Anaheim Gardens v. United States ( 2018 )


Menu:
  •            In the United States Court of Federal Claims
    No. 93-655C
    (E-Filed: September 25, 2018)
    )       Regulatory Takings Claims; Motion
    ANAHEIM GARDENS, et al.,              )       for Summary Judgment, RCFC 56;
    )       Right to Pre-Pay Mortgages on
    Plaintiffs,                  )       Subsidized Low-Income Housing
    )       Developments; No Reasonable
    v.                                    )       Investment-Backed Expectation in a
    )       Property Right Destroyed Prior to
    THE UNITED STATES,                    )       Purchase of Property; Insufficient
    )       Evidence of Economic Impact to
    Defendant.                   )       Support a Permanent Regulatory
    )       Taking.
    Harry J. Kelly, Washington, DC, for plaintiffs.
    A. Bondurant Eley, Senior Trial Counsel, with whom were Joseph H. Hunt, Assistant
    Attorney General, Robert E. Kirschman, Jr., Director, Franklin E. White, Jr., Assistant
    Director, Christopher J. Carney, Senior Litigation Counsel, Isaac B. Rosenberg and Kara
    M. Westercamp, Trial Attorneys, Commercial Litigation Branch, Civil Division, United
    States Department of Justice, Washington, DC, for defendant.
    OPINION AND ORDER
    CAMPBELL-SMITH, Judge.
    The court has before it defendant’s motion for summary judgment, ECF No. 422,
    which has been extensively briefed.1 Defendant’s motion is brought pursuant to Rule 56
    1
    The following briefs and appendices have been considered by the court:
    (1) defendant’s motion for summary judgment, ECF No. 422; defendant’s proposed
    findings of uncontroverted fact, ECF No. 423; defendant’s appendix, ECF No. 423-1;
    plaintiffs’ opposition brief, ECF No. 439; plaintiffs’ response to defendant’s proposed
    findings of uncontroverted fact, ECF No. 440; plaintiffs’ appendix, ECF No. 441-1
    through 441-4; defendant’s reply brief, ECF No. 459; defendant’s supplemental summary
    judgment brief, ECF No. 477; plaintiffs’ supplemental opposition brief, ECF No. 479;
    and, defendant’s supplemental reply brief, ECF No. 482.
    of the Rules of the United States Court of Federal Claims (RCFC). Oral argument was
    requested by plaintiffs but is deemed to be unnecessary by the court.2 Defendant’s
    motion is GRANTED. In consequence, the parties’ pending motions in limine regarding
    expert trial testimony, ECF Nos. 430, 452, are DENIED as moot.
    I.     Background
    This case has a long history; much of the pertinent procedural background of this
    dispute may be found in Anaheim Gardens v. United States, 
    125 Fed. Cl. 88
    (2016)
    (Anaheim). There are approximately fifty plaintiffs asserting takings claims in these
    consolidated cases.3 
    Id. at 94.
    Currently the parties are preparing for trial on the claims
    of the First Wave Plaintiffs (FWPs). 
    Id. at 94-95.
    The list of FWPs was finalized on
    September 30, 2013, ECF No. 332, and discovery proceeded as to these plaintiffs shortly
    thereafter. Thus, the parties have had approximately five years to prepare for trial on the
    regulatory takings claims of the FWPs.
    The six FWPs are Buckman Gardens L.P., Chauncy House Company, Cedar
    Gardens Associates, Rock Creek Terrace L.P., 620 Su Casa Por Cortez, and 3740
    Silverlake Village, L.P.4 
    Anaheim, 125 Fed. Cl. at 95
    . All of the FWPs assert takings
    2
    Plaintiffs requested oral argument not in their opposition brief in the first round of
    briefing defendant’s motion, but in their second opposition brief submitted during a
    round of supplemental briefing ordered by the court. See ECF No. 479 at 1. At that
    point, however, the parties had been fully heard on every necessary issue. The court
    notes, too, that plaintiffs submitted a thorough supplemental opposition brief. ECF No.
    479. Plaintiffs were afforded six weeks, overall, to prepare that brief after the court’s
    briefing order issued, ECF No. 470, and two weeks to respond, in particular, to
    defendant’s arguments in its supplemental summary judgment brief.
    3
    These plaintiffs were originally grouped into two multi-plaintiff cases, Anaheim
    Gardens, et al. v. United States, Case No. 93-655, and Algonquin Heights Associates, et
    al. v. United States, Case No. 97-582. When those cases were consolidated, all plaintiffs,
    except the named plaintiffs, were assigned individual case numbers and were terminated
    from the multi-plaintiff cases. See Order of April 30, 2013, ECF No. 327. All of the
    subsequent history of this case, however, is docketed in the lead case, Case No. 93-655.
    
    Id. 4 The
    six FWPs are docketed, 
    see supra
    note 3, in the following cases: (1) Buckman
    Gardens L.P., et al. v. United States, Case No. 97-5837, which includes both the
    partnership and the individual partners as plaintiffs; Chauncy House Company v. United
    States, Case No. 97-5845; Cedar Gardens Associates v. United States, Case No. 93-6568;
    Rock Creek Terrace L.P. v. United States, Case No. 93-6578; 620 Su Casa Por Cortez v.
    United States, Case No. 93-6580; and Silverlake Village, L.P. v. United States, Case No.
    93-6582. The docket in Case No. 93-6582 incorrectly identifies the plaintiff as Silverlake
    2
    claims based on the enactment of the “Preservation Statutes,” which affected their
    mortgage prepayment rights for government loans on subsidized apartment complexes.
    The relevant statutes are identified in the following excerpt from Anaheim:
    Plaintiffs allege that the enactment of two federal statutes, the Emergency
    Low Income Housing Preservation Act of 1987, Pub. L. No. 100-242, § 202,
    101 Stat. 1877 (1988) (ELIHPA), and the Low-Income Housing Preservation
    and Resident Homeownership Act of 1990, Pub. L. No. 101-625, 104 Stat.
    4249 (1990) (LIHPRHA), collectively known as the Preservation Statutes,
    prevented them from exercising their contractual right to repay their
    mortgages upon the twentieth anniversary of the issuance of the mortgage.
    Plaintiffs’ prepayment rights were later restored by a third federal statute, the
    Housing Opportunity Program Extension Act of 1996 (Hope Act [or HOPE
    Act]), Pub. L. No. 104-120, 110 Stat. 834 (1996).
    125 Fed. Cl at 93-94.
    The parties agree that the court’s analysis of the regulatory takings alleged by the
    FWPs is governed by Penn Central Transportation Co. v. New York City, 
    438 U.S. 104
    (1978) (Penn Central). As summarized by the United States Court of Appeals for the
    Federal Circuit, the three Penn Central factors are: (1) “‘[t]he economic impact of the
    regulation on the claimant’”; (2) “‘the extent to which the regulation has interfered with
    distinct investment-backed expectations’”; and (3) “‘the character of the governmental
    action.’” CCA Assocs. v. United States, 
    667 F.3d 1239
    , 1244 (Fed. Cir. 2011) (CCA
    Associates II) (quoting Penn 
    Central, 438 U.S. at 124
    ) (alteration in original). Most of
    the court’s inquiry here will focus on the investment-backed expectations and economic
    impact prongs of the Penn Central test.
    Two preliminary issues, however, were raised by the court in its order requiring
    supplemental briefing from the parties.5 ECF No. 470. First, the court required more
    Village, L.P., not 3740 Silverlake Village, L.P., although the court, in its opinion of
    October 2, 2014, found that the proper plaintiff in that case is 3740 Silverlake Village,
    L.P. See ECF No. 374 at 12 (“Plaintiffs may file a sixth amended complaint designating
    3740 Silverlake Village, L.P. as the named plaintiff pursuing a takings claim based on the
    Silverlake Village Apartments.”); ECF No. 376 at 3 (correcting the name of 3740
    Silverlake Village, L.P. in the sixth amended complaint filed in this lead case); ECF No.
    412 at 3 (showing the correct plaintiff name in the seventh amended complaint filed in
    this lead case).
    5
    Plaintiffs argue that these two issues were waived by defendant. ECF No. 479 at
    10 n.3. The court does not agree. The court ordered supplemental briefing on the two
    3
    robust briefing concerning the “reasonable investment-backed expectations” of plaintiff
    620 Su Casa Por Cortez, whose purchase of the subject property occurred after the
    enactment of the Preservation Statutes. 
    Id. at 2.
    Second, the court required additional
    briefing from the parties addressing the question of whether the takings alleged by the
    FWPs are more properly characterized as temporary regulatory takings, or as permanent
    regulatory takings. 
    Id. at 2-3.
    The analysis section of this opinion will discuss these two
    topics before reviewing the arguments raised in defendant’s motion for summary
    judgment. Before turning to its analysis, however, the court addresses the standard of
    review that is applicable to defendant’s motion.
    II.    Standard of Review
    “[S]ummary judgment is a salutary method of disposition designed to secure the
    just, speedy and inexpensive determination of every action.” Sweats Fashions, Inc. v.
    Pannill Knitting Co., 
    833 F.2d 1560
    , 1562 (Fed. Cir. 1987) (internal quotations and
    citations omitted). The party moving for summary judgment will prevail “if the movant
    shows that there is no genuine dispute as to any material fact and the movant is entitled to
    judgment as a matter of law.” RCFC 56(a). “[A]ll evidence must be viewed in the light
    most favorable to the nonmoving party, and all reasonable factual inferences should be
    drawn in favor of the nonmoving party.” Dairyland Power Coop. v. United States, 
    16 F.3d 1197
    , 1202 (Fed. Cir. 1994) (citations omitted).
    A genuine dispute of material fact is one that could “affect the outcome” of the
    litigation. Anderson v. Liberty Lobby, Inc., 
    477 U.S. 242
    , 248 (1986). “The moving
    party . . . need not produce evidence showing the absence of a genuine issue of material
    fact but rather may discharge its burden by showing the court that there is an absence of
    evidence to support the nonmoving party’s case.” Dairyland 
    Power, 16 F.3d at 1202
    (citing Celotex Corp. v. Catrett, 
    477 U.S. 317
    , 325 (1986)). A summary judgment
    motion is properly granted against a party who fails to make a showing sufficient to
    establish the existence of an essential element to that party’s case and for which that party
    bears the burden of proof at trial. 
    Celotex, 477 U.S. at 324
    .
    The United States Supreme Court has instructed that “the mere existence of some
    alleged factual dispute between the parties will not defeat an otherwise properly
    supported motion for summary judgment; the requirement is that there be no genuine
    issue of material fact.” 
    Anderson, 477 U.S. at 247-48
    . A nonmovant will not defeat a
    motion for summary judgment “unless there is sufficient evidence favoring the
    nonmoving party for [the fact-finder] to return a verdict for that party.” 
    Id. at 249
    (citation omitted). “A nonmoving party’s failure of proof concerning the existence of an
    element essential to its case on which the nonmoving party will bear the burden of proof
    issues, which are fundamental to plaintiffs’ takings claims. The court deemed it more
    efficient to address these issues in supplemental briefing prior to trial.
    4
    at trial necessarily renders all other facts immaterial and entitles the moving party to
    summary judgment as a matter of law.” Dairyland 
    Power, 16 F.3d at 1202
    (citing
    
    Celotex, 477 U.S. at 323
    ).
    III.   Analysis
    A.     Challenge Specific to Plaintiff 620 Su Casa Por Cortez
    1.      No Reasonable Investment-Backed Expectation in a Mortgage
    Prepayment Right Once LIHPRHA Was Enacted
    The government argues that 620 Su Casa Por Cortez did not have reasonable
    investment-backed expectations in a mortgage prepayment right, because the subject
    property was purchased after LIHPRHA went into effect.6 See ECF No. 477 at 11-14.
    As the Federal Circuit has stated:
    The purchaser who buys a parcel with a known and valid regulatory
    restriction on certain uses cannot complain that she thereafter sustains an
    economic loss when the restriction is enforced. If the purchaser paid more
    than the property with the restriction on it is worth, the loss is the result of an
    error in market judgment, not a result of the restriction as such. In the
    parlance of takings law, the purchaser does not have reasonable expectations
    that the property can be used for the prohibited purpose; to assess the
    government for such a loss is to give the purchaser a windfall to which she
    is not entitled.
    Palm Beach Isles Assocs. v. United States, 
    231 F.3d 1354
    , 1363 (Fed. Cir. 2000).
    A similar statement of the law was provided in an earlier case:
    In legal terms, the owner who bought with knowledge of the restraint could
    be said to have no reliance interest, or to have assumed the risk of any
    economic loss. In economic terms, it could be said that the market had
    6
    In its supplemental reply brief, defendant appears to have abandoned its standing
    challenge to the takings claim of 620 Su Casa Por Cortez. ECF No. 482 at 5. Even if
    defendant has not done so, the court agrees with plaintiffs, for the reasons stated in their
    supplemental opposition brief, that 620 Su Casa Por Cortez has the requisite standing for
    its takings claim. See ECF No. 479 at 11-12 (arguing that LIHPRHA takings claims
    accrue not on the statute’s enactment date, but on the property’s mortgage prepayment
    date); see also Cienega Gardens v. United States, 
    503 F.3d 1266
    , 1287-88 & n.20 (Fed.
    Cir. 2007) (Cienega X) (describing the alleged takings periods in that case as starting on
    the properties’ mortgage prepayment dates).
    5
    already discounted for the restraint, so that a purchaser could not show a loss
    in his investment attributable to it.
    Loveladies Harbor, Inc. v. United States, 
    28 F.3d 1171
    , 1177 (Fed. Cir. 1994), abrogated
    on other grounds as noted in Bass Enters. Prod. Co. v. United States, 
    381 F.3d 1360
    (Fed.
    Cir. 2004) (Bass Enterprises).
    As the Federal Circuit explained more recently: “The purpose of consideration of
    plaintiffs’ investment-backed expectations is to limit recoveries to property owners who
    can demonstrate that ‘they bought their property in reliance on a state of affairs that did
    not include the challenged regulatory regime.’” Cienega Gardens v. United States, 
    331 F.3d 1319
    , 1345-46 (Fed. Cir. 2003) (Cienega VIII) (citing Loveladies 
    Harbor, 28 F.3d at 1177
    ); see also Norman v. United States, 
    429 F.3d 1081
    , 1093 (Fed. Cir. 2005) (stating
    that because the plaintiffs in that suit “were not only constructively but also actually
    aware of the applicable wetland restrictions, . . . [t]hey could not have made those
    purchases in reliance on a ‘state of affairs’ that did not include those restrictions”)
    (citations omitted). Further, acknowledging the guidance provided by Palazzolo v.
    Rhode Island, 
    533 U.S. 606
    (2001), the Federal Circuit has commented that “it is
    particularly difficult to establish a reasonable investment-backed expectation in
    circumstances like these [where actual knowledge of the restriction predated the real
    estate purchase].” 
    Norman, 429 F.3d at 1092-93
    (citing 
    Palazzolo, 533 U.S. at 630
    ).
    Plaintiffs argue that because the regulations implementing LIHPRHA had not been
    finalized at the time 620 Su Casa Por Cortez purchased the subject property, an investor
    would still retain reasonable investment-backed expectations in the mortgage prepayment
    right. ECF No. 479 at 9-10. But the statute itself was sufficiently detailed to destroy any
    reasonable expectation as to the free exercise of the prepayment right. See Cienega
    Gardens v. United States, 
    503 F.3d 1266
    , 1272-73 & n.4 (Fed. Cir. 2007) (Cienega X)
    (discussing the extensive conditions placed on the mortgage prepayment right by
    numerous provisions of LIHPRHA); see also ECF No. 482 at 9-10 (citing LIHPRHA
    provisions restricting the mortgage prepayment right). Further, plaintiffs have asserted
    that the FWPs were sophisticated investors in low-income housing properties, in general,
    ECF No. 439 at 30-35, and that the investors in 620 Su Casa Por Cortez had a particular
    focus on the mortgage prepayment right, 
    id. at 34-35.
    The statute gave such investors
    adequate notice of the effects of LIHPRHA on the prepayment right. Defendant notes,
    too, that plaintiffs’ briefing in the “ripeness” phase of this litigation indicates that the
    FWPs knew of the effects of LIHPRHA on the FWPs’ mortgage prepayment right at the
    time that statute was enacted. ECF No. 482 at 11-13. Plaintiffs’ reliance on the absence
    of finalized regulations to claim that 620 Su Casa Por Cortez did not know the impact of
    LIHPRHA on the mortgage prepayment right, ECF No. 479 at 9-10, is unavailing.
    Here, 620 Su Casa Por Cortez could not possess reasonable investment-backed
    expectations in a mortgage prepayment right. Plaintiff 620 Su Casa Por Cortez purchased
    the subject property after LIHPRHA had destroyed the prepayment right that would
    6
    otherwise have been available to the owner of that property under the terms of the
    underlying agreements with the United States Department of Housing and Urban
    Development (HUD). Applying Palazzolo, Norman, Cienega VIII, Palm Beach Isles, and
    Loveladies Harbor to the circumstances of this case, the sophisticated investors in the 620
    Su Casa Por Cortez partnership could not have relied on a regime in which the
    prepayment right existed. As a result, 620 Su Casa Por Cortez did not have reasonable
    investment-backed expectations in the property right alleged to have been taken by the
    government here. As to this prong of the Penn Central analysis for the takings claim of
    620 Su Casa Por Cortez, there is no genuine dispute of material fact.
    2.     In the Absence of Any Reasonable Investment-Backed Expectations,
    the Regulatory Takings Claim of 620 Su Casa Por Cortez Must Be
    Dismissed
    Plaintiffs argue that the takings claim of 620 Su Casa Por Cortez must survive
    summary judgment even if the court should find that the investment-backed expectations
    factor weighs against this claim. ECF No. 479 at 22-23. Plaintiffs’ argument is largely
    based on Murr v. Wisconsin, 
    137 S. Ct. 1933
    (2017). ECF No. 479 at 22-23. Defendant
    argues, and the court must agree, that Murr cannot save the takings claim of 620 Su Casa
    Por Cortez. ECF No. 477 at 13-14.
    Although there is language in Murr which suggests that a regulatory takings
    analysis under Penn Central must be 
    “flexible,” 137 S. Ct. at 1943
    , there is no statement
    in Murr which precludes this court from dismissing a takings claim where there is no
    reasonable investment-backed expectation in the free exercise of a property right.
    Indeed, the Court in Murr held that a regulatory takings claim was properly dismissed, at
    least in part, because the owners had purchased the property after the complained-of
    regulatory restrictions were already in place. See 
    id. at 1949
    (“Petitioners cannot claim
    that they reasonably expected to sell or develop their lots separately given the regulations
    which predated their acquisition of both lots.”).
    The court notes, too, that the Federal Circuit has expressly stated that the absence
    of reasonable investment-backed expectations may be sufficient cause to dismiss a
    regulatory takings claim. See 
    Norman, 429 F.3d at 1094
    (citing Ruckelshaus v.
    Monsanto Co., 
    467 U.S. 986
    , 1005 (1984) (Monsanto); Golden Pac. Bankcorp. v. United
    States, 
    15 F.3d 1066
    , 1074 (Fed. Cir. 1994) (Golden Pacific)). And, while there may be
    cases of extraordinary government action that excuse the absence of reasonable
    investment-backed expectations, see 
    id. at 1094
    n.6 (citing Hodel v. Irving, 
    481 U.S. 704
    ,
    714 (1987)), the court sees no such extraordinary action in the enactment of the
    7
    Preservation Statutes.7 Here, the regulatory takings claim of 620 Su Casa Por Cortez is
    unsupported by reasonable investment-backed expectations and must be dismissed.
    Plaintiffs also argue that two Supreme Court cases preclude a grant of summary
    judgment on a regulatory takings claim where the character of the government action has
    “result[ed] in the abrogation of a fundamental property right.” ECF No. 439 at 15 (citing
    Hodel and Kaiser Aetna v. United States, 
    444 U.S. 164
    (1979)). Turning first to Kaiser,
    two decisions of this court, affirmed in relevant part on appeal, have rejected similar
    contentions that Kaiser is analogous to the regulatory takings claims at issue in those
    suits. See CCA Assocs. v. United States, 
    91 Fed. Cl. 580
    , 599-601 (2010) (CCA
    Associates I), aff’d in relevant part, 
    667 F.3d 1239
    (Fed. Cir. 2011); Norman v. United
    States, 
    63 Fed. Cl. 231
    , 248 (2004), aff’d, 
    429 F.3d 1081
    (Fed. Cir. 2005). As for Hodel,
    it was the “extraordinary” character of the governmental action and the strength of the
    economic impact factor which excused an absence of reasonable investment-backed
    expectations in that case. See 
    Norman, 429 F.3d at 1094
    n.6 (citing 
    Hodel, 481 U.S. at 714
    ); see also CCA Associates 
    I, 91 Fed. Cl. at 600-01
    (distinguishing Hodel from the
    regulatory takings that were alleged to have occurred as a result of the enactment of the
    Preservation Statutes). The court must agree with defendant, ECF No. 459 at 9 n.1, that
    Hodel and Kaiser are inapposite to the takings claims at issue in this case and to
    defendant’s motion for summary judgment.
    Plaintiffs’ broadest argument is that the Penn Central test is fundamentally
    incompatible with the dismissal of a regulatory takings claim, on summary judgment,
    where only one of the Penn Central factors has been considered to be dispositive by the
    court. ECF No. 439 at 11, 39-41. As the court reads the Federal Circuit’s decision in
    Norman, however, dismissal of a takings claim is indeed possible where the absence of
    reasonable investment-backed expectations is considered to be the sole dispositive Penn
    Central 
    factor. 429 F.3d at 1094
    (citing Monsanto and Golden Pacific).
    Defendant relies on Norman, but also points to another Federal Circuit decision,
    Good v. United States, 
    189 F.3d 1355
    , 1363 (Fed. Cir. 1999), as support for its contention
    that “[f]ailure to satisfy the reasonable-expectations prong requires judgment in favor of
    the Government.” ECF No. 422 at 10 (emphasis added). In light of Hodel, as construed
    in 
    Norman, 429 F.3d at 1094
    n.6, defendant’s contention appears to be overbroad. The
    full text of the relevant footnote in Norman is as follows:
    7
    Although plaintiffs insist that Cienega VIII found that the enactment of the
    Preservation Statutes was “extraordinary” for the purposes of weighing the character of
    the governmental action factor in the Penn Central analysis, ECF No. 439 at 15, the only
    use of that term in Cienega VIII is to describe the regulation discussed in Hodel, not the
    Preservation Statutes, Cienega 
    VIII, 331 F.3d at 1338
    (citing 
    Hodel, 481 U.S. at 715-16
    ).
    8
    The Supreme Court’s decision in Hodel v. Irving, 
    481 U.S. 704
    , 
    107 S. Ct. 2076
    , 
    95 L. Ed. 2d 668
    (1987), is [illustrative]. In that case, the Court clearly
    found that two of the three Penn Central factors—economic impact and
    character of the government’s action—weighed in favor of just
    compensation, and that in light of the “extraordinary” nature of the
    government action, the absence of reasonable investment-backed
    expectations did not defeat the takings claim. See 
    Hodel, 481 U.S. at 714
    ,
    
    107 S. Ct. 2076
    .
    429 F.3d at 1094 n.6. Hodel thus provides the exception to the rule proposed by
    defendant.
    In the court’s view, Good stands for the proposition that the reasonable
    investment-backed expectations factor may indeed be dispositive, on summary judgment,
    of a regulatory takings claim. 
    See 189 F.3d at 1363
    (stating that “the government is
    entitled to summary judgment on a regulatory takings claim where the plaintiffs lacked
    reasonable, investment-backed expectations, even where the challenged government
    action ‘substantially reduc[ed] the value of plaintiffs’ property.’” (quoting Avenal v.
    United States, 
    100 F.3d 933
    , 937 (Fed. Cir. 1996)) (alteration in original)).
    The court acknowledges that a mechanistic application of the Penn Central factors
    is generally disfavored. See, e.g., Cienega 
    X, 503 F.3d at 1278
    (“To make [the
    determination whether a regulatory taking has occurred], there is no set formula.”); Bass
    
    Enterprises, 381 F.3d at 1370
    (“The Supreme Court’s decision in Tahoe-Sierra further
    stressed that a gestalt approach should be used when evaluating all of the Penn Central
    factors, including the ‘character of the Government action’ factor.”) (citing Tahoe-Sierra
    Preservation Council, Inc. v. Tahoe Reg’l Planning Agency, 
    535 U.S. 302
    , 330 (2002)).
    In the circumstances of this case, however, 620 Su Casa Por Cortez purchased the subject
    property after the mortgage prepayment right had been destroyed by the Preservation
    Statutes. This fact clearly shows the absence of any reasonable investment-backed
    expectation of the exercise of that extinguished prepayment right. In these circumstances
    the court finds that the investment-backed expectations factor of the Penn Central
    analysis is dispositive of the regulatory takings claim of 620 Su Casa Por Cortez; plaintiff
    620 Su Casa Por Cortez must be dismissed from these consolidated cases.8
    B.     Whether a Temporary or Permanent Regulatory Takings Analysis Applies
    to Each of the Takings Alleged by the FWPs
    8
    Even if the court has erred in granting summary judgment as to 620 Su Casa Por
    Cortez solely based on the investment-backed expectations factor, the court notes that the
    court’s more general holding on the Penn Central factors, once economic injury is
    considered, is applicable to all six FWPs, including 620 Su Casa Por Cortez.
    9
    The court asked the parties to submit supplemental briefing addressing the nature
    of the alleged takings asserted by the FWPs, and to determine whether these alleged
    regulatory takings were temporary or permanent in nature. There were strong reasons to
    resolve this question before trial, not thereafter:
    The court does not believe it prudent to conduct a trial on takings claims
    where the type of regulatory taking is uncertain and in dispute, and where the
    relevance of the evidence of economic injury presented is also uncertain
    because the nature of the taking is undetermined.
    ECF No. 470 at 3. Although the parties’ supplemental briefs are quite thorough, neither
    side proffers an analysis as to the character of the alleged takings with which the court
    can agree.
    In plaintiffs’ supplemental opposition brief, all six FWPs are alleged to have
    suffered temporary regulatory takings. ECF No. 479 at 7. In defendant’s supplemental
    summary judgment brief, five of the FWPs, those who sold their properties through
    LIHPRHA procedures, are alleged to have suffered permanent regulatory takings, if any.
    ECF No. 477 at 7. The sixth FWP, the only FWP to enter into a continuing use
    agreement with HUD under the terms of LIHPRHA, rather than a sale, is alleged by the
    government to have suffered a temporary taking, if any. 
    Id. Both plaintiffs
    and the
    government assert that under either a permanent or temporary takings theory, their side
    must prevail on the economic injury factor of the Penn Central analysis. ECF No. 477 at
    16-18; ECF No. 479 at 25-37.
    Although the appropriate test discerned in the precedent discussed below was not
    advanced, in full, by either side in this dispute, the court finds that the regulatory takings
    alleged by the FWPs are all permanent in nature. This finding has a profound impact on
    the evidence of economic injury that would be relevant to the court’s Penn Central
    analysis, were this case to proceed to trial on the claims of the FWPs. This finding is also
    dispositive of defendant’s motion for summary judgment, because plaintiffs’ evidence
    regarding the economic injury suffered by the FWPs is insufficient to prevail at trial.
    1.     Measuring Economic Injury in Permanent Regulatory Takings
    When a real estate parcel has been permanently affected by a regulatory taking,
    the measure of economic injury is the difference between the fair market value of the
    property, without the restriction imposed by the government action, and the fair market
    value of the property, with the restriction imposed by the government action, both
    measured at the time of the taking. See, e.g., Forest Props., Inc. v. United States, 
    177 F.3d 1360
    , 1367 (Fed. Cir. 1999) (citing Loveladies 
    Harbor, 28 F.3d at 1178
    , 1182; Fla.
    Rock Indus., Inc. v. United States, 
    18 F.3d 1560
    , 1567 (Fed. Cir. 1994)). There does not
    appear to be any real dispute that the fair market value of income-producing property
    reflects and includes the value of income that might be realized from the property. See,
    10
    e.g., First Fed. Lincoln Bank v. United States, 
    518 F.3d 1308
    , 1317 (Fed. Cir. 2008)
    (“The market value of income-generating property reflects the market’s estimate of the
    present value of the chance to earn future income, discounted by the market’s view of the
    lower future value of the income and the uncertainty of the occurrence and amount of any
    future property.”) (citations omitted); Cane Tenn., Inc. v. United States, 
    71 Fed. Cl. 432
    ,
    438 (2005) (discussing fair market value determination based upon the income-
    generating potential of the property) (citations omitted), aff’d, 214 F. App’x 978 (Fed.
    Cir. 2007) (table). Thus, the standard approach for measuring economic injury, the
    difference in fair market value without and with the government restriction, is applicable
    to alleged permanent regulatory takings affecting income-producing real property, just as
    it applies to alleged permanent takings of other real property. See A.A. Profiles, Inc. v.
    City of Fort Lauderdale, 
    253 F.3d 576
    , 584 (11th Cir. 2001) (reversing the trial court’s
    methodology which relied on a “market rate return” approach, and stating that for a
    permanent regulatory taking, the “diminution in market value test” is proper); see also
    MHC Fin. Ltd. P’ship v. City of San Rafael, 
    714 F.3d 1118
    , 1127 (9th Cir. 2013) (MHC
    Financing) (stating that the trial court should have used a figure representing the
    diminution in the value of the property to assess the economic impact of a regulation on a
    mobile home park).
    2.     Three Types of Plaintiffs Affected by the Preservation Statutes
    Three relevant types of plaintiffs have litigated takings claims based on the
    enactment of the Preservation Statutes. The first category consists of owners who
    retained possession of their properties and whose mortgage prepayment rights were
    restored, in some fashion, by the passage of the Hope Act. These plaintiffs neither
    entered into a LIHPRHA sale, nor entered into a LIHPRHA use agreement. None of the
    FWPs fall into this category, although four of the plaintiffs in Cienega X were in this
    
    category. 503 F.3d at 1287
    n.20. For want of a better term, the court describes these
    litigants as Hope Act plaintiffs, because the passage of the Hope Act signaled the end of
    the alleged temporary regulatory takings period. See 
    id. at 1287-88
    & n.20 (emphasizing
    that the duration of the legislative restriction, which ended as a result of the enactment of
    the Hope Act, was an essential fact for the takings analysis applicable to these plaintiffs).
    The second category of owners are those who, before the passage of the Hope Act,
    entered into LIHPRHA use agreements with HUD “to stay in the [low-income housing]
    program,” through which they exchanged any vestige of the original mortgage
    prepayment right for significant benefits in their ongoing relationship with HUD.
    Cienega 
    X, 503 F.3d at 1273
    & n.4. Only one of the FWPs, Rock Creek Terrace L.P.
    (Rock Creek), signed a LIHPRHA use agreement and is in this category of plaintiff.
    Four of the Cienega X plaintiffs were in this 
    category. 503 F.3d at 1273
    n.5, 1279 n.12,
    1288. The court refers to these litigants as LIHPRHA use agreement plaintiffs.
    The third category of owners sold their properties either before the Hope Act was
    in effect, or arranged the sale before the Hope Act was in effect and completed the sale
    11
    shortly thereafter. All of these sales were LIHPRHA sales, in conformance with the
    requirements of LIHPRHA. Five of the FWPs in this suit, every FWP except Rock
    Creek, are in this category. None of the Cienega X plaintiffs were in this category. The
    court refers to these litigants as LIHPRHA sale plaintiffs.
    Before delving into relevant precedent, the court provides some general comments
    regarding the three categories of plaintiffs and the significance of those categories. Much
    of the commentary in Cienega X appears to be directed to a temporary regulatory takings
    analysis, which is logical because the Hope Act plaintiffs in that appeal are emblematic
    of property owners whose property right was temporarily extinguished by one
    governmental action, then restored by another governmental action, nineteen to twenty-
    seven months 
    later. 503 F.3d at 1287-88
    & n.20. None of the FWPs here are in the
    category of the Hope Act plaintiffs; thus, the FWPs cannot benefit from any portions of
    Cienega X which are directed to the situation of the Hope Act plaintiffs.
    Similarly, aside from Rock Creek, none of the FWPs are in the second category of
    LIHPRHA use agreement plaintiffs, which is the only other type of plaintiff before the
    Federal Circuit in Cienega X. For the LIHPRHA sale plaintiffs here, five of the FWPs,
    Cienega X did not address their situation, and the court must look to other precedent for
    guidance. More specifically, for the LIHPRHA sale plaintiffs, the court must determine
    whether the owner’s sale of the property, while a government restriction is still in effect,
    signifies that the alleged taking should be considered to be permanent in nature.
    Finally, the court notes a similarity between the second and third categories of
    plaintiffs, the categories which encompass all six FWPs in this case. In each instance, the
    plaintiff disposed of any vestige of the original mortgage prepayment right, pursuant to
    LIHPRHA procedures, either through a LIHPRHA use agreement or a LIHPRHA sale.
    Through that action which took place, or was put in place, before the Hope Act took
    effect, the plaintiff no longer retained any attenuated version of the original prepayment
    right, and that property right for the owner was permanently extinguished. Conceptually,
    at least, the fact that these plaintiffs’ prepayment rights were permanently extinguished is
    a strong indication that any alleged regulatory taking here was permanent, not temporary.
    The court begins its analysis by examining the trial court’s decision in Cienega
    Gardens v. United States, 
    67 Fed. Cl. 434
    (2005) (Cienega IX), vacated, 
    503 F.3d 1266
    (Fed. Cir. 2007).
    3.     Cienega IX
    There is no doubt that the trial court in Cienega IX viewed the alleged takings in
    that case (for the eight plaintiffs that would also be the subject of Cienega X), as
    temporary regulatory takings. Cienega 
    IX, 67 Fed. Cl. at 437-38
    . The trial court relied,
    at least in part, on the characterization in the Cienega VIII opinion of the takings alleged
    by the four “Model Plaintiffs.” 
    Id. at 437
    (citing Cienega 
    VIII, 331 F.3d at 1353-54
    ).
    12
    The trial court in Cienega IX noted that the four Model Plaintiffs had recently been
    awarded just compensation, and that their awards were on appeal before the Federal
    Circuit. 
    Id. at 437
    n.1. Those appeals resulted in two Federal Circuit decisions,
    Independence Park Apartments v. United States, 
    449 F.3d 1235
    (Fed. Cir.)
    (Independence Park I), decision clarified on reh’g, 
    465 F.3d 1308
    (Fed. Cir. 2006), and
    Independence Park Apartments v. United States, 
    465 F.3d 1308
    (Fed. Cir. 2006)
    (Independence Park II).
    Cienega IX was vacated by the Federal Circuit, and the suit was remanded for a
    “new Penn Central analysis under the correct legal standard.” Cienega 
    X, 503 F.3d at 1291
    . Thus, Cienega IX cannot guide the court here.
    The court turns next to Independence Park I and Independence Park II.
    4.     Independence Park I and Independence Park II
    The most relevant portion of Independence Park I concerns two LIHPRHA use
    agreement plaintiffs, Sherman Park Apartments (Sherman Park) and St. Andrews
    Gardens (St. 
    Andrews). 449 F.3d at 1246-48
    . According to the Federal Circuit, the
    holdings in Cienega VIII did not specifically address the particular circumstances of
    Sherman Park and St. Andrews:
    [A]t no point in [Cienega VIII] did we discuss the [LIHPRHA] use
    agreements or their effect on the plaintiffs’ legal rights in this case. The
    statements on which the trial court relied consisted mainly of
    characterizations of the facts as applied generally to all 42 plaintiffs. We did
    not focus on the specific situation of Sherman Park and St. Andrews, nor did
    we suggest that their entry into use agreements before the enactment of the
    HOPE Act had no legal effect. The mandate in Cienega VIII therefore does
    not foreclose the plaintiffs’ cross-appeal. Accordingly, we turn to the merits
    of the parties’ arguments regarding the legal effect of the [LIHPRHA] use
    agreements.
    Independence Park 
    I, 449 F.3d at 1246-47
    . Thus, it is clear that the Independence Park I
    panel viewed the takings claims of the LIHPRHA use agreement plaintiffs in that case to
    be open to an analysis that differed from the takings analysis discussed in Cienega VIII.
    According to the Federal Circuit, the legal effect of a LIHPRHA use agreement is
    “better characterized as an offer by the government of something of value to offset the
    prepayment rights taken by statute.” Independence Park 
    I, 449 F.3d at 1247
    . Indeed, the
    enactment of the Hope Act was immaterial in light of the extinguishment of the original
    prepayment right by the plaintiffs’ execution of the LIHPRHA use agreements: “Once
    the plaintiffs had signed the use agreements, however, the passage of the HOPE Act was
    irrelevant to them.” 
    Id. Thus, according
    to Independence Park I, the date of the
    13
    enactment of the Hope Act, which is a key fact in the takings claims of Hope Act
    plaintiffs, see Cienega 
    X, 503 F.3d at 1287-88
    & n.20, is of absolutely no consequence in
    the takings claims of LIHPRHA use agreement plaintiffs.
    How, then, is a court to measure the economic impact of the alleged takings of
    LIHPRHA use agreement plaintiffs? Independence Park I provides the initial answer to
    that question:
    This situation is analogous to a physical taking in which the government
    appropriates a plaintiff’s property at the outset and then takes steps to
    mitigate the financial impact of the taking, rather than returning the property
    to the plaintiff. In such a case, the proper analysis is to treat the initial taking
    as permanent and to calculate the damages for the taking by starting with the
    amount that the plaintiff lost as a result of the initial taking and subtracting
    from that sum the amount by which the plaintiff was made better off by the
    steps taken by the government to offset the impact of the taking. See, e.g.,
    Shelden v. United States, 
    7 F.3d 1022
    , 1031 (Fed. Cir. 
    1993). 449 F.3d at 1247
    (emphasis added).
    Put in simpler terms, the alleged taking is permanent in nature and the economic
    impact of the alleged taking is measured in two steps. First, the court determines the
    difference in the fair market value of the property, without and with the restriction, both
    measured at the time of the taking. See, e.g., Colony Cove Props., LLC v. City of
    Carson, 
    888 F.3d 445
    , 451 (9th Cir. 2018) (“[E]conomic impact is determined by
    comparing the total value of the affected property before and after the government action.
    Projected income streams can contribute to a method for determining the post-deprivation
    value of property, but the severity of the loss can be determined only by comparing the
    post-deprivation value to pre-deprivation value.” (citing MHC 
    Financing, 714 F.3d at 1127
    )). Second, the court adjusts that value by deducting the monetary value of the
    benefits to the plaintiff flowing from the LIHPRHA use agreement. Independence Park 
    I, 449 F.3d at 1247
    . No clearer blueprint is required for the determination of the economic
    impact of the regulatory takings claims asserted by LIHPRHA use agreement plaintiffs.
    If there were any doubt as to the proper takings analysis for LIHPRHA use
    agreement plaintiffs, Independence Park II responded to the government’s challenge to
    this portion of the holdings in Independence Park I. Independence Park 
    II, 465 F.3d at 1309-10
    . Once again, the Federal Circuit held that the passage of the Hope Act was
    irrelevant to the claims of LIHPRHA use agreement plaintiffs. 
    Id. at 1310.
    Once again,
    the Federal Circuit described the situation as a permanent taking, where the first step of
    the analysis was determining the loss in property value caused by the enactment of the
    Preservation Statutes:
    14
    A person valuing the amount taken at the time those statutes were enacted
    would consider the taking permanent and make the valuation determination
    on that basis.
    
    Id. at 1311
    (citing Almota Farmers Elevator & Warehouse Co. v. United States, 
    409 U.S. 470
    , 474 (1973)). And, once again, the Federal Circuit reiterated its commitment to a
    two-step permanent regulatory takings analysis of the economic impact on LIHPRHA use
    agreement plaintiffs:
    We therefore reiterate that the proper method for assessing the damages
    suffered by St. Andrews and Sherman Park is to start with the damages that
    would have been assessed for a permanent taking and to reduce that amount
    by the value of the benefits conferred on St. Andrews and Sherman Park by
    the use agreements, as determined at the time they entered into the
    agreements.
    
    Id. at 1312.
    After considering the holdings in Independence Park I and Independence Park II,
    the court concludes that a permanent takings analysis of economic injury, not a temporary
    takings analysis of economic injury, is appropriate for LIHPRHA use agreement
    plaintiffs. In this case, the Independence Park I and Independence Park II analysis is
    directly applicable to the claims of Rock Creek, and its evidence of economic injury must
    allow the court to first determine the difference in fair market value caused by the
    Preservation Statutes, and then, in a second step, to determine the reduction to that loss
    derived from the benefits afforded to Rock Creek by the LIHPRHA use agreement.
    The court notes that the Independence Park II decision relied upon a seminal
    takings case, First English Evangelical Lutheran Church of Glendale v. Los Angeles
    County, California, 
    482 U.S. 304
    (1987) (First English). First English is cited for this
    proposition:
    When subsequent action converts an otherwise permanent taking into a
    temporary one, just compensation is typically calculated in the same manner,
    adjusted to account for the subsequent events so that the damages will
    accurately reflect the value of what was taken.
    Independence Park 
    II, 465 F.3d at 1311
    (citing First 
    English, 482 U.S. at 321
    ; Yuba Nat.
    Res., Inc. v. United States, 
    904 F.2d 1577
    , 1581 (Fed. Cir. 1990)). The “subsequent
    action” cutting short the permanent taking in Independence Park II was the “act of
    entering into the use agreements” by Sherman Park and St. Andrews. 
    Id. at 1312.
    Although First English specifically addressed subsequent government action that might
    cut short the alleged 
    taking, 482 U.S. at 321
    , Independence Park II extends the analysis in
    First English to a situation where it is the landowner’s action that cuts short the taking.
    15
    Because LIHPRHA sale plaintiffs are in the same posture as LIHPRHA use
    agreement plaintiffs, having extinguished any vestige of their original prepayment rights
    by entering into LIHPRHA sale agreements (in lieu of LIHPRHA use agreements), the
    analytical framework provided by Independence Park I and Independence Park II also
    provides the proper measure of the economic impact of the Preservation Statutes on these
    plaintiffs. The only real difference between these two categories of plaintiffs, as to the
    method for determining economic injury, is the deduction made to adjust the permanent
    effect of LIHPRHA on the property’s fair market value. In the case of the LIHPRHA use
    agreement plaintiffs, it is the deduction for the benefits derived from the use agreements,
    measured at the time the use agreements were signed. For the LIHPRHA sale plaintiffs,
    it is the deduction for the amount realized from the sale of the subject property, measured
    at the time of the sale.
    The court now turns to Cienega X, to determine whether any portion of that
    opinion directly contradicts the guidance given by Independence Park I and
    Independence Park II.
    5.      Cienega X
    Certainly, the Cienega X panel was aware of the holdings in Independence Park I
    and that the situation of LIHPRHA use agreement plaintiffs was addressed in that
    opinion, because the precedential holdings in Independence Park I are cited twice by the
    Cienega X panel. See Cienega 
    X, 503 F.3d at 1273
    n.5, 1284 n.14. The primary focus in
    Cienega X appears to be on Hope Act plaintiffs, or on more general pronouncements that
    might apply both to Hope Act plaintiffs and LIHPRHA use agreement plaintiffs. See 
    id. at 1273
    (stating that “only four of the plaintiffs entered into [LIHPRHA] use agreements
    after ELIHPA expired but during the period that LIHPRHA was in effect”) (emphasis
    added). There is very little discussion in Cienega X of the legal effects particular to the
    execution of a LIHPRHA use agreement, and how that fact should be incorporated in the
    analysis of the economic injury suffered by the plaintiff.
    Generally, there is ambiguity as to whether certain sections of the Cienega X
    opinion apply specifically to Hope Act plaintiffs, LIHPRHA use agreement plaintiffs, or
    both. The court begins with the least ambiguous, relevant portions of Cienega X. There
    is one passage which echoes the Independence Park I and Independence Park II
    decisions, in that it discusses the need to deduct, or “offset,” benefits offered the plaintiffs
    by LIHPRHA. Cienega 
    X, 503 F.3d at 1282-83
    . Offsetting in the specific case of
    LIHPRHA use agreement plaintiffs was addressed in detail. 
    Id. at 1285-87.
    Somewhat less clearly, but still echoing Independence Park I and Independence
    Park II, the Cienega X panel noted in the “Duration” section of the opinion that
    LIHPRHA use agreement plaintiffs were different from Hope Act plaintiffs. The passage
    noting that difference is very generally worded:
    16
    Four of the owners elected to enter into use agreements after the enactment
    of LIHPRHA but before the HOPE enactment: Cienega Gardens, Del Amo
    Gardens, Las Lomas Gardens, and Chancellor Manor. The temporary nature
    of the legislation is irrelevant with respect to those who had use agreements
    in place when HOPE was enacted since those owners acted reasonably on
    the assumption that the restrictions were permanent.
    Cienega 
    X, 503 F.3d at 1288
    (emphasis added). This statement can reasonably be read to
    endorse a permanent takings analysis for the LIHPRHA use agreement plaintiffs, as was
    set forth in Independence Park I and Independence Park II. The “Duration” section of the
    opinion also appears to indicate that the passage of the Hope Act is of great significance
    to the claims of Hope Act plaintiffs, and irrelevant to the claims of LIHPRHA use
    agreement plaintiffs. Cienega 
    X, 503 F.3d at 1287-88
    & n.20. This is perfectly
    consonant with the analysis set forth in Independence Park I and Independence Park II.
    The court notes, too, that the phrases “temporary taking” or “temporary regulatory
    taking,” occur only a few times in Cienega X, including twice in the dissent. 
    See 503 F.3d at 1292-93
    (Newman, J., dissenting). In other instances, the phrases are used to
    describe prior history of the case. 
    Id. at 1275
    (citing Cienega 
    VIII, 331 F.3d at 1324
    ),
    1277 (citing Cienega 
    IX, 67 Fed. Cl. at 438
    ). The most substantive use of the temporary
    takings phraseology occurs in the “Parcel as a Whole” section of the opinion, which
    addressed some aspects of the Cienega IX court’s flawed measurement of economic
    injury in its Penn Central analysis. Cienega 
    X, 503 F.3d at 1281-82
    .
    The court has considered each occurrence of “temporary taking” phraseology in
    this section of Cienega X. The court concludes that the Federal Circuit’s analysis broadly
    describes the applicability of a temporary regulatory takings analysis to at least some of
    the plaintiffs in that case, which, as noted above, included both Hope Act plaintiffs and
    LIHPRHA use agreement plaintiffs. This opinion section does not clearly state that all of
    the takings in that case were temporary in nature. Nor, it must be acknowledged, does
    this section of the Cienega X opinion state that only the Hope Act plaintiffs’ alleged
    takings were temporary in nature.9 Finding no conflict in Cienega X with the guidance
    9
    At the end of the “Parcel as a Whole” section of Cienega X, a LIHPRHA use
    agreement plaintiff, Chancellor Manor, is mentioned in a 
    footnote. 503 F.3d at 1282
    n.13. The Federal Circuit noted that the economic impact of the Preservation Statutes on
    Chancellor Manor, as determined by the trial court, was obviously flawed because that
    impact was significantly greater than the assessed value of the property. 
    Id. (citing Cienega
    IX, 67 Fed. Cl. at 477 
    n.54). The court does not construe this footnote in
    Cienega X to be an indication that the Federal Circuit considered Chancellor Manor to
    have been subject to a temporary regulatory taking. Instead, the Cienega X panel appears
    to have pointed to Chancellor Manor as an illustrative example of how the trial court had
    erred in its economic impact analysis, in general.
    17
    provided by Independence Park I and Independence Park II, the court must follow the
    takings analysis set forth in those earlier Federal Circuit decisions for both the LIHPRHA
    use agreement plaintiff among the FWPs, i.e., Rock Creek, and for the LIHPRHA sale
    plaintiffs, the other five FWPs.
    Finally, the Cienega X opinion puts to rest any concerns that the analytical
    framework provided by Independence Park I and Independence Park II, elaborated in the
    just compensation context, is inapplicable to the economic injury prong of the Penn
    Central analysis required in takings cases based on the Preservation Statutes. The text of
    the opinion includes this statement: “The [offsetting] benefits [provided by the
    Preservation Statutes] must be considered as part of the [Penn Central] takings analysis.”
    Cienega 
    X, 503 F.3d at 1283-84
    . In the accompanying footnote, the Cienega X panel
    explained why the reasoning of Independence Park I was of value for both the just
    compensation inquiry and the economic impact inquiry:
    Such [offsetting] benefits, of course, would be pertinent as well to a just
    compensation analysis if a taking had occurred. In Cienega VIII, we held
    that a taking had occurred with respect to the model plaintiffs (two of which
    had entered into use agreements under LIHPRHA—Sherman Park and St.
    Andrews), and directed the Court of Federal Claims to enter the damages
    awarded in Cienega [Gardens v. United States], 
    38 Fed. Cl. 64
    [(1997)
    (subsequent history omitted)]. See Cienega 
    VIII, 331 F.3d at 1353
    . On
    remand, the Court of Federal Claims reinstated the damages award for the
    model plaintiffs, and we reviewed that award in Independence Park
    Apartments v. United States, 
    449 F.3d 1235
    (Fed. Cir. 2006) [(Independence
    Park I)]. There we stated that, for purposes of determining just
    compensation, “the calculation of damages should be adjusted [for the two
    model plaintiffs that entered into use agreements] to treat the ban on
    prepayment as lasting as long as the use agreements provided for, with the
    amount of the damages adjusted to account for any benefits . . . obtained as
    a result of the use agreements.” 
    Id. at 1248.
    However, the Independence
    Park [I] decision does not suggest that these benefits should not also be
    considered as part of the takings analysis.
    Cienega 
    X, 503 F.3d at 1284
    n.14; see also CCA Associates 
    II, 667 F.3d at 1251
    (noting
    that offsetting benefits in LIHPRHA cases are counted in both the just compensation
    calculation, as well as in the Penn Central analysis) (citing Cienega 
    X, 503 F.3d at 1283-84
    ). Thus, although not every just compensation analysis is germane to the
    economic injury prong in a Penn Central inquiry, see Cienega X at 1281-82
    18
    (distinguishing Kimball Laundry Co. v. United States, 
    338 U.S. 1
    (1949)), the analytical
    framework in Independence Park I was specifically endorsed for that purpose.10
    6.     Summary of Precedent
    Having reviewed the precedent most relevant to the takings claims of LIHPRHA
    use agreement plaintiffs and LIHPRHA sale plaintiffs, the court concludes that
    Independence Park I and Independence Park II provide the analytical framework for these
    regulatory takings claims. Applying this precedent, the FWPs’ claims are in the nature of
    permanent takings claims. To determine the economic injury, if any, suffered by these
    plaintiffs, the first step is to determine the difference in fair market value caused by the
    Preservation Statutes. This is accomplished by comparing the subject property’s fair
    market value, as enhanced by the mortgage prepayment right, to the property’s fair
    market value, deprived of the mortgage prepayment right, both measured at the time of
    the taking.
    The second step is to deduct from the sum achieved in the first step the benefits
    LIHPRHA provided the FWPs. In the case of Rock Creek, those benefits arise from the
    LIHPRHA use agreement. For the remaining FWPs, those benefits derive from the
    proceeds of the LIHPRHA sale to the new owner of the subject property. These two
    calculations determine the actual economic impact of the Preservation Statutes on these
    plaintiffs.
    A third and final step, if economic loss has been shown, would be to determine
    whether the plaintiff’s economic loss was severe enough to support a taking under Penn
    Central. Neither Cienega 
    X, 503 F.3d at 1280-82
    , nor the decisions in Independence Park
    I and Independence Park II, offer definitive guidance as to this final step in the analysis
    for the categories of plaintiffs in this case. At a minimum, however, it is clear that
    “return on equity” measures cannot be used, because that particular metric does not
    address the value of the parcel as a whole. See Cienega 
    X, 503 F.3d at 1280-81
    (citing
    Concrete Pipe & Prods. of Cal., Inc. v. Constr. Laborers Pension Tr. for S. Cal., 
    508 U.S. 602
    , 643-44 (1993)). The court need not opine as to the precise contours of the severity
    framework applicable to the FWPs, because their evidence is insufficient to perform even
    the first step of the economic impact analysis, i.e., the comparison of the fair market
    10
    As the Supreme Court has commented, “just compensation for a net loss of zero is
    zero.” Brown v. Legal Found. of Wash., 
    538 U.S. 216
    , 240 n.11 (2003). Just
    compensation is therefore related, logically, to the economic injury determined in a Penn
    Central inquiry. Cf. Love Terminal Partners, L.P. v. United States, 
    889 F.3d 1331
    , 1343
    n.2 (Fed. Cir. 2018) (noting that expert testimony on the topic of economic loss may
    employ assumptions that are similar to those in expert testimony regarding just
    compensation).
    19
    values for each property, with and without the mortgage prepayment right, measured at
    the time of the alleged taking.
    Having laid the foundation for the Penn Central analysis of the permanent
    regulatory takings alleged by the FWPs, the court now turns to the application of the
    three Penn Central factors to the evidence proffered by plaintiffs. The question before
    the court is whether plaintiffs have adduced sufficient evidence to survive defendant’s
    motion for summary judgment. As noted earlier in this opinion, “[a] nonmoving party’s
    failure of proof concerning the existence of an element essential to its case on which the
    nonmoving party will bear the burden of proof at trial necessarily renders all other facts
    immaterial and entitles the moving party to summary judgment as a matter of law.”
    Dairyland 
    Power, 16 F.3d at 1202
    (citing 
    Celotex, 477 U.S. at 323
    ).
    C.     The Penn Central Factors
    1.     The Character of the Governmental Action
    The character of the governmental action factor of the Penn Central test, as applied
    to the Preservation Statues, has been addressed by the Federal Circuit. Plaintiffs argue,
    and the court must agree, that the character of the governmental action factor weighs in
    favor of a finding that a taking was effected by the Preservation Statutes vis-à-vis the
    FWPs. See, e.g., Cienega 
    VIII, 331 F.3d at 1340
    (“We conclude, as matter of law, that
    the government’s actions in enacting ELIHPA and LIHPRHA, insofar as they abrogated
    the Model Plaintiffs’ contractual rights to prepay their mortgages and thereby exit the
    housing programs, had a character that supports a holding of a compensable taking.”).
    Defendant acknowledges that the character of the governmental action factor
    weighs in the FWPs’ favor. ECF No. 459 at 9. Plaintiffs contend that the weight of the
    character of the governmental action factor is sufficient, “on its own,” to deny the
    government’s summary judgment motion. ECF No. 439 at 15. Defendant disagrees,
    citing CCA Associates 
    II, 667 F.3d at 1248
    . ECF No. 459 at 9. Defendant’s position is
    correct.
    Plaintiffs’ burden at trial would be to put forth sufficient evidence on all three
    Penn Central factors to establish a taking. See CCA Associates 
    II, 667 F.3d at 1245
    (stating that “the plaintiff has the burden to prove a taking occurred”). Insufficient
    evidence on the economic impact (or economic injury) factor and the investment-backed
    expectations factor defeats a takings claim, even if the character of the governmental
    action factor weighs heavily in favor of the claimant. See 
    id. at 1248
    (holding that
    because the investment-backed expectations and the economic injury factors weighed
    against the finding of a taking, the character of the governmental action factor was not
    dispositive). Summary judgment for the government is not precluded by plaintiffs’
    strong showing on the character of the governmental action factor.
    20
    Following CCA Associates II and the other authorities cited by defendant, ECF
    No. 459 at 9-12, the court must consider whether the FWPs could prevail at trial when the
    court considers their evidence as to economic injury and investment-backed expectations.
    As plaintiffs oppose defendant’s motion for summary judgment, the sufficiency of their
    evidence on these two factors is determinative of the outcome. 
    Anderson, 477 U.S. at 249
    . The court therefore finds plaintiffs’ reliance on the character of the governmental
    action factor, as a full and effective bar to summary judgment in favor of the government,
    to be unavailing, and now turns to the other Penn Central factors.
    2.     Distinct Investment-Backed Expectations
    According to the government, the FWPs have failed to point to sufficient evidence
    on the investment-backed expectations factor to withstand summary judgment in favor of
    the government on their takings claims. ECF No. 422 at 12. The court cannot agree
    (except as to 620 Su Casa Por Cortez, 
    see supra
    ).
    The evidence of the five remaining FWPs as to their investment-backed
    expectations is not deficient, when seen through the summary judgment lens, despite
    defendant’s protestations to the contrary. The government contends that plaintiffs have
    failed to identify a genuine dispute of material fact as to the FWPs’ investment-backed
    expectations. See ECF No. 422 at 12 (“The Court should grant summary judgment
    because there is no genuine dispute that plaintiffs cannot satisfy their burden under the
    controlling standard for the investment-backed expectations prong–namely, reasonable
    expectations at the time of investment.”) (citing Cienega 
    X, 503 F.3d at 1288
    ).
    Defendant argues, and plaintiffs do not disagree, that investment-backed expectations are
    measured at the time the investment was made, and according to objective, industry
    standards for reasonableness. 
    Id. Applying this
    standard, defendant argues that plaintiffs’ evidence falls short. In
    the government’s opening brief, the focus is mostly on plaintiffs’ expert, Dr. William
    Wade. 
    Id. at 13-14.
    In defendant’s reply brief, the critique encompasses a broader range
    of plaintiffs’ evidence of investment-backed expectations. ECF No. 459 at 13-16.
    According to defendant, “[w]ithout objective evidence of the industry’s investment
    backed expectations at the time of the plaintiffs’ investment, plaintiffs have failed to
    make a sufficient showing on an essential element of their claim, and the Court should
    grant summary judgment in favor of the Government.” ECF No. 422 at 14.
    At this point in the litigation of plaintiffs’ claims, the court does not evaluate the
    evidence to determine whether plaintiffs have met their ultimate burden of proof on the
    investment-backed expectations prong of the Penn Central inquiry. Instead, the court is
    tasked with reviewing plaintiffs’ evidence to see if they could win on this prong.
    
    Anderson, 477 U.S. at 249
    . The court credits not Dr. Wade, see infra, but the “body of
    evidence” compiled by plaintiffs, ECF No. 439 at 30, largely derived from the testimony
    of the investors, developers and syndicators who were involved in the development of the
    21
    properties at issue in these consolidated cases. Although defendant urges the court to
    reject much of this evidence as “self-serving,” and “subjective,” not “objective,” ECF No.
    459 at 7, 13-14, plaintiffs’ evidence is sufficient to establish a genuine dispute of material
    fact as to the reasonableness of the FWPs’ investment-backed expectations, measured
    objectively, by industry standards, at the time the investments were made.
    Defendant relies heavily on CCA Associates II. 
    Id. at 13-14
    & n.3. While the
    discussion of the objective evidence of investment-backed expectations in CCA
    Associates II is instructive, the court cannot conclude, as defendant urges, that the
    Federal Circuit described therein a rigid scheme for distinguishing subjective from
    objective evidence in every takings case based on the passage of the Preservation
    Statutes. The Federal Circuit noted, first, that different facts may yield different
    outcomes on this prong. See CCA Associates 
    II, 667 F.3d at 1247
    (“Cienega X,
    however, does not suggest that there can only be one objectively reasonable investment
    strategy for the industry, and we hold that there can potentially be multiple objectively
    reasonable investment strategies dictated by geography, economics, or other factors.”).
    The Federal Circuit then proceeded to examine the specific evidence of record in that
    case, and in particular the evidence relied upon by the trial court, and found that the
    plaintiffs had not met their burden, after a trial, on the reasonable investment-backed
    expectations prong. 
    Id. at 1247-48.
    After careful review of the passage in CCA
    Associates II relied upon by defendant, the court concludes that the types of evidence
    which may establish objective measures of investment-backed expectations are not
    necessarily limited to the specific examples of evidence discussed in CCA Associates II.
    Plaintiffs rely on the evidence provided in a number of depositions of the
    investors, developers and syndicators of the FWPs’ housing complexes and similar
    properties. See generally ECF Nos. 441-1 through 441-4. Plaintiffs note, generally, that
    these deponents have broad experience in the real estate market, and have participated in
    a number of organizations which broadly represent the real estate investment sector of the
    American economy. ECF No. 439 at 30-34; ECF No. 440 at 29-38.
    Further, the court notes that the Federal Circuit has expressed a preference for
    contemporaneous documentation relevant to the investment-backed expectations factor.
    Cienega 
    X, 503 F.3d at 1290-91
    . For the reasonable investment-backed expectations
    factor, plaintiffs also rely on contemporaneous documentation, at least some of which has
    probative value. ECF No. 439 at 31-32, 34; ECF No. 440 at 10-11, 34-35; ECF No. 441-
    1 at 34-215; ECF No. 441-3 at 711-21. The court concludes that the five remaining
    FWPs have pointed to enough testimony and contemporaneous documentation that they
    might meet their burden of proof on the investment-backed expectations factor at trial.
    As the Federal Circuit has stated, takings cases are fact-intensive and should not
    be hastily dismissed on summary judgment. Moden v. United States, 
    404 F.3d 1335
    ,
    1342 (Fed. Cir. 2005) (citing Yuba Goldfields, Inc. v. United States, 
    723 F.2d 884
    , 887
    (Fed. Cir. 1983)). Viewing plaintiffs’ evidence in the light most favorable to the FWPs,
    22
    and according all favorable inferences to this evidence, the court views plaintiffs’
    deposition and documentary evidence as probative of the reasonable investment-backed
    expectations factor, and sufficient to withstand defendant’s motion for summary
    judgment on this factor. Dairyland 
    Power, 16 F.3d at 1202
    . In other words, plaintiffs’
    evidence on the reasonable investment-backed expectations factor is sufficient to create a
    genuine dispute of material fact as to this factor.11
    3.     Economic Injury
    According to the government, five of the FWPs, those that sold their properties
    using LIHPRHA procedures, have failed to point to sufficient evidence on the economic
    impact (or economic injury) factor to withstand summary judgment in favor of the
    government on their takings claims. ECF No. 422 at 17-18. The sixth FWP, Rock
    Creek, the only FWP to enter into a LIHPRHA use agreement, is also alleged to have
    “not suffered any economic injury.” 
    Id. at 18
    (citations omitted). The court agrees with
    defendant that summary judgment is merited because the FWPs have not pointed to
    evidence sufficient to prevail on the economic impact prong of the Penn Central analysis.
    As a threshold matter, the court considers whether summary judgment is available
    based solely on an insufficiency of evidence of economic impact in a regulatory takings
    case. Plaintiffs argue that the government cannot prevail on summary judgment even if
    plaintiffs have not mustered sufficient evidence of economic impact. See ECF No. 439 at
    15 (“Application of Hodel and Kaiser precludes summary judgment based solely on the
    distinct investment backed expectations or economic injury factors of Penn Central in this
    case.”). Defendant points out that the Federal Circuit has not embraced plaintiffs’
    reading of Hodel and Kaiser, ECF No. 459 at 9-10 & n.1, and as 
    stated supra
    , the court
    has found that Hodel and Kaiser are inapposite to the takings claims in this case.
    Defendant argues, further, that a regulatory takings claim cannot survive summary
    judgment if the plaintiff fails to point to sufficient evidence of economic injury. 
    Id. at 10
    (citing Seiber v. United States, 
    364 F.3d 1356
    , 1370 (Fed. Cir. 2004); Hendler v. United
    States, 
    175 F.3d 1374
    , 1385 (Fed. Cir. 1999)). The court agrees with defendant. In light
    of the binding precedent cited by the parties, the court must consider whether the FWPs’
    takings claims fail for lack of evidence of economic injury.
    Defendant raises a number of challenges to the sufficiency of plaintiffs’ evidence
    of economic injury. The court addresses only two of these challenges, because they are
    dispositive. The government correctly asserts that plaintiffs have not established the fair
    11
    Defendant contends that plaintiffs’ expert does not proffer probative evidence of
    reasonable investment-backed expectations. ECF No. 422 at 13-14; ECF No. 459 at
    16-17. The court does not reach this argument, because plaintiffs’ other evidence is
    sufficient to withstand summary judgment as to this Penn Central factor.
    23
    market value of the FWPs’ properties at the time of the alleged taking. ECF No. 422 at
    17. The government also asserts that the testimony of plaintiffs’ expert Dr. William
    Wade cannot establish economic injury because his methodology is “flatly inconsistent
    with controlling precedent.” 
    Id. at 20.
    This contention is also true, although the court’s
    analysis and defendant’s analysis diverge in many respects.
    The court notes, at the outset, that plaintiffs’ only evidence of economic injury is
    founded on the methodology of Dr. Wade. See First-Wave Plaintiffs’ Pretrial
    Memorandum, ECF No. 438 at 69-71, 83-84, 97. Plaintiffs submitted two expert reports
    authored by Dr. Wade in support of their opposition to the government’s summary
    judgment motion. See ECF No. 441-4 at 4-318. After conducting an extensive review of
    those reports, the court agrees with the government that plaintiffs have not established the
    fair market value (FMV) of the FWPs’ properties at the time of the taking, for either the
    scenario where the mortgage prepayment right was unrestricted, or the scenario where the
    mortgage prepayment right was restricted by LIHPRHA. The court also finds that Dr.
    Wade’s methodology is unsound because it is inconsistent with binding precedent.
    The court divides its analysis into three sections. First, the court examines Dr.
    Wade’s general approach to the economic injury analysis. Second, the court reviews Dr.
    Wade’s conclusions as to the economic injury suffered by Chauncy House Company
    (Chauncy House). The court chooses Chauncy House as a representative LIHPRHA sale
    plaintiff because its economic injury, as calculated by Dr. Wade, is in the middle of the
    range of economic injury for the FWPs ($5,106,883, in a range of $2,055,488 to
    $9,814,429). ECF No. 441-4 at 12. The final section devoted to Dr. Wade’s findings
    concerns plaintiff Rock Creek, the only LIHPRHA use agreement plaintiff among the
    FWPs.
    a.     Dr. Wade’s Methodology, in General
    Dr. Wade disavows the value of any economic injury calculation relying on a
    comparison of the FMVs of the subject property at the time of the taking, where one
    FMV includes the mortgage prepayment right, and the other excludes that mortgage
    prepayment right. He sometimes refers to this approach, which he shuns in his reports, as
    the “change in property values” approach, ECF No. 441-4 at 214, or the “difference in
    property values” approach, 
    id. at 217,
    but his short-hand reference for this approach is the
    “diminution in value” method, or, simply, the DIV method, 
    id. at 224-25.
    Dr. Wade’s
    rejection of the DIV method is categorical, complete and unwavering. See 
    id. at 11,
    28-29 (showing Dr. Wade’s economic injury formulas, which do not compare FMVs); 
    id. at 31
    (noting Dr. Wade’s reliance on a “Net Present Value,” which is distinguished from
    FMV); 
    id. at 214-15,
    217, 221, 223, 243, 251, 257, 291-96, 300, 317 (rejecting the
    government experts’ reliance on the DIV method); see also 
    id. at 28
    n.13 (acknowledging
    that Cienega 
    X, 503 F.3d at 1282
    , specifically endorsed the “‘change in value’” approach
    as a valid test for determining economic loss in LIHPRHA takings cases, but contending,
    24
    paradoxically, that the DIV method is appropriate only in “real property” takings cases,
    not here).
    Dr. Wade’s expert reports show that he did not use the DIV method. As noted
    earlier in this opinion, a comparison of the FMVs of the subject properties at the time of
    the taking, one with and the other without the mortgage prepayment right, is the first step
    required by Independence Park I and Independence Park II. Dr. Wade did not perform
    this calculation, and his calculations of economic injury are fundamentally flawed as a
    result.
    Not only did Dr. Wade fail to perform a comparison of FMVs as the first step in
    determining economic injury, he does not opine as to the actual and correct FMVs that
    could be used to perform such a comparison. Dr. Wade’s primary use of appraisals of the
    subject properties in the record is to use these as a “first step.” ECF No. 441-4 at 39. Dr.
    Wade’s first step, however, is not analogous to the first step required by Independence
    Park I and Independence Park II. He uses appraisals performed in accordance with
    LIHPRHA guidelines in the following manner: “The analysis in this report relies on the
    resultant [LIHPRHA FMV appraisals] solely as the basis from which to determine what
    the owners actually received on sale to [a] non-profit, not as a predictor of future income
    losses.” ECF No. 441-4 at 29; see also 
    id. at 300
    (same).
    Thus, Dr. Wade presents no opinion as to the actual FMVs of the subject
    properties. Instead, he questions the validity of the LIHPRHA FMV appraisals.12 See 
    id. at 39
    (suggesting that the LIHPRHA FMV appraisal “subtracts conversion [to market rent
    apartments] costs from an appraiser’s estimated FMV”); 298 (stating that the “owners
    actually did not receive the FMV when transferring their properties to Qualified Buyers
    [based on LIHPRHA FMV appraisals]).
    While there is at least one LIHPRHA FMV appraisal figure for each of the
    properties in the record, see ECF No. 423 ¶¶ 18, 21, 24, 27, 34, 37, Dr. Wade provides no
    estimate of the correct pair of FMVs, one for each scenario, for each of the subject
    properties at the time of the alleged taking. Therefore, even if the court could step into
    Dr. Wade’s shoes and compare FMVs for the subject properties at the time of the alleged
    taking, a calculation that he refuses to perform, he has not provided the FMV figures that
    would permit the court to perform even the first step of the economic injury calculation
    required by Independence Park I and Independence Park II.
    12
    The court employs the term LIHPRHA FMV appraisals loosely, to encompass
    both Transfer Preservation Value and Extension Preservation Value, figures which are
    derived by following LIHPRHA appraisal guidelines. ECF No. 441-4 at 29 n.14, 298
    n.18. These are both measures of FMV, although the accuracy of these FMV measures
    is disputed by Dr. Wade. 
    Id. at 298-99.
    25
    The court concludes that plaintiffs have neither compared FMVs, with or without
    the mortgage prepayment right, for the subject properties at the time of the alleged taking,
    nor have they provided the foundation necessary for such a calculation. Their evidence
    of economic injury is fatally flawed and is not probative. Although this flaw is
    determinative and compels the court to grant defendant’s motion for summary judgment
    as to all of the FWPs, the court has discerned two other significant flaws in plaintiffs’
    evidence of economic injury which must be noted, one related to the parcel as a whole
    concept, the other to economic loss severity measures.
    As defendant argues, the parcel as a whole focus of the Penn Central inquiry
    requires that a plaintiff demonstrate economic injury to the entire property, not just to the
    owner’s equity in the parcel. ECF No. 422 at 20 n.2. Cienega X is instructive in this
    regard. Impact on the owner is measured against the “property as a whole” in both
    temporary and, as here, permanent takings. Cienega 
    X, 503 F.3d at 1281
    . Only “serious
    financial consequences,” in terms of the property as a whole, will establish a regulatory
    taking. 
    Id. at 1282.
    The Federal Circuit rejected, in particular, the “return on equity” model employed
    in Cienega IX because it did not consider the property as a whole. 
    Id. at 1280-82.
    The
    court noted, in addition, that one of the economic injury findings of the trial court was
    invalid because the injury calculated by the trial court significantly exceeded the entire
    assessed value of the property. 
    Id. at 1282
    n.13. Cienega X held that
    [l]ogically speaking, the government cannot take more than what the
    plaintiffs actually possess. A determination that damages exceed the value
    of the property should be indicative that the method of computing damages
    is flawed.
    
    Id. Applying the
    reasoning of Cienega X in this case, the economic injury of the
    alleged taking must not be measured against the owner’s equity portion of the subject
    property, but against the parcel as a whole. Here, Dr. Wade refused to compare FMVs,
    with or without the mortgage prepayment right, of the entire properties, and instead
    applied a formula, or formulas, that benchmarked the economic loss to the “owners’
    equity in the property.” ECF No. 441-4 at 11. In the court’s view, Dr. Wade’s approach
    is inconsistent with the parcel as a whole teaching of Cienega X.
    Indeed, it is impossible to imagine how Dr. Wade’s economic injury analysis
    might translate to the parcel as a whole owned by each of the FWPs. The equity portion
    of the subject properties, sometimes referred to as the “owner’s investment,” is
    fundamental to his calculations. ECF No. 441-4 at 12, 28, 30, 38-39, 49, 58, 218 & n.8,
    253-55, 257-58. Dr. Wade states that “[s]everity of economic impact must be
    26
    benchmarked . . . to the owners’ equity at stake to concretely demonstrate the severity of
    economic impact.” 
    Id. at 253.
    The court disagrees with that statement for two reasons.
    First, any benchmarking of the severity of economic injury must be to the parcel
    as a whole. Cienega 
    X, 503 F.3d at 1280-82
    . No reasonable reading of Cienega X would
    substitute the owner’s equity portion of the entire property for the parcel as a whole.
    Second, there is a very real risk, as defendant points out, that benchmarking the severity
    of economic impact to an equity portion of the entire property inflates, rather than
    demonstrates, the actual severity of the economic injury under Penn Central. Def.’s Mot.
    in Limine, ECF No. 452 at 12. The court concludes that Dr. Wade’s analysis does not
    use the correct benchmark for economic injury or the severity of economic impact, which
    must be the parcel as a whole. In consequence, none of Dr. Wade’s conclusions as to
    economic injury or the severity of economic injury are probative.
    Turning now to the severity of economic impact issue, Dr. Wade’s “return on
    equity” approach produces a number of putative indicators of the severity of the FWPs’
    economic losses, none of which are helpful to the court. In Cienega X, the Federal
    Circuit disfavored an analytical framework where the economic loss, for one plaintiff,
    significantly exceeded the appraised value of that plaintiff’s entire 
    property. 503 F.3d at 1282
    n.13. Here, three of the five LIHPRHA sale plaintiffs are alleged to have suffered
    economic losses larger than their sale prices, which were established by the LIHPRHA
    FMV appraisal process. Compare ECF No. 422 at 16, with ECF No. 441-4 at 12. In one
    instance, for Buckman Gardens L.P., the property was valued at, and sold for,
    approximately $6,608,000, but Dr. Wade found an economic injury of $9,814,429. ECF
    No. 422 at 16; ECF No. 441-4 at 12; see also 
    id. at 38
    (suggesting that correction of a
    clerical error would have raised the LIHPRHA FMV appraisal to $6,610,000). In other
    words, Dr. Wade’s analysis suggests that for Buckman Gardens L.P., where the lost
    prepayment right was worth $9,814,429, and the property’s sale price was $6,608,000,
    the prepayment right’s value, alone, exceeded the sale value of the entire property by
    over $3,000,000. In the court’s view, Dr. Wade’s methodology is just as illogical as the
    one criticized in Cienega 
    X. 503 F.3d at 1282
    n.13.
    There are at least two other measures of the severity of the economic losses of the
    FWPs presented by Dr. Wade. One is presented in a table titled: “First Wave Plaintiffs’
    % Reduction in NPV.” ECF No. 441-4 at 21, 69, 219. According to Dr. Wade, NPV is
    “Net Present Value,” the present value of certain cash flows from which the owner’s
    equity in the property has been subtracted. 
    Id. at 12.
    Four of the six properties owned by
    the FWPs are described by Dr. Wade as having lost more than 100 percent of their NPV
    as a result of the alleged taking caused by the Preservation Statutes. 
    Id. at 21.
    This
    sounds impressive, but there is no obvious way to translate this indicator into the
    traditional measure provided by a numerator (property value lost) and a denominator
    (value of the parcel as a whole) that guides this court after Cienega X. 
    See 503 F.3d at 1281
    (citing Concrete 
    Pipe, 508 U.S. at 644
    ). In addition, the court notes that this “%
    27
    Reduction in NPV” indicator is benchmarked to the equity of each FWP in the property,
    not to the value of the parcel as a whole, and therefore is not a proper measure of
    economic severity. 
    See supra
    .
    Another measure of the severity of economic loss is presented by Dr. Wade in a
    table titled: “First Wave Plaintiffs’ Conversion Rate of Return.” ECF No. 441-4 at 61.
    According to Dr. Wade, if the FWPs had been able to convert their properties to market-
    rate rents at the time of the alleged takings, their investment rates of return would have
    been much higher than the 9.6% industry threshold for investments. 
    Id. at 60-61.
    This
    table posits that the FWPs would have earned between 13.3% and 29.9% per year, absent
    the enactment of the Preservation Statues. 
    Id. The “Conversion
    Rate of Return” figures
    are benchmarked to the owner’s equity in the property. 
    Id. at 86,
    97, 110, 129, 140, 151.
    Again, however, this calculation does not compare the value of property lost to the value
    of the parcel as a whole, and is not probative evidence of the severity of the losses of the
    FWPs. Cienega 
    X, 503 F.3d at 1280-82
    .
    Dr. Wade’s methodology is not probative as to economic injury, or the severity of
    economic injury. Plaintiffs have not pointed to sufficient evidence of the economic
    impact of the Preservation Statutes on the FWPs to prevail at trial under Penn Central.
    The court turns next to the specific application of Dr. Wade’s methodology to two
    representative FWPs—Chauncy House and Rock Creek—to examine his economic loss
    findings in more detail.
    b.     Chauncy House – a LIHPRHA Sale Plaintiff
    Dr. Wade finds that Chauncy House experienced an economic loss of $5,106,883.
    ECF No. 441-4 at 12. He notes that the LIHPRHA FMV appraisal value for the property
    was $3,550,000. 
    Id. at 10
    2. The court observes that if $3,550,000 is indeed an accurate
    FMV appraisal of Chauncy House, the mere loss of the prepayment right (but not the
    land, buildings, or income stream from the low-income apartments), is calculated by Dr.
    Wade to exceed the value of the entire property by approximately $1,500,000. As
    applied to Chauncy House, Dr. Wade’s methodology could only be justified if he
    persuasively explained why the LIHPRHA FMV appraisal grossly undervalues Chauncy
    House.
    Dr. Wade does not provide that persuasive explanation in his expert reports.
    Instead, Dr. Wade relies on the LIHPRHA FMV appraisal to calculate the owner’s equity
    in Chauncy House. 
    Id. at 10
    2. In turn, the owner’s equity figure produced by that
    calculation is used to calculate economic loss. 
    Id. at 112.
    In sum, rather than explaining
    why the LIHPRHA FMV appraisal is wrong, Dr. Wade bases his analytical framework
    upon the LIHPRHA FMV appraisal. Either Dr. Wade’s has employed an inaccurate
    LIHPRHA FMV appraisal in his economic loss calculation for Chauncy House, or that
    same LIHPRHA FMV appraisal figure is accurate and demonstrates that Dr. Wade’s
    28
    economic loss figure for Chauncy House is grossly inflated. The court sees no logic in
    Dr. Wade’s economic loss findings regarding Chauncy House.
    c.     Rock Creek – a LIHPRHA Use Agreement Plaintiff
    Including a minor adjustment for completed repairs to the property, Dr. Wade
    again relies on the LIHPRHA FMV appraisal to calculate the owner’s equity in Rock
    Creek at the time of the taking. 
    Id. at 115.
    Once the owner’s equity is established by this
    calculation, Dr. Wade uses the equity figure to calculate economic loss. 
    Id. at 131.
    Thus,
    in support of the economic loss finding of $8,014,386 for Rock Creek, Dr. Wade again
    depends on the accuracy of the LIHPRHA FMV appraisal. In this respect, the use of the
    LIHPRHA FMV appraisal in the Rock Creek analysis reinforces the court’s view that Dr.
    Wade’s reliance on LIHPRHA FMV appraisals contradicts any reasonable inference that
    his Chauncy House economic loss finding is logical.
    Dr. Wade’s economic loss finding for Rock Creek is different, however, than his
    economic loss finding for Chauncy House, because a LIHPRHA use agreement plaintiff’s
    circumstances are not the same as a LIHPRHA sale plaintiff’s circumstances. There is no
    sale figure for Rock Creek. Thus, the $8 million loss figure is not fundamentally illogical
    on the grounds that it cannot be reconciled with a LIHPRHA sale figure. The flaws in
    Dr. Wade’s economic loss finding for Rock Creek are inherent in his methodology:
    (1) There is no comparison of FMVs for Rock Creek, with or without the mortgage
    prepayment right; (2) Dr. Wade does not opine as to the correct pair of FMVs for Rock
    Creek, so that the court could compare those FMVs and perform the first step of the
    analysis required by Independence Park I and Independence Park II; (3) Dr. Wade
    measures economic loss as benchmarked to the owner’s equity in the property, which is
    improper; and (4) Dr. Wade’s measures of the severity of the economic loss for Rock
    Creek, ECF No. 441-4 at 61, 69, are fundamentally flawed and not probative of this issue.
    IV.    Conclusion
    Plaintiff 620 Su Casa Por Cortez lacked distinct investment-backed expectations in
    the mortgage prepayment right allegedly taken by the Preservation Statutes, and its claim
    must be dismissed. All of the First Wave Plaintiffs—Buckman Gardens L.P. (and the
    individual partners in Buckman Gardens), Chauncy House Company, Cedar Gardens
    Associates, Rock Creek Terrace L.P., 620 Su Casa Por Cortez, and 3740 Silverlake
    Village, L.P.—have failed to produce sufficient evidence on the economic impact prong
    of Penn Central to prevail at trial, and their claims must be dismissed. Accordingly,
    (1)    Defendant’s Motion for Summary Judgment, ECF No. 422, is GRANTED;
    (2)    The clerk’s office is directed to CORRECT the docket in Case No. 93-6582
    to change the name of the plaintiff from Silverlake Village, L.P. to 3740
    Silverlake Village, L.P., as explained in footnote 4 of this opinion;
    29
    (3)   For docket clarity, a copy of this opinion shall be filed in each of the six
    member cases;
    (4)   The clerk’s office is directed to ENTER final judgment for defendant and
    DISMISS all of the claims in each of the following member cases, with
    prejudice:
    (a) Buckman Gardens L.P., et al. v. United States, Case No. 97-5837;
    (b) Chauncy House Company v. United States, Case No. 97-5845;
    (c) Cedar Gardens Associates v. United States, Case No. 93-6568;
    (d) Rock Creek Terrace L.P. v. United States, Case No. 93-6578;
    (e) 620 Su Casa Por Cortez v. United States, Case No. 93-6580; and
    (f) 3740 Silverlake Village, L.P. v. United States, Case No. 93-6582;
    (5)   Plaintiffs’ Motion in Limine, ECF No. 430, is DENIED as moot;
    (6)   Defendant’s Motion in Limine, ECF No. 452, is DENIED as moot;
    (7)   The pretrial conference scheduled         for September     27,    2018,   is
    CANCELLED;
    (8)   The trial scheduled for October 15-26, 2018, is CANCELLED; and,
    (9)   On or before October 22, 2018, the parties shall CONFER and FILE a joint
    status report proposing further proceedings in this matter.
    IT IS SO ORDERED.
    s/Patricia Campbell-Smith
    PATRICIA CAMPBELL-SMITH
    Judge
    30