Francis Kaess v. BB Land, LLC ( 2024 )


Menu:
  •                                                                                      FILED
    No. 23-522, Francis Kaess v. BB Land, LLC
    November 14, 2024
    released at 3:00 p.m.
    Walker, Justice, dissenting, and joined by Justice Bunn:                       C. CASEY FORBES, CLERK
    SUPREME COURT OF APPEALS
    OF WEST VIRGINIA
    In this certified question proceeding, the majority opinion applies an implied
    duty to market to an oil and gas lease that contains an in-kind royalty provision. It goes on
    to hold that the requirements for the deductions of post-production expenses from
    Wellman1 and Tawney2 apply to the lease. With respect for my colleagues in the majority,
    I dissent. As explained below, the majority’s analysis does not withstand scrutiny primarily
    because it muddles the distinction between different types of leases. As a result, the
    majority effectively rewrites the leases to take money from the producers to give it to the
    royalty owners. But it is not the province of this Court to rewrite an oil and gas lease to
    1
    See Syl. Pt. 4, Wellman v. Energy Res., Inc., 
    210 W. Va. 200
    , 
    557 S.E.2d 254
    (2001) (“If an oil and gas lease provides for a royalty based on proceeds received by the
    lessee, unless the lease provides otherwise, the lessee must bear all costs incurred in
    exploring for, producing, marketing, and transporting the product to the point of sale.”).
    2
    See Syl. Pt. 10, Estate of Tawney v. Columbia Natural Res., 
    219 W. Va. 266
    , 
    633 S.E.2d 22
     (2006) (“Language in an oil and gas lease that is intended to allocate between
    the lessor and lessee the costs of marketing the product and transporting it to the point of
    sale must expressly provide that the lessor shall bear some part of the costs incurred
    between the wellhead and the point of sale, identify with particularity the specific
    deductions the lessee intends to take from the lessor’s royalty (usually 1/8), and indicate
    the method of calculating the amount to be deducted from the royalty for such post-
    production costs.”).
    1
    reflect the Court’s view of a fair bargain. We certainly would not go to such extreme
    measures to rewrite contracts in any other context.3
    I would have held that for leases that contain an in-kind royalty provision,
    there is no implied duty to market and the requirements of Wellman and Tawney for the
    deductions of post-production expenses are inapplicable. As explained below, the duty to
    market is only triggered when a royalty owner does not or cannot take physical possession
    of its royalty share of the production; when that occurs, the producer must market and sell
    the royalty owner’s share of the production to avoid waste and loss, and the producer may
    properly charge the royalty owner his share of any post-production costs.
    One of the most contentious legal issues in the oil and gas industry is the
    dispute concerning the deductibility of post-production costs from royalty payments owed
    to lessors.4 At the risk of oversimplification, most royalty clauses generally fall into one
    3
    When examining a contract in an employment dispute, this Court stated that: “Our
    task is not to rewrite the terms of contract between the parties; instead, we are to enforce it
    as written.” Fraternal Ord. of Police, Lodge No. 69 v. City of Fairmont, 
    196 W. Va. 97
    ,
    101, 
    468 S.E.2d 712
    , 716 (1996). In the same fashion, we have held parties to a contract
    dispute involving an insurance policy to the plain language in the policy and noted that:
    “‘We will not rewrite the terms of the policy; instead, we enforce it as written.’” Auto Club
    Prop. Cas. Ins. Co. v. Moser, 
    246 W. Va. 493
    , 500, 
    874 S.E.2d 295
    , 302 (2022) (quoting
    Payne v. Weston, 
    195 W. Va. 502
    , 507, 
    466 S.E.2d 161
    , 166 (1995)).
    4
    See William T. Silvia, Slouching Toward Babel: Oklahoma’s First Marketable
    Product Problem, 
    49 Tulsa L. Rev. 583
     (Winter, 2013) (outlining the “minefield of judicial
    interpretations among the major oil and gas-bearing states[,]” including West Virginia);
    Scott Lansdown, The Marketable Condition Rule, 
    44 S. Tex. L. Rev. 667
    , 668-69 (2003)
    2
    of two broad categories: “proceeds” royalty provisions, which provide for the mineral
    owner to receive a royalty consisting of a monetary share of the proceeds the producer
    receives from the sale of the oil and gas produced under the lease, and “in-kind” royalty
    provisions, which provide for the mineral owner to receive a royalty consisting of a portion
    of the physical oil and gas produced, tendered at the wellhead.
    This Court has stated that an oil and gas lease is both a conveyance and a
    contract because it contains “traditional conveyancing portions and the usually separate
    contractual portions.”5 The contractual portions of an oil and gas lease govern the rights
    and responsibilities of the parties.6
    The majority begins on the wrong foot when it states that “this Court is ‘once
    again asked to wade into the waters of postproduction costs[,]’ an expedition that by
    (recognizing the deductibility of post-production costs is a widely litigated issue in the oil
    and gas industry).
    5
    McCullough Oil, Inc. v. Rezek, 
    176 W. Va. 638
    , 642, 
    346 S.E.2d 788
    , 792-93
    (1986); see also Teller v. McCoy, 
    162 W. Va. 367
    , 383, 
    253 S.E.2d 114
    , 124 (1978) (“The
    authorities agree today that the modern lease is both a conveyance and a contract.”).
    6
    Ascent Res. - Marcellus, LLC v. Huffman, 
    244 W. Va. 119
    , 125, 
    851 S.E.2d 782
    ,
    788 (2020); see also Phillip T. Glyptis, Viability of Arbitration Clauses in West Virginia
    Oil and Gas Leases: It Is All About the Lease!!!, 
    115 W. Va. L. Rev. 1005
    , 1007 (2013)
    (“[A] lease is by definition a contract. All rights and protections are controlled by the
    principles of contract law and depend on the proper construction.”).
    3
    necessity begins with a review of our relevant precedents.”7       But the cause of action that
    prompted the certified questions is Mr. Kaess’s claim that BB Land breached their contract
    by improperly deducting post-production costs from his royalties. A breach of contract
    analysis in any context should not begin with industry-specific precedent, but with the
    language of the contract itself. In failing to observe that very basic starting point, what the
    parties actually agreed to is dwarfed into insignificance at the outset.
    When the oil and gas lease is not ambiguous and plainly expresses the intent
    of the parties, then it must be enforced according to that intent. This Court has held that:
    “An oil and gas lease which is clear in its provisions and free from ambiguity, either latent
    or patent, should be considered on the basis of its express provisions and is not subject to
    a practical construction by the parties.”8 As we said in Syllabus Points 1 and 3 of Cotiga
    Development Company v. United Fuel Gas Company,9
    [a] valid written instrument which expresses the intent
    of the parties in plain and unambiguous language is not subject
    to judicial construction or interpretation but will be applied and
    enforced according to such intent.
    It is not the right or province of a court to alter, pervert
    or destroy the clear meaning and intent of the parties as
    7
    Quoting SWN Prod. Co., LLC v. Kellam, 
    247 W. Va. 78
    , 84, 
    875 S.E.2d 216
    , 222
    (2022).
    8
    Syl. Pt. 3, Little Coal Land Co. v. Owens-Illinois Glass Co., 
    135 W. Va. 277
    , 
    63 S.E.2d 528
     (1951).
    9
    
    147 W. Va. 484
    , 
    128 S.E.2d 626
     (1962).
    4
    expressed in unambiguous language in their written contract or
    to make a new or different contract for them.
    Under an oil and gas lease that contains an in-kind royalty clause, the lessor
    owns a share of the actual production at the wellhead. “Where the royalty owner has the
    necessary infrastructure to take physical possession of its royalty share of the production,
    a lessee may discharge its royalty obligations under an in-kind royalty clause by delivering
    the royalty owner’s share of the production directly to the royalty owner.”10 But if the
    royalty owner decides to monetize its royalty, “it may make its own arrangements—on its
    own terms and at its own risk—to sell its share of the production to a third-party
    purchaser.”11 For these reasons, the implied duty to market does not apply to an in-kind
    royalty provision lease and the majority should have answered the first certified question
    in the negative.
    Obviously, not all royalty owners have the infrastructure (wells or tanks or
    pipelines) to store and market their one-eighth share of the oil and gas produced. But the
    majority wrongly concludes that Mr. Kaess’s inability to take his share of the oil and gas
    produced creates an inherent ambiguity in an otherwise straightforward in-kind lease. As
    10
    Byron C. Keeling, Fundamentals of Oil and Gas Royalty Calculation, 54 St.
    Mary’s L.J. 705, 711 (2023) (footnotes omitted).
    11
    
    Id.
    5
    commentator Byron C. Keeling has described, when Mr. Kaess could not take his one-
    eighth share of the oil and gas in kind, BB Land had three possible courses of action:
    If, for whatever reason, a royalty owner does not or
    cannot take physical possession of its royalty share of the
    production under an in-kind royalty clause, then the lessee or
    producer may discharge its royalty obligation to the royalty
    owner in one of several ways:
    (1) The producer may deliver the royalty owner’s share
    of the production to a pipeline purchaser or other third-party
    purchaser near the wellhead—free of cost, and to the royalty
    owner’s credit—under the terms of a division order or other
    contract in which the purchaser pays the royalty owner directly
    for its share of the production.
    (2) The producer may buy the royalty owner’s share of
    the production from the royalty owner on terms that the
    producer negotiates with the royalty owner.
    (3) Or, if the producer does not either buy the royalty
    owner’s share of the production or deliver the royalty owner’s
    share of the production to a purchaser free of cost, then under
    the implied marketing covenant, the producer must market and
    sell the royalty owner’s share of the production—on the royalty
    owners behalf—along with the producer's own share of the
    production.[12]
    Under this commentator’s scenario three, an implied duty to market is
    triggered—to avoid waste and loss—when the producer does not either buy the royalty
    owner’s share of the production or deliver it to a purchaser free of cost. The majority cites
    that portion of Mr. Keeling’s article. But the majority omits the very next paragraph of the
    12
    Id. at 711-12.
    6
    article, which states that the producer may properly charge the royalty owner his share of
    any post-production costs in this scenario:
    If, under the third of these options, the producer sells the
    royalty owner’s share of the oil and gas production, the
    producer must pay the royalty owner the net proceeds that the
    producer received for the royalty owner’s share of the
    production—or, in other words, the producer must pay the
    royalty owner its share of the actual sales price for the oil and
    gas production, minus the royalty owner’s share of the costs
    that the producer incurred to make the production marketable
    and deliver it to the downstream point of sale. Because any
    such sale arises from the implied marketing covenant, the
    producer must market the production in a way that mutually
    benefits both the producer and the royalty owner—typically by
    selling the production for the “best price . . . reasonably
    available.” Nonetheless, the producer may properly charge the
    royalty owner with the royalty owner’s share of any post-
    production costs on the theory that those post-production costs
    enhance the value of the production for the mutual benefit of
    both the producer and the royalty owner.[13]
    Turning to the second certified question—whether the requirements for the
    deductions of postproduction expenses from Wellman and Tawney apply to leases
    containing an in-kind royalty provision—it is unnecessary for me to give an exhaustive
    overview of our caselaw because the majority has done so. It is sufficient to recognize that
    in the landmark ruling of Wellman, this Court examined a proceeds royalty lease that was
    silent on what party would bear post-production costs.14 In Wellman, we established the
    13
    Id. at 711-12 (footnotes omitted and emphasis added).
    14
    
    210 W. Va. at 211
    , 
    557 S.E.2d at 265
    .
    7
    presumption that unless the lease provides otherwise, the lessee bears post-production
    costs, and when we articulated that presumption, we referred specifically to “proceeds”
    leases.15 In Tawney, this Court expanded on Wellman by clarifying the type of language
    that must be included in a lease that contains a proceeds royalty clause before a lessor could
    allocate some, or all, of the post-production expenses to the lessor.16
    As explained above, the contract dispute before the district court in this
    case—unlike Wellman and Tawney—involves a lease that contains an in-kind royalty
    provision.17     For this reason, the requirements for the deductions of postproduction
    expenses from Wellman and Tawney do not apply here and the majority should have
    answered the second certified question in the negative.
    By proclaiming that that Wellman and Tawney apply to all oil and gas leases
    in West Virginia, the majority has lost sight of the fact that the language of the in-kind
    royalty lease controls. Words in the contract matter; when the terms are clear there is no
    reason to resort to an implied covenant. This principle of law applies to oil and gas leases
    just like any other contract. The terms of the lease, including its royalty clause, are freely
    15
    See note 1.
    16
    See note 2.
    17
    As the majority notes, the district court held that by virtue of Mr. Kaess’s failure
    to respond to a request for admission, the court deemed admitted “that the LEASE entitles
    YOU to receive YOUR royalty in-kind, as opposed to a percentage of proceeds received
    by [BB LAND] from the sale of any OIL, GAS, or NGLs.”
    8
    negotiable.18 So, the parties to an oil and gas lease may, if they wish, agree to shift some
    of the costs of production to the lessor in exchange for an increase in the royalty interest
    that he is entitled to receive on production.19
    The majority goes further off course when it devotes pages to its fascination
    with Leggett’s20 criticism of Wellman and Tawney—as well as Kellam’s21 criticism of
    Leggett—along with the legislative history of West Virginia Code § 22-6-8 (a statute that
    deals with flat-rate leases22). This discussion offers nothing useful to the questions
    presented. And this walk down memory lane reveals the majority’s motive for engaging
    in this endeavor when it grasps ahold of this controversy to declare, by judicial fiat, that
    “the Legislature’s extension of Wellman and Tawney to leases containing flat-rate royalty
    provisions [is] a persuasive indicator that those precedents should govern leases containing
    in-kind royalty provisions as well.” Indeed, the majority “discern[s] no principled basis on
    which to hold that in-kind leases are somehow different[,]” to flat-rate leases. But if the
    18
    See Jeff King, Natural Gas Royalties: Lessors vs. Lessee and the Implied
    Covenant to Market, 63 Tex. Bar J. 854 (2000) (“Oil and gas leases are negotiated
    contracts.”).
    19
    Id. (“As to the royalty amount, the parties to the lease are free to decide and define
    the type, basis, or standard for the royalties to be paid.”) (citations omitted).
    20
    Leggett v. EQT Prod. Co., 
    239 W. Va. 264
    , 
    800 S.E.2d 850
     (2017).
    21
    SWN Prod. Co., LLC v. Kellam, 
    247 W. Va. 78
    , 
    875 S.E.2d 216
     (2022).
    22
    Flat-rate leases require the producer to pay the royalty owner a set royalty per
    well, per year, whether that well produces oil and gas or not.
    9
    Legislature intended West Virginia Code § 22-6-8’s protections to include freely
    negotiated in-kind royalty provision leases, it certainly would have said so.
    The majority’s sweeping holding is audacious—three members of the
    majority have now commandeered thousands of leases across the State for judicial
    revision—and its damaging impact on this institution’s legitimacy will be felt for years to
    come. Its decision cannot be justified by the parties’ written agreement. It cannot be
    justified by our case law. Nor is there any authority for extending the Legislature’s
    statutory protections for royalty owners who hold flat-rate leases to those who hold in-kind
    royalty leases. Because I find no authority for the invasion into the right to contract that
    the majority now commits, I dissent. I am authorized to state that Justice Bunn joins in this
    dissent.
    10
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 23-522

Filed Date: 11/14/2024

Precedential Status: Separate Opinion

Modified Date: 11/14/2024