions explicitly permitting costs to be taken into
    account. See, e.g., §7404(a)(1); §7521(a)(2); §7545(c)(2);
    §7547(a)(3); §7554(b)(2); §7571(b); §7651c(f)(1)(A). Ameri-
    can Trucking thus demanded “a textual commitment of
    authority to the EPA to consider 
    costs,” 531 U.S., at 468
    —
    a hurdle that the Good Neighbor Provision comes nowhere
    close to clearing. Today’s opinion turns its back upon that
    case and is incompatible with that opinion.3
    ——————
    3 The   majority shrugs off American Trucking in a footnote, reasoning
    that because it characterized the provision there in question as “abso-
    lute,” it has nothing to say about the Good Neighbor Provision, which is
    not absolute. See ante, at 28, n. 21. This is a textbook example of
    begging the question: Since the Good Neighbor Provision is not absolute
    (the very point at issue here), American Trucking, which dealt with a
    provision that is absolute, is irrelevant. To the contrary, American
    Trucking is right on point. As described in text, the provision at issue
    14         EPA v. EME HOMER CITY GENERATION, L. P.
    SCALIA, J., dissenting
    II. Imposition of Federal Implementation Plans
    The D. C. Circuit vacated the Transport Rule for the
    additional reason that EPA took the reins in allocating
    emissions budgets among pollution-producing sources
    through Federal Implementation Plans (FIPs) without
    first providing the States a meaningful opportunity to
    perform that task through State Implementation Plans
    (SIPs). The majority rejects that ruling on the ground
    that “the Act does not require EPA to furnish upwind
    States with information of any kind about their good
    neighbor obligations before a FIP issues.” Ante, at 16.
    “[N]othing in the statute,” the majority says, “places EPA
    under an obligation to provide specific metrics to States
    before they undertake to fulfill their good neighbor obliga­
    tions.” Ante, at 17. This remarkably expansive reasoning
    makes a hash of the Clean Air Act, transforming it from a
    program based on cooperative federalism to one of central­
    ized federal control. Nothing in the Good Neighbor Provi­
    sion suggests such a stark departure from the Act’s fun­
    damental structure.
    A. Implications of State Regulatory Primacy
    Down to its very core, the Clean Air Act sets forth a
    federalism-focused regulatory strategy. The Act begins by
    declaring that “air pollution prevention (that is, the reduc­
    tion or elimination, through any measures, of the amount
    of pollutants produced or created at the source) and air
    pollution control at its source is the primary responsibility
    of States and local governments.” §7401(a)(3) (emphasis
    added). State primacy permeates Title I, which addresses
    the promulgation and implementation of NAAQS, in par­
    ticular. Under §7409(a), EPA must promulgate NAAQS
    for each pollutant for which air-quality criteria have been
    ——————
    here is even more categorical (“absolute”) than the provision at issue in
    American Trucking.
    Cite as: 572 U. S. ____ (2014)           15
    SCALIA, J., dissenting
    issued pursuant to §7408. Section 7410(a)(1), in turn,
    requires each State, usually within three years of each
    new or revised NAAQS, to submit a SIP providing for its
    “implementation, maintenance, and enforcement.” EPA
    may step in to take over that responsibility if, and only if,
    a State discharges it inadequately. Specifically, if the
    Agency finds that a State has failed to make a required or
    complete submission or disapproves a SIP, it “shall prom­
    ulgate a [FIP] at any time within 2 years . . . , unless the
    State corrects the deficiency, and [EPA] approves the [SIP]
    or [SIP] revision.” §7410(c)(1).
    To describe the effect of this statutory scheme in simple
    terms: After EPA sets numerical air-quality benchmarks,
    “Congress plainly left with the States . . . the power to
    determine which sources would be burdened by regulation
    and to what extent.” Union Elec. 
    Co., 427 U.S., at 269
    .
    The States are to present their chosen means of achieving
    EPA’s benchmarks in SIPs, and only if a SIP fails to meet
    those goals may the Agency commandeer a State’s author­
    ity by promulgating a FIP. “[S]o long as the ultimate
    effect of a State’s choice of emission limitations is compli­
    ance with the [NAAQS], the State is at liberty to adopt
    whatever mix of emission limitations it deems best suited
    to its particular situation.” Train v. Natural Resources
    Defense Council, Inc., 
    421 U.S. 60
    , 79 (1975). EPA, we
    have emphasized, “is relegated by the Act to a secondary
    role in the process of determining and enforcing the spe-
    cific, source-by-source emission limitations which are
    necessary if the [NAAQS] are to be met.” 
    Ibid. The Good Neighbor
    Provision is one of the requirements
    with which SIPs must comply. §7410(a)(2)(D)(i)(I). The
    statutory structure described above plainly demands that
    EPA afford States a meaningful opportunity to allocate
    reduction responsibilities among the sources within their
    borders. But the majority holds that EPA may in effect
    force the States to guess at what those responsibilities
    16        EPA v. EME HOMER CITY GENERATION, L. P.
    SCALIA, J., dissenting
    might be by requiring them to submit SIPs before learning
    what the Agency regards as a “significan[t]” contribu­
    tion—with the consequence of losing their regulatory
    primacy if they guess wrong. EPA asserts that the D. C.
    Circuit “was wrong as a factual matter” in reasoning that
    States cannot feasibly implement the Good Neighbor
    Provision without knowing what the Agency considers
    their obligations to be. Brief for Federal Petitioners 29.
    That is literally unbelievable. The only support that EPA
    can muster are the assertions that “States routinely un­
    dertake technically complex air quality determinations”
    and that “emissions information from all States is publicly
    available.” 
    Ibid. As respondents rightly
    state: “All the
    scientific knowledge in the world is useless if the States
    are left to guess the way in which EPA might ultimately
    quantify ‘significan[ce].’ ” Brief for State Respondents 50.
    Call it “punish[ing] the States for failing to meet a
    standard that EPA had not yet announced and [they] did
    not yet 
    know,” 696 F.3d, at 28
    ; asking them “to hit the
    target . . . before EPA defines [it],” 
    id., at 32;
    requiring
    them “to take [a] stab in the dark,” 
    id., at 35;
    or “set[ting]
    the States up to fail,” 
    id., at 37.
    Call it “hid[ing] the ball,”
    Brief for State Respondents 20; or a “shell game,” 
    id., at 54.
    	 Call it “pin the tail on the donkey.” Tr. of Oral Arg.
    24. 	As we have recently explained:
    “It is one thing to expect regulated parties to conform
    their conduct to an agency’s interpretations once the
    agency announces them; it is quite another to require
    regulated parties to divine the agency’s interpre­
    tations in advance or else be held liable when the
    agency announces its interpretations for the first
    time . . . and demands deference.” Christopher v.
    SmithKline Beecham Corp., 567 U. S. ___, ___ (2012)
    (slip op., at 14).
    That principle applies a fortiori to a regulatory regime
    Cite as: 572 U. S. ____ (2014)           17
    SCALIA, J., dissenting
    that rests on principles of cooperative federalism.
    B. Past EPA Practice
    EPA itself has long acknowledged the proposition that it
    is nonsensical to expect States to comply with the Good
    Neighbor Provision absent direction about what consti­
    tutes a “significan[t]” contribution to interstate pollution.
    The Agency consistently adopted that position prior to
    the Transport Rule. In 1998, when it issued the NOX SIP
    Call under §7410(k)(5), EPA acknowledged that “[w]ithout
    determining an acceptable level of NOX reductions, the
    upwind State would not have guidance as to what is an
    acceptable submission.” 63 Fed. Reg. 57370. EPA deemed
    it “most efficient—indeed necessary—for the Federal
    government to establish the overall emissions levels for
    the various States.” 
    Ibid. Accordingly, the Agency
    quanti­
    fied good-neighbor responsibilities and then allowed
    States a year to submit SIPs to implement them. 
    Id., at 57450–57451.
       Similarly, when EPA issued the Clean Air Interstate
    Rule (CAIR) in 2005 under §7410(c), it explicitly “recog­
    nize[d] that States would face great difficulties in develop­
    ing transport SIPs to meet the requirements of today’s
    action without th[e] data and policies” provided by the
    Rule, including “judgments from EPA concerning the
    appropriate criteria for determining whether upwind
    sources contribute significantly to downwind nonattain­
    ment under [§74]10(a)(2)(D).” 70 
    id., at 25268–25269.
    The Agency thus gave the States 18 months to submit
    SIPs implementing their new good-neighbor responsibili­
    ties. See 
    id., at 25166–25167,
    25176. Although EPA
    published FIPs before that window closed, it specified that
    they were meant to serve only as a “Federal backstop” and
    would not become effective unless necessary “a year after
    the CAIR SIP submission deadline.” 71 
    id., at 25330–
    25331 (2006).
    18          EPA v. EME HOMER CITY GENERATION, L. P.
    SCALIA, J., dissenting
    Even since promulgating the Transport Rule, EPA has
    repeatedly reaffirmed that States cannot be expected to
    read the Agency’s mind. In other proceedings, EPA has
    time and again stated that although “[s]ome of the ele­
    ments of the [SIP-submission process] are relatively
    straightforward, . . . others clearly require interpretation
    by EPA through rulemaking, or recommendations through
    guidance, in order to give specific meaning for a particular
    NAAQS.” 76 
    id., at 58751
    (2011). As an example of the
    latter, the Agency has remarked that the Good Neighbor
    Provision “contains numerous terms that require substan­
    tial rulemaking by EPA in order to determine such basic
    points as what constitutes significant contribution,” citing
    CAIR. Ibid., n. 6. In fact, EPA repeated those precise
    statements not once, not twice, but 30 times following
    promulgation of the Transport Rule.4
    Notwithstanding what parties may have argued in other
    litigation many years ago, it is beyond responsible debate
    that the States cannot possibly design FIP-proof SIPs
    without knowing the EPA-prescribed targets at which
    they must aim. EPA insists that it enjoys significant
    discretion—indeed, that it can consider essentially what­
    ever factors it wishes—to determine what constitutes a
    “significan[t]” contribution to interstate pollution; and it
    simultaneously asserts that the States ought to know
    what quantities it will choose. The Agency—and the
    ——————
    4 In  addition to the citations in text, see 77 Fed. Reg. 50654, and n. 7
    (2012); 
    id., at 47577,
    and n. 7; 
    id., at 46363,
    and n. 7; 
    id., at 46356,
    and
    n. 9; 
    id., at 45323,
    and n. 7; 
    id., at 43199,
    and n. 7; 
    id., at 38241,
    and
    n. 6; 
    id., at 35912,
    and n. 7; 
    id., at 34909,
    and n. 7; 
    id., at 34901,
    and n.
    8; 
    id., at 34310,
    and n. 7; 
    id., at 34291,
    and n. 8; 
    id., at 33384,
    and n. 7;
    
    id., at 33375,
    and n. 7; 
    id., at 23184,
    and n. 7; 
    id., at 22543,
    and n. 4;
    
    id., at 22536,
    and n. 7; 
    id., at 22253,
    and n. 8; 
    id., at 21915,
    and n. 7;
    
    id., at 21706,
    and n. 6; 
    id., at 16788,
    and n. 4; 
    id., at 13241,
    and n. 5;
    
    id., at 6715,
    and n. 7; 
    id., at 6047,
    and n. 4; 
    id., at 3216,
    and n. 7; 76 
    id., at 77955,
    and n. 7 (2011); 
    id., at 75852,
    and n. 7; 
    id., at 70943,
    and n. 6;
    
    id., at 62636,
    and n. 3.
    Cite as: 572 U. S. ____ (2014)                   19
    SCALIA, J., dissenting
    majority—cannot have it both ways.
    C. Abuse of Discretion
    The majority attempts to place the blame for hollowing
    out the core of the Clean Air Act on “the Act’s plain text.”
    Ante, at 16. The first textual element to which it refers is
    §7410(c)’s requirement that after EPA has disapproved a
    SIP, it “shall promulgate a [FIP] at any time within 2
    years.” That is to say, the Agency has discretion whether
    to act at once or to defer action until some later point
    during the 2-year period. But it also has discretion to
    work within the prescribed timetable to respect the right­
    ful role of States in the statutory scheme by delaying the
    issuance or enforcement of FIPs pending the resubmission
    and approval of SIPs—as EPA’s conduct surrounding
    CAIR clearly demonstrates. And all of this assumes that
    the Agency insists on disapproving SIPs before promulgat­
    ing the applicable good-neighbor standards—though in
    fact EPA has discretion to publicize those metrics before
    the window to submit SIPs closes in the first place.
    The majority states that the Agency “retained discretion
    to alter its course” from the one pursued in the NOX SIP
    Call and CAIR, ante, at 17, but that misses the point.
    The point is that EPA has discretion to arrange things so
    as to preserve the Clean Air Act’s core principle of state
    primacy—and that it is an abuse of discretion to refuse to
    do so. See §7607(d)(9)(A); see also 
    5 U.S. C
    . §706(2)(A)
    (identical text in the Administrative Procedure Act).
    Indeed, the proviso in §7410(c)(1) that the Agency’s au­
    thority to promulgate a FIP within the 2-year period
    terminates if “the State corrects the deficiency, and [EPA]
    approves the [SIP] or [SIP] revision” explicitly contem­
    plates just such an arrangement.5
    ——————
    5 I am unimpressed, by the way, with the explanation that the major-
    ity accepts for EPA’s about-face: that the D. C. Circuit admonished it to
    “act with dispatch in amending or replacing CAIR.” Ante, at 18 (citing
    20         EPA v. EME HOMER CITY GENERATION, L. P.
    SCALIA, J., dissenting
    The majority’s conception of administrative discretion is
    so sprawling that it would allow EPA to subvert state
    primacy not only with respect to the interstate-pollution
    concerns of the Good Neighbor Provision, but with respect
    to the much broader concerns of the NAAQS program
    more generally. States must submit SIPs “within 3 years”
    of each new or revised NAAQS “or such shorter period as
    [EPA] may prescribe.” §7410(a)(1) (emphasis added).
    Because there is no principled reason to read that schedul­
    ing provision in a less malleable manner than the one at
    issue here, under the majority’s view EPA could demand
    that States submit SIPs within a matter of days—or even
    hours—after a NAAQS publication or else face the imme­
    diate imposition of FIPs.
    The second element of “plain text” on which the majority
    relies is small beer indeed. The Good Neighbor Provision
    does not expressly state that EPA must publish target
    quantities before the States are required to submit SIPs—
    even though the Clean Air Act does so for NAAQS more
    generally and for vehicle inspection and maintenance
    programs, see §7511a(c)(3)(B). From that premise, the
    majority reasons that “[h]ad Congress intended similarly
    to defer States’ discharge of their obligations under the
    Good Neighbor Provision, Congress . . . would have included
    a similar direction in that section.” Ante, at 17. Per­
    haps so. But EPA itself read the statute differently when
    it declared in the NOX SIP Call that “[d]etermining the
    overall level of air pollutants allowed to be emitted in a
    State is comparable to determining [NAAQS], which the
    courts have recognized as EPA’s responsibility, and is
    ——————
    North Carolina v. EPA, 
    550 F.3d 1176
    , 1178 (2008) (per curiam)).
    Courts of Appeals’ raised eyebrows and wagging fingers are not law,
    least so when they urge an agency to take ultra vires action. Nor can
    the encouragement to act illegally qualify as a “good reaso[n]” for an
    agency’s alteration of course under FCC v. Fox Television Stations, Inc.,
    
    556 U.S. 502
    , 515 (2009).
    Cite as: 572 U. S. ____ (2014)           21
    SCALIA, J., dissenting
    distinguishable from determining the particular mix of
    controls among individual sources to attain those stand­
    ards, which the caselaw identifies as a State responsibil­
    ity.” 63 Fed. Reg. 57369 (emphasis added).
    The negative implication suggested by a statute’s failure
    to use consistent terminology can be a helpful guide to
    determining meaning, especially when all the provisions
    in question were enacted at the same time (which is not
    the case here). But because that interpretive canon, like
    others, is just one clue to aid construction, it can be over­
    come by more powerful indications of meaning elsewhere
    in the statute. It is, we have said, “no more than a rule of
    thumb that can tip the scales when a statute could be read
    in multiple ways.” Sebelius v. Auburn Regional Medical
    Center, 568 U. S. ___, ___ (2013) (slip op., at 9) (internal
    quotation marks and brackets omitted). The Clean Air
    Act simply cannot be read to make EPA the primary regu­
    lator in this context. The negative-implication canon is
    easily overcome by the statute’s state-respecting struc­
    ture—not to mention the sheer impossibility of submitting
    a sensible SIP without EPA guidance. Negative implica­
    tion is the tiniest mousehole in which the majority discov­
    ers the elephant of federal control.
    *      *    *
    Addressing the problem of interstate pollution in the
    manner Congress has prescribed—or in any other manner,
    for that matter—is a complex and difficult enterprise. But
    “[r]egardless of how serious the problem an administrative
    agency seeks to address, . . . it may not exercise its author­
    ity ‘in a manner that is inconsistent with the administra­
    tive structure that Congress enacted into law.’ ” Brown &
    
    Williamson, 529 U.S., at 125
    (quoting ETSI Pipeline
    Project v. Missouri, 
    484 U.S. 495
    , 517 (1988)). The major­
    ity’s approval of EPA’s approach to the Clean Air Act
    violates this foundational principle of popular government.
    I dissent.
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 12–1182; 12–1183.

Citation Numbers: 188 L. Ed. 2d 775, 134 S. Ct. 1584, 2014 U.S. LEXIS 3108, 572 U.S. 489

Judges: Ginsburg

Filed Date: 4/29/2014

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 10/19/2024

Authorities (17)

United States v. Mead Corp. , 121 S. Ct. 2164 ( 2001 )

ETSI Pipeline Project v. Missouri , 108 S. Ct. 805 ( 1988 )

Whitman v. American Trucking Assns., Inc. , 121 S. Ct. 903 ( 2001 )

MCI Telecommunications Corp. v. American Telephone & ... , 114 S. Ct. 2223 ( 1994 )

Chevron U. S. A. Inc. v. Natural Resources Defense Council, ... , 104 S. Ct. 2778 ( 1984 )

Food & Drug Administration v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco ... , 120 S. Ct. 1291 ( 2000 )

Motor Vehicle Mfrs. Assn. of United States, Inc. v. State ... , 103 S. Ct. 2856 ( 1983 )

state-of-michigan-michigan-department-of-environmental-quality-and-state , 213 F.3d 663 ( 2000 )

United States v. Detroit Timber & Lumber Co. , 26 S. Ct. 282 ( 1906 )

Federal Communications Commission v. Fox Television ... , 129 S. Ct. 1800 ( 2009 )

Kontrick v. Ryan , 124 S. Ct. 906 ( 2004 )

Train v. Natural Resources Defense Council, Inc. , 95 S. Ct. 1470 ( 1975 )

American Hospital Ass'n v. National Labor Relations Board , 111 S. Ct. 1539 ( 1991 )

Babbitt v. Sweet Home Chapter, Communities for Great Ore. , 115 S. Ct. 2407 ( 1995 )

Arbaugh v. Y & H Corp. , 126 S. Ct. 1235 ( 2006 )

North Carolina v. Environmental Protection Agency , 531 F.3d 896 ( 2008 )

United States v. Shimer , 81 S. Ct. 1554 ( 1961 )

View All Authorities »

Cited By (50)

Sierra Club v. McCarthy ( 2018 )

Club v. United States Environmental Protection Agency , 2015 FED App. 0149P ( 2015 )

National Parks Conservation Ass'n v. United States ... , 803 F.3d 151 ( 2015 )

Nebraska v. United States EPA , 812 F.3d 662 ( 2016 )

National Parks Conservation Ass'n v. McCarthy , 816 F.3d 989 ( 2016 )

Helping Hand Tools v. U.S. Environmental Protection Agency , 836 F.3d 999 ( 2016 )

King Soopers, Inc. v. National Labor Relations Board , 859 F.3d 23 ( 2017 )

Marlow v. The New Food Guy, Inc. , 861 F.3d 1157 ( 2017 )

G.L. v. Ligonier Valley School District Authority , 802 F.3d 601 ( 2015 )

St. Marys Cement Inc. v. United States Environmental ... , 2015 FED App. 0054P ( 2015 )

National Parks Conservation Ass'n v. McCarthy , 811 F.3d 1005 ( 2016 )

Helping Hand Tools v. Usepa ( 2016 )

In re Application of Maui Electric Company, Limited. ( 2017 )

Util. Air Regulatory Grp. v. Envtl. Prot. Agency , 885 F.3d 714 ( 2018 )

Natural Res. Def. Council v. Envtl. Prot. Agency , 896 F.3d 459 ( 2018 )

R. Acosta, Secretary, LABR v. Hensel Phelps Constr , 909 F.3d 723 ( 2018 )

Foster v. Mabus , 103 F. Supp. 3d 95 ( 2015 )

Sierra Club v. United States Environmental Protection Agency ( 2016 )

New York State Citizens' Coalition for Children v. Poole ( 2019 )

National Security Counselors v. Central Intelligence Agency ( 2016 )

View All Citing Opinions »