DocketNumber: 79-2468
Citation Numbers: 637 F.2d 105, 1980 U.S. App. LEXIS 12617
Judges: Aldisert, Sloviter, Rambo
Filed Date: 11/3/1980
Status: Precedential
Modified Date: 11/4/2024
The major question for decision in this appeal by unsuccessful plaintiffs in an antitrust action is whether they established a prima facie case of a “contract, combination, ... or conspiracy, in restraint of trade ...” in violation of § 1 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 1. Sweeney, a wholesale and retail distributor of Texaco fuels, and two of its wholesale customers attempted to prove that Texaco unlawfully conspired with other fuel distributors and retailers to fix the retail price of Texaco motor fuel. Determining that appellants had failed to introduce evidence from which a jury could infer the existence of a conspiracy, the district court directed a verdict in favor of Texaco.
The district court also directed a verdict against appellants on their claims that Texaco violated § 2 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 2, and § 2(a) of the Clayton Act, as amended by the Robinson-Patman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 13(a). In addition, the district court dismissed damage claims against Texaco raised by Mission Gas Oil Company and Petroleum Products Company. The court granted Texaco’s prayer for injunctive and declaratory relief against Sweeney concerning Sweeney’s practice of misrepresenting non-Texaco fuel as Texaco fuel. Sweeney, Mission, and Petroleum Products appeal these adverse rulings. We conclude that the district court did not err and, therefore, we affirm.
I.
We need recite only those facts essential to this appeal because of the extensive elaboration already undertaken by the district court. Edward J. Sweeney & Sons, Inc. v. Texaco, Inc., 478 F.Supp. 243, 249-51 (E.D. Pa.1979). Appellant Edward J. Sweeney & Sons, Inc., is a wholesaler and distributor of Texaco motor fuels in Eastern Pennsylvania and Southern New Jersey. In addition to its wholesale business Sweeney owns several retail gasoline stations. Mission Gas Oil Company, Inc., and Petroleum Products Company are distributors who purchase fuel from Sweeney. The defendant Texaco, Inc., refines and sells gasoline and other petroleum products.
After several years as a consignee and wholesaler for other companies, Sweeney became a Texaco wholesaler and distributor in 1958. In 1963 Sweeney and Texaco entered into the distributor agreement at the heart of this' litigation. Part of the agreement provided that Sweeney would haul its own fuel. When it sells motor fuel to distributors, Texaco charges a price that includes the cost of delivering the product to the distributor’s bulk plant. If the distributor picks up fuel at Texaco’s plant, however, as Sweeney did, it receives a discount or hauling allowance. The discount equals the lowest amount it would cost Texaco to deliver the fuel from a designated distribution point to the purchaser’s bulk plant by common carrier, contract carrier, or Texaco company truck. Texaco initially designated its terminal in Westville, New Jersey, as Sweeney’s pick-up point. Accordingly, Sweeney received a hauling allowance equal to the common carrier rate for trips between Westville and its bulk plant located in Pottstown, Pennsylvania.
Sweeney used the hauling allowance to its advantage. Between 1965 and 1970 Sweeney acquired several retail gasoline stations in addition to ones it already owned. The newly acquired stations were located within a twenty mile radius of Texaco’s Westville, New Jersey, terminal. Sweeney picked up fuel in Westville and transported it directly to these stations. This practice enabled Sweeney to receive an allowance for hauling fuel from Westville to Pottstown, roughly fifty miles, while hauling it less than twenty miles. Receiving the greater allowance effectively lowered Sweeney’s cost for gasoline which in turn allowed Sweeney to lower its retail prices.
Use of the hauling allowance was just one part of Sweeney’s retail marketing strategy. A second major part was “no-frills” retailing. Prior to 1965, Sweeney’s retail stations offered complete automobile
Sweeney’s prosperity did not augur well with competing Texaco retailers. Beginning in 1966, some of these retailers complained to Texaco that Sweeney’s discount pricing was hurting their businesses. Sweeney contends that Texaco conspired with these retailers to terminate Sweeney’s distributorship or to reduce its hauling allowance and thereby force Sweeney to raise its prices. Sweeney cites Texaco’s actions in 1970 and 1971 as evidence of this alleged conspiracy.
The evidence disclosed that as early as 1966 Texaco had reviewed the status of Sweeney’s hauling agreement. Texaco found that it could save at least $2,158 annually by supplying Sweeney from Macungie, Pennsylvania, rather than from Westville, New Jersey, due to Macungie’s proximity to the Sweeney plant. When it learned of Texaco’s consideration of a change to Macungie, Sweeney objected and Texaco postponed its decision on the matter.
By 1970, the economics of supplying Sweeney out of Westville had changed drastically. Instead of $2,158, Texaco’s loss attributable to supplying Sweeney from Westville had risen to more than $58,000 annually. Texaco informed Sweeney in December, 1970, that it was changing Sweeney’s supply point from Westville to Macungie under a provision in the hauling agreement permitting Texaco to terminate the agreement or to changé the pick-up point. Nevertheless, Sweeney refused to go along with the change to Macungie. Texaco then notified Sweeney that it was terminating Sweeney’s distributor and hauling agreements in sixty days, effective February 28, 1971.
After it received the termination notice, Sweeney attempted but failed to obtain an alternate source of supply. Sweeney then negotiated with Texaco. As a result of the negotiations, Sweeney’s distributor’s agreement was not terminated and the parties agreed on a compromise hauling arrangement on March 1, 1971.
Under the new hauling agreement, Sweeney continued to pick up at Westville until May 31, 1971, and received the allowance it had been getting for the distance from Westville to Pottstown. Thereafter, Sweeney picked up fuel at Macungie and received a hauling allowance based on the Macungie to Pottstown rate. Texaco also agreed that after May 31, 1971, Sweeney could pick up fuel at either location, at Sweeney’s option, although the hauling allowance for all purchases would be based on the Macungie to Pottstown trip. This agreement mitigated the effect of the change in the hauling allowance by permitting Sweeney to continue supplying its southern New Jersey stations from nearby Westville.
After this new hauling agreement became effective, Sweeney began delivering non-Texaco fuel to Texaco brand stations in trucks bearing the Texaco trademark. Texaco learned of Sweeney’s commingling and conducted a thorough investigation of Sweeney’s operations using Texaco security personnel. The investigation confirmed Texaco’s suspicion of Sweeney’s pervasive trademark violations.
On December 17, 1971, Daniel A. Doherty, Texaco’s Manager for the Philadelphia Region, told Texaco’s Vice President of Sales, United States, of his decision to terminate Sweeney’s distributor and hauling agreements. Doherty based his decision primarily on Sweeney’s trademark violations and misrepresentations. In addition, Doherty explained that Sweeney’s stations failed to maintain Texaco’s brand integrity,
Texaco notified Sweeney that effective February 29, 1972, it would terminate both the 1963 distributor agreement and the March 1, 1971, hauling agreement. Although Sweeney tried again to obtain an alternate source of supply, it was again unsuccessful. After various negotiations, Texaco agreed to supply Sweeney until it gave a ten day notice of its intention to discontinue Sweeney’s supply. No termination notice has been given, and Texaco continues to provide Sweeney with fuel.
The present litigation followed these events. Sweeney charged that Texaco conspired in violation of § 1 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 1, with the dealers who complained about Sweeney’s competitive practices. It also alleged that Texaco violated § 2 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 2, by attempting to monopolize the sale of Texaco fuel. Finally, Sweeney averred that Texaco discriminated against it in the price Texaco charged for fuel and thereby violated § 2(a) of the Clayton Act as amended by the Robinson-Patman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 13(a). Mission Gas Oil Company and Petroleum Products Company, two of Sweeney’s wholesale customers, joined in Sweeney’s lawsuit. Plaintiffs sought damages and injunctive relief. Texaco counterclaimed against Sweeney seeking injunctive and declaratory relief from Sweeney’s commingling practices, basing its claims on various state, federal, and common law provisions. The district court dismissed Mission’s and Petroleum’s damage claims on the ground that they were improper plaintiffs because they did not purchase fuel directly from Texaco. After the close of the evidence the district court directed a verdict denying all of appellants’ remaining claims and granting Texaco’s prayer for injunctive and declaratory relief. Appellants challenge these adverse rulings.
II.
The only § 1 contention before us is appellants’ claim that certain Texaco dealers conspired with Texaco to have Texaco terminate Sweeney as a distributor or to reduce its hauling allowance.
Unilateral action, no matter what its motivation, cannot violate § 1. United
To establish the existence of concerted action, appellants had to submit evidence from which a jury could reasonably infer that Texaco and others had a conscious commitment to a common scheme designed to achieve an unlawful objective. Klein v. American Luggage Works, Inc., 323 F.2d 787, 791 (3d Cir. 1963); United States v. Standard Oil Co., 316 F.2d 884, 890 (7th Cir. 1963). Direct proof of an express agreement is not required. On the contrary, the plaintiff may rely on an inference of a common understanding drawn from circumstantial evidence: “The picture of conspiracy as a meeting by twilight of a trio of sinister persons with pointed hats close together belongs to a darker age.” William Goldman Theatres v. Loew’s, Inc., 150 F.2d 738, 743 n.15 (3d Cir. 1945). Nevertheless, appellants had the burden of adducing sufficient evidence from which the jury could find illegal concerted action on the basis of reasonable inferences and not mere speculation. Venzie Corp. v. United States Mineral Products Co., 521 F.2d 1309, 1312 (3d Cir. 1975).
The necessary first step toward appellants’ proof of a prohibited § 1 conspiracy was proof of a causal relationship between competitor complaints that Sweeney was selling Texaco gasoline several cents below their own price, and the reduction of Sweeney’s hauling allowance. Cernuto, Inc. v. United Cabinet Corp., 595 F.2d 164, 168 (3d Cir. 1979). The mere reception of complaints by Texaco would be insufficient to prove this causal nexus. Nor would it suffice to prove only that some Texaco employees who knew of the complaints were also the ones who decided to terminate Sweeney’s distributor agreement and change its hauling allowance.
Appellants claim that they submitted sufficient evidence to allow an inference of illegal concerted action. They point to testimony that beginning in 1966 or 1967 and continuing through 1979 some lessees of stations owned by Texaco complained to the refiner that certain stations supplied by Sweeney were marketing gasoline two or three cents per gallon lower than their prices. To establish their point, appellants relied on the testimony of several witnesses, but especially that of James P. Rodden, Daniel A. Doherty, and Glenn B. Murray.
A.
Rodden is a former Texaco sales representative who left Texaco to become a part
Rodden testified that he “believed” Texaco changed Sweeney’s hauling allowance because of the retailer complaints about the loss of volume at Texaco’s retail stations. Rodden admitted, however, that his “belief” was just unsupported surmise, without factual basis. App. at 842a-46a. The district court determined that the surmise of Rod-den “cannot, as a matter of law, support a jury finding of a contract, combination, or conspiracy between Texaco and other Texaco dealers either in 1970 or 1971.” 478 F.Supp. at 255. We agree. In our view, Rodden’s testimony goes no further than merely identifying retailer complaints. We turn now to other possible evidence of concerted action.
B.
Appellants argue that proof of concerted action was also forthcoming from the testimony of Daniel A. Doherty, the manager of Texaco’s Philadelphia region. Appellants assert that Doherty made the actual decision to terminate Sweeney’s distributorship, “basing his decision partially on Sweeney’s marketing strategy.” Appellants’ Brief at 18.
Doherty’s testimony provides no help to Sweeney’s theory. On June 8, 1979, appellants introduced the following deposition testimony of Doherty:
Q. Were you aware that Sweeney was a price-cutter in the area?
A. I was aware that Sweeney was engaging in a marketing strategy where the principal attraction of those retail outlets that he supplied was primarily, if not exclusively, based upon posting a price generally lower than major brand price in the areas.
App. at 1162a.
Q. What factors entered into your decision to terminate Sweeney as the distributor?
A. Sweeney’s marketing strategy that I observed and the consequences of it that I observed ....
Q. Is that the marketing strategy referred to previously?
A. There [were] other elements of it.
A. As a consequence of the kinds of retail operations that Sweeney apparently solicited and acquired wherein the .. . primary business builder of the locations was a low, highly competitive retail price, the outlets to a concerning if not alarming degree did not meet the standards of housekeeping, service, or service capability. In addition to that, we received continuing customer complaints from Texaco customers and motorist customers and, more alarmingly, the best class of customer that we had was being impacted very heavily, and that was our credit card customers, because my memory is that his retail outlets were involved in credit card irregularities and it was apparent that Sweeney’s ... marketing strategy, relied entirely on having the lowest or one of the lowest prices, which is entirely his prerogative, the prerogative of those people he serviced. But, the trend away from the prestige service that had been the hallmark and the objectives of Texaco retail marketing, certainly from my entire career, was clear, and was adversely impacting, in our opinion, on the entire brand integrity of Texaco in the area.
Id. at 1602a-03a.
On June 13, 1979, appearing in open court, Doherty stated during cross examination by Sweeney’s counsel:
*113 Q. Now, did you discuss the fact Mr. Sweeney was a price cutter with Mr. Hicks, prior to Sweeney’s termination?
. A. I made the point yesterday, Mr. Kramer, that I never regarded Sweeney as a price cutter because I knew nothing about Sweeney’s pricing. I don’t know what he sold his retail for, so I couldn’t characterize him as a price cutter. I never have.
Q. Now Mr. Doherty, isn’t it a fact that at the time of your deposition you said that one of the factors among many .. . that entered into your consideration to terminate Sweeney was the pricing practices of the Sweeney supplied stations?
A. No, sir.
Q. So, you’re still saying that pricing in your view had no effect on your decision?
A. Yes, sir.
App. at 1593a, 1605a-06a.
Appellants suggest that this testimony provided the quantum of evidence necessary to get their case to the jury. Appellants’ best case is Doherty’s deposition statement that Sweeney’s distributorship was terminated because of Sweeney’s marketing strategy. That strategy, Sweeney maintains, was, in Doherty’s words, “based upon posting a price generally lower than major brand prices in the area.” But Doherty immediately explained that he included other elements of the “marketing strategy and the consequences of it.” He emphasized that Sweeney “relied entirely on having the lowest or one of the lowest prices, which is entirely his [Sweeney’s] prerogative, the prerogative of those people he serviced.” Id. at 1162a (emphasis added).
Viewed in the light most favorable to the appellants, only three reasonable and permissible inferences relevant to Sweeney’s lawsuit flow from this testimony. First, Texaco did not object to Sweeney’s low prices. Pricing was “entirely” Sweeney’s prerogative. Second, Texaco’s concern over Sweeney’s marketing strategy grew out of Sweeney’s failure to meet housekeeping, service, or service capability standards-practices contrary to “the prestige service that had been the hallmark and objective of Texaco retail marketing”-and resulting customer complaints. Third, these concerns led Doherty to the decision to terminate Sweeney’s distributorship.
Appellants maintain that the jury should have been permitted to infer from this testimony that Doherty decided to terminate Sweeney because Texaco received complaints from Sweeney’s competitors that Sweeney was underselling them. This inference is impermissible. In both his deposition and in court, Doherty testified that although he was generally aware of Sweeney’s pricing policies, he did not consider these policies unacceptable except insofar as they adversely affected Sweeney’s customer service. In his deposition he stated flatly that pricing was Sweeney’s prerogative. Appellants would have the jury infer that Doherty’s asserted explanation was mere pretense and that Doherty actually terminated Sweeney’s agreement as part of an illegal scheme. Absent some evidence supporting appellants’ theory, we will not assume Doherty lied about his reasons. The district court correctly prevented the jury from speculating on the existence of a conspiracy on the basis of such meager evidence.
C.
Appellants also rely on Glenn B. Murray’s testimony, arguing that Murray’s belief “that Texaco had terminated Sweeney because of Sweeney’s competitive abilities as against other Texaco retailers and wholesalers” supports their § 1 claim. Appellants’ Brief at 17. An examination of portions of the record relied on by appellants discloses no evidence in support of this argument:
Q. I take it from your testimony that you have no personal knowledge of why Texaco wanted to terminate Sweeney?
A. [N]o direct personal knowledge, no.
Q. Tell us what, if any, knowledge you do have, whether it is direct or indirect?
*114 A. Well, it would be just the general feeling that E. J. Sweeney and Sons had literally expanded their operation [to] the point where they were picking up product in Westville and delivering it virtually next door in some instances, well within ten miles, 15, 20 miles of the terminal, and being granted hauling allowances for [the] distance up to Pottstown. And, as a result, they were in a much better competitive position than others would have been.
App. at 1347a-48a.
We cannot conclude that Murray’s testimony, alone or in conjunction with that of others, made out a jury case of concerted action. Murray’s testimony did not refer to complaints of price cutting or of Texaco’s response to such complaints. His testimony, admittedly not based on personal knowledge, was entitled to little or no weight by the trial judge. The “general feeling” he expressed concerning Sweeney’s competitive position cannot support an inference of concerted action or buttress any inferences of concerted action drawn from other testimony.
Putting aside the testimony of Rodden, Doherty, Murray and the others on which appellants rely,
Moreover, the record indicates that the complaints began in 1966, five years before the acts in question, and continued until 1979, eight years after Texaco altered the agreements with Sweeney. There is no evidence showing the frequency of the complaints or whether the frequency changed at any time. These facts militate strongly against a causal relation between the complaints and Texaco’s actions. Furthermore, the change in Sweeney’s hauling allowance was less than one cent per gallon.
Appellants urge that Cernuto, Inc. v. United Cabinet Corp., 595 F.2d 164 (3d Cir. 1979), requires a different result. We agree with the district court that it does not. Appellants argue that Cernuto stands for the proposition that when a manufacturer terminates a distributor’s supply because of complaints from other distributors concerning price cutting, these actions make out a § 1 claim without proof of concerted action. Appellants’ Brief at 22-23. We reject this interpretation. Cernuto decided simply that cut-off distributors in these circumstances need not prove anti-competitive effects to prevail in a § 1 lawsuit. Such action “per se” unreasonably restrains trade. 595 F.2d at 170.
If Cernuto can prove at trial that United, Lappin and Famous conspired to protect Famous from price competition by Cernuto, and that United and Lappin terminated Cernuto at Famous’ request and in pursuit of a price related end, then it can prevail on a price-fixing theory notwithstanding its failure to show any impact on competition involving kitchen cabinet sales in Western Pennsylvania. Of course, at trial the defendants may be able to demonstrate that the evidence does not at all conform to what plaintiff has alleged.
595 F.2d at 170 (emphasis added). Cf. Theatre Enterprises, Inc. v. Paramount Film Distributing Corp., 346 U.S. 537, 541, 74 S.Ct. 257, 259, 98 L.Ed. 273 (1954) (“Circumstantial evidence of consciously parallel behavior may have made heavy inroads into the traditional judicial attitude toward conspiracy; but ‘conscious parallelism’ has not yet read conspiracy out of the act entirely.”).
We agree with the district court that aside from the evidence of complaints made to Texaco by other retailers, Sweeney introduced no evidence of a conspiracy between Texaco and its retailers or wholesalers. In the absence of evidence that Texaco decided to terminate Sweeney because of competitor complaints and evidence of such a conspiracy, it would have been improper for the court to allow the jury to speculate on the cause for Texaco’s action.
D.
The teachings of the Supreme Court are clear on when a matter may be submitted to the jury:
The matter is essentially one to be worked out in particular situations and for particular types of cases. Whatever may be the general formulation, the essential requirement is that mere speculation not be allowed to do duty for probative facts, after making due allowance for all reasonably possible inferences favoring the party whose case is attacked.
Galloway v. United States, 319 U.S. 372, 395, 63 S.Ct. 1077, 1089, 87 L.Ed. 1458 (1943). A reviewing court applies the same standard to a decision by a trial judge granting a motion for directed verdict. The appellate court must consider the record as a whole and in the light most favorable to the non-moving party, drawing all reasonable inferences to support its contentions. If no reasonable resolution of the conflicting evidence and inferences therefrom could result in a judgment for the non-moving party, the appellate court must affirm the lower court’s decision. See Columbia Metal Culvert Co., Inc. v. Kaiser Aluminum and Chemical Corp., 579 F.2d 20 (3d Cir.), cert. denied, 439 U.S. 876, 99 S.Ct. 214, 58 L.Ed.2d 190 (1979).
The jury’s role in our legal tradition probably represents modern America’s unique characteristic in the trial of civil cases. Its role cannot be minimized, nor its importance dissipated one iota. Yet the limits of the jury’s role must always be recognized. The jury translates as found fact a congeries of relevant evidence on controverted factual issues. The jury does not engage in
The court’s role is especially crucial when, as here, the plaintiff’s case, and therefore the defendant’s liability, is based solely on circumstantial evidence. The illegal action must be inferred from the facts shown at trial. Inferred factual conclusions based on circumstantial evidence are permitted only when, and to the extent that, human experience indicates a probability that certain consequences can and do follow from the basic circumstantial facts. The inferences that the court permits the jury to educe in a courtroom do not differ significantly from inferences that rational beings reach daily in informally accepting a probability or arriving at a conclusion when presented with some hard, or basic evidence. A court permits the jury to draw inferences because of this shared experience in human endeavors. See generally, McCormick, Handbook of the Law of Evidence 289-96 (2d edition 1972). Perhaps the only distinction between extracting factual conclusions from circumstantial evidence in daily life and in the courtroom is that a jury’s act of drawing or not drawing an inference is preceded by a judge’s instruction. The instruction serves to guide the jury through some process of ordered consideration. The court informs the jury that it must weigh the narrative or historical evidence presented, making credibility findings when appropriate, and then draw only those inferences that are reasonable in reaching a verdict.
When a trial court grants a directed verdict in a circumstantial evidence case, the court makes a legal determination that the narrative or historical matters in evidence allow no permissible inference of the ultimate fact urged by the opposing party. It decides that no reasonable person could reach the suggested conclusion on the basis of the hard evidence without resorting to guesswork or conjecture. To permit a jury to draw an inference of the ultimate fact under these circumstances is to substitute the experience of logical probability for what the courts describe as “mere speculation.” Galloway v. United States, 319 U.S. at 395, 63 S.Ct. at 1089; Columbia Metal Culvert Co. v. Kaiser Aluminum & Chemical Corp., 579 F.2d at 25.
Logicians describe one process of reaching an ultimate fact from insufficient basic facts as the false cause or post hoc fallacy. The fallacy consists of reasoning from sequence to consequence, that is, assuming a causal connection between two events merely because one follows the other. For this reason the fallacy is often referred to as that ofepost hoc ergo propter hoc (after this and therefore in consequence of this), an expression which itself explains the nature of the error.
Here, the district court properly concluded that the basic facts adduced at trial were insufficient to allow the jury to find for appellants. The basic record facts were that some of Sweeney’s competitors complained that Sweeney’s stations undersold them by one to three cents per gallon, that Rodden did not know but “guessed” Texaco acted to terminate Sweeney because of these complaints, that Murray surmised Texaco was evaluating Sweeney’s ability to get long hauling allowances for short deliveries, and that certain consequences of Sweeney’s marketing strategy not directly related to Sweeney’s competitive position figured into Doherty’s decision to terminate Sweeney. Faced with this scanty record, the district court properly removed the issue of concerted action from the jury. It determined that insufficient narrative or historical evidence had been submitted to permit the conclusion that Texaco’s decision was a reaction to the specific complaints received. Moreover, the record was devoid of proof of concerted action among Swee
III.
The district court also directed a verdict for Texaco on appellants’ claims that Texaco attempted or conspired to monopolize the Texaco gasoline market in violation of § 2 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 2. The court explained that “Sweeney has failed to produce any evidence from which a jury could find that Texaco gasoline constitutes a product market for § 2 purposes.” 478 F.Supp. at 267. We find appellants’ contentions on this issue devoid of merit.
First, we hold an antitrust plaintiff in an appeal to the theory advanced at trial. There, Sweeney represented, and properly so, that the focal point of any discussion of its § 2 damage claims is the issue of relevant market. By letter dated May 24, 1979, Sweeney agreed that
if a court and/or jury in [Sweeney v. Texaco] does not determine that a relevant product market or submarket is limited to “Texaco gasoline,” then Texaco has not violated Section 2 of the Sherman Act.
We will not permit appellants to repudiate that agreement. See American Motor Inns, Inc. v. Holiday Inns, Inc., 521 F.2d 1230, 1246 (3d Cir. 1975) (“AMI will be bound by its own analysis in open court of the issues to be litigated.”).
Moreover, the theory of Ninth Circuit cases cited by Sweeney to support its argument-Greyhound Computer Corp. v. International Business Machines Corp., 559 F.2d 488 (9th Cir. 1977), cert. denied, 434 U.S. 1040, 98 S.Ct. 782, 54 L.Ed.2d 790 (1978), and Lessig v. Tidewater Oil Co., 327 F.2d 459 (9th Cir.), cert. denied, 377 U.S. 993, 84 S.Ct. 1920, 12 L.Ed.2d 1046 (1964)-was rejected by this court in Coleman Motor Co. v. Chrysler Corp., 525 F.2d 1338 (3d Cir. 1975). Coleman expressly held that definition of the relevant market was critical in § 2 attempt cases, specifically repudiating the Ninth Circuit view that it is possible to find an attempt to monopolize without such proof. Id. at 1348 n.17.
To establish that Texaco gasoline alone constituted a relevant market or sub-market, appellants had to prove that Texaco gasoline was not considered reasonably interchangeable with other brands of gasoline and non-branded gasoline by a significantly large number of consumers. Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 325, 82 S.Ct. 1502, 1524, 8 L.Ed.2d 510 (1962); United States v. E. I. duPont de Nemours & Co., 351 U.S. 377, 393, 395, 399-400, 76 S.Ct. 994, 1006, 1007, 1009, 100 L.Ed. 1264 (1956); Columbia Metal Culvert Co. v. Kaiser Aluminum & Chemical Corp., 579 F.2d at 26-27. There must be evidence, for example, of “industry or public recognition of the submarket as a separate economic entity, the product’s peculiar characteristics and uses, unique production facilities, distinct customers, distinct prices, sensitivity to price changes, and specialized vendors.” Brown Shoe, 370 U.S. at 325, 82 S.Ct. at 1524; Columbia Metal, 579 F.2d at 27. Appellants offered no such evidence.
The evidence mandates the conclusion that the range of commodities “reasonably interchangeable by consumers for the same purposes” includes all brands of gasoline and that there are no product submarkets. By Sweeney’s own assertion, gasoline is a fungible commodity. Sweeney itself continually bought gasoline from other refiners. Moreover, uncontradicted testimony indicated that Sweeney’s gas stations competed not only with Texaco stations, but also with other brand and non-brand stations. Similarly, the record shows that Sweeney competed with other wholesalers offering non-Texaco fuel. App. at 620a-31a, 735a-37a, 760a, 855a-56a, 916a-18a, 957a-62a. Paraphrasing the conclusion by Judge, now Justice, Stevens in Mullis v. Arco Petroleum Corp., 502 F.2d 290, 296-97 (7th Cir. 1974) (footnote omitted): “Under the kind of economic analysis employed by both the majority and the dissent in United
Appellants contend that the value of the Texaco trademark establishes Texaco gasoline as a separate relevant submarket. They also contend that because Texaco stations can only sell Texaco fuel a product submarket exists for them. Accepting these arguments would lead to the conclusion that every manufacturer of a trademarked product has monopoly power over that product. No legal precept stands for this proposition, as the Supreme Court has emphatically held:
[0]ne can theorize that we have monopolistic competition in every nonstandardized commodity with each manufacturer having power of the price and production of his own product. However, this power that, let us say, automobile or soft-drink manufacturers have over their trademarked products is not the power that makes an illegal monopoly. Illegal power must be appraised in terms of the competitive market for the product.
United States v. E.I. duPont de Nemours & Co., 351 U.S. at 393, 76 S.Ct. at 1006 (footnote omitted). See also, Columbia Metal, 579 F.2d at 27 n.11.
If, on the other hand, the relevant market is all motor fuel sold in the area of Sweeney’s stations, Texaco could not monopolize that market by driving Sweeney out of business. The retail price of Texaco gasoline sold by Sweeney’s competitors and wholesale prices of Texaco fuel were determined to a large extent by market conditions of supply and demand involving all brand and non-brand gasoline. Competition from other refiners and independent dealers would severely limit Texaco’s ability to succeed. See Coleman, 525 F.2d at 1348-49.
Accordingly, we agree with the district court that appellants produced no evidence demonstrating that Texaco gasoline was not easily interchanged with other gasoline and constituted a separate product market. Nor can it be inferred that Texaco intended to monopolize the entire gasoline market in southern New Jersey. The § 2 claim alleging conspiracy to monopolize cannot prevail because of appellants’ failure to establish a conspiracy, as discussed above. Thus appellants’ § 2 claim was properly removed from the jury’s consideration.
IV.
Sweeney alleged violations by Texaco of § 2(a) of the Clayton Act, as amended by the Robinson-Patman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 13(a), and asked for both damages and injunctive relief.
Although Sweeney has never clarified the theory underlying its Robinson-Patman Act claim, in essence it contends that by changing the gasoline pickup point from West-ville to Macungie, Texaco effectively imposed a discriminatory price on it. Sweeney alleges discrimination by comparing the price charged it to two different prices: the effective price of gasoline to it before the change of pickup points and the effective price of gasoline to other distributors whose bulk storage facilities were located farther from their pickup points. Sweeney’s claim is more confusing because it has not explained whether the attack is on the hauling allowance system as a per se violation of the Robinson-Patman Act, or on the appliction of the system to Sweeney. Neither of these alternative theories for recovery states a violation of the act.
Under the Robinson-Patman Act, price discrimination requires “at least two completed sales by the same seller at differential prices to different purchasers.” S.C. Oppenheim & G. Weston, Unfair Trade Practices and Consumer Protection: Cases and Comments 816 (1974); see Utah Pie Co. v. Continental Baking Co., 386 U.S. 685, 702, 87 S.Ct. 1326, 1335, 18 L.Ed.2d 406 (1967). The proper comparison for determining whether a price discrimination has occurred is between the prices charged to two different customers. We therefore reject Sweeney’s argument that it has shown improper discrimination merely by showing that Texaco charged it a different effective price at two distinct points in time.
Sweeney argues that the formula for calculating the hauling allowance, though available on equal terms to all distributors, resulted in price discrimination because the effective price of gasoline varied from purchaser to purchaser. The variations in price arose because Texaco calculated the hauling allowance based on the differing distances between each distributor’s bulk plant and Texaco’s pickup point, using the lowest rate from among common carrier, contract carrier, or Texaco delivery truck. Complications arose because distributors frequently did not travel the full distance, but instead delivered the gasoline directly from Texaco’s pickup point to nearby retail stations. This practice allowed distributors, including Sweeney, to travel fewer miles than the hauling allowance compensated them for. The most advantaged distributors, therefore, were the ones with bulk plants far distant from the pickup point, but with retail stations close to the pickup point.
Sweeney’s indictment of the hauling allowance system apparently concentrates on two separate aspects. First, Sweeney alleges that by changing its pickup point from Westville to Macungie, Texaco eliminated its locational advantage and put it at a disadvantage with respect to other distribu
A'.
Under our analysis, the first argument merges into the second. Sweeney does not allege, and introduced no evidence to substantiate, that Texaco deviated from its hauling allowance formula by switching his pickup point from Westville, far from Sweeney’s storage facility, to Macungie, much closer to his storage facility. We are faced, therefore, with a hauling allowance formula, uniform in structure and application, that produces differentials in the effective price of gasoline sold to Texaco distributors. Sweeney’s first argument alleges no more than that the formula produced a higher effective price to him than to other distributors. The first argument cannot succeed unless we are persuaded that uniform application of the formula violates the act.
B.
The attack on the hauling allowance system assumes that such a system discriminates merely because it results in a different effective price to each distributor. Although the Supreme Court has said that “a price discrimination within the meaning of that provision is merely a price difference,” FTC v. Anheuser-Busch, Inc., 363 U.S. 536, 549, 80 S.Ct. 1267, 1274, 4 L.Ed.2d 1385 (1960), the business reality of distributing gasoline over a large geographic region militates against elevating this isolated passage to an all-inclusive definition.
We are persuaded by the Second Circuit’s reasoning in FLM Collision Parts, Inc. v. Ford Motor Co., 543 F.2d 1019 (2d Cir. 1976), cert. denied, 429 U.S. 1097, 97 S.Ct. 1116, 51 L.Ed.2d 545 (1977), which supports Texaco’s position that a uniform pricing formula applicable to all customers is not a price discrimination under the act. In FLM, Ford charged different prices to its parts customers according to the function, such as retail, wholesale, or repair, that each customer performed. In concluding that this practice was not a price discrimination under the Robinson-Patman Act, the court reasoned that the dual price was available, not only in theory but in fact, to all purchasers. It concluded that
the Act . .. requires equality of treatment among purchasers, but it does not require a seller to adopt a single uniform price under all circumstances. . . . This principle has been applied in cases which found no violation of § 2(a) in pricing plans which, though varying prices according to different terms of sale, were administered equally to all purchasers.
Id. at 1026 (citations omitted). We hold, therefore, that Sweeney has failed to establish that the hauling allowance formula discriminates in violation of the Robinson-Pat-man Act.
Our holding is not inconsistent with prior Supreme Court decisions that have found pricing formulas violative of the act. In FTC v. Morton Salt Co., 334 U.S. 37, 68 S.Ct. 822, 92 L.Ed. 1196 (1948), the Court held that Morton Salt’s quantity discount system violated the act because the largest discounts were actually unavailable to the great majority of Morton’s customers. Id. at 42-43, 68 S.Ct. at 826; see also Mueller Co. v. FTC, 323 F.2d 44, 46 (7th Cir. 1963), cert. denied, 377 U.S. 923, 84 S.Ct. 1219, 12
Nor does Corn Products Refining Co. v. FTC, 324 U.S. 726, 65 S.Ct. 961, 89 L.Ed. 1320 (1945), preclude the result we reach. Corn Products operated a delivered price system for glucose sold to all its customers throughout the midwest. The “base point” for its calculation of the delivered price was its plant in Chicago, although Corn Products actually delivered glucose from its Kansas City plant to customers near that plant. The result was a built-in favoritism, unjustified by the facts of delivery, for customers in the Chicago area. Corn Products differs from this case in an important respect. In that case, the manufacturer was utilizing two shipping points, but calculating its freight charges as if it were using only one. The result was that customers close to the Kansas City plant were arbitrarily deprived of the locational advantage similar to the one held by customers close to the Chicago plant. Instead, they were placed at a great disadvantage in an industry in which “differences of a fraction of a cent ... [were] sufficient to divert business from one manufacturer to another....” Id. at 742, 65 S.Ct. at 969. In this case, all relevant allowances are calculated on mileage between the actual shipping point and the customer’s bulk storage facility. The formula is therefore not discriminatory.
Sweeney responds with two arguments. First, it notes that customers of Texaco get the benefit of the allowance based on distance from their plant to Texaco’s plant, but in reality rarely travel the full distance. Because Texaco is aware of the common practice of delivering gasoline to retail stations directly from Texaco’s plant rather than from the bulk storage facilities, Sweeney argues, Texaco is in fact sanctioning discriminatory prices. Sweeney asks this court to mandate f. o. b. shipping point pricing to eliminate this abuse of the hauling allowance. In rejecting this argument, we rely on the teaching that the RobinsonPatman Act should not be construed “in a manner which runs counter to the broad goals which Congress intended it to effectuate.” FTC v. Fred Meyer, Inc., 390 U.S. 341, 349, 88 S.Ct. 904, 908, 19 L.Ed.2d 1222 (1968). Sweeney’s argument is apparently based on some perceived duty of a manufacturer to assure that uniform discounts are not abused by customers. Even if we were persuaded that closer supervision of the hauling allowance would be better commercial practice, we would decline to impose a particular pricing strategy on a market as complex as the gasoline market merely because the current system may be imperfect.
Alternatively, Sweeney would have us require Texaco to calculate, on a station by station basis, the actual mileage travelled by the distributors in making their deliveries. This requirement would impose a substantial administrative burden on Texaco, requiring it to adjust the allowance on a sale by sale basis. It would also eliminate Texaco’s ability to base the hauling allow
Sweeney’s second response is that Texaco has deviated from uniform application of its formula. Only one instance is cited in which Texaco allegedly deviated from the formula. We need not address Sweeney’s argument that this deviation constituted a violation of the act because Sweeney has failed to prove both that it was in any way affected by this deviation
Accordingly, the district court’s order directing a verdict for Texaco on Sweeney’s Robinson-Patman Act damage claim and the order denying its injunction claim will be affirmed.
V.
We have considered the other contentions presented by Sweeney, Mission Gas Oil Company, and Petroleum Products Company. We conclude there was no error in the choice, interpretation, or application of legal precepts
On June 1, 1979, the court granted, in part, Texaco’s motion for partial summary judgment and dismissed Mission’s and Petroleum’s claims for damages. The district court’s decision was correct. Neither of these companies purchased fuel from Texaco, but were Sweeney’s customers. Consequently, under Illinois Brick Co. v. Illinois, 431 U.S. 720, 97 S.Ct. 2061, 52 L.Ed.2d 707 (1977), and Klein v. Lionel Corp., 237 F.2d 13 (3d Cir. 1956), they cannot assert claims for damages under §§ 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act or § 2(a) of the Robinson-Patman Act.
Accordingly, we will affirm the judgment of the district court in all respects.
. Although Sweeney initially asserted antitrust damages based bn the 1971 termination, it withdrew this claim during trial. App. at 1826a-27a; Transcript of Oral Argument at 12. Only the claim of damages based on the change in hauling allowance was before the court on the motion for directed verdict, and therefore only that claim is before us now. Nevertheless, we accept for purposes of argument that both the termination and the change in hauling allowance were parts of a single alleged conspiracy. The 1971 termination was before the court on plaintiff’s claim for injunctive relief, with the court sitting as the trier of fact, and the court’s denial of that relief is discussed in section V, infra.
. There are special reasons for applying this precept to a case in which a manufacturer receives price cutting complaints from competitors of a particular customer. To permit the inference of concerted action on the basis of receiving complaints alone and thus to expose the defendant to treble damage liability would both inhibit management’s exercise of its independent business judgment and emasculate the terms of the statute. As Professor Areeda has explained, many cut off dealers in this situation will be tempted to harass their former suppliers with treble damage suits. Recognizing the potential for harassment, courts should hesitate to scrutinize too closely the supplier’s ambiguous refusal to sell. P. Areeda, Anti-Trust Analysis 560 (2d ed. 1974).
. In addition to Rodden, Doherty, and Murray, appellants also relied on testimony of Paul B. Hicks, Texaco Vice President of Sales, United States, and Edward C. Enstice, Texaco assistant regional wholesale manager. Appellants’ Brief at 17-18. At best, this testimony merely repeats other testimony showing Texaco knew of retailer complaints concerning Sweeney’s pricing policies. Investigation followed the complaints, but the conclusion was that the practices were not objectionable. App. at 1053a, 1078a-80a, lII4a-I120a.
. Prior to June 1, 1971, Sweeney received an allowance of $.0146 per gallon. After June 1, 1971, the allowance was $.0069 per gallon, or a decrease of $.0077. App. at 309a, 497a.
. The Robinson-Patman Act claims asserted by Mission Gas Oil Company and Petroleum Products Company are discussed in section V, infra.
. The district court refused to submit Sweeney’s claim for damages to the jury on the ground that Sweeney failed to establish compensable damages. It relied on Enterprise Indus., Inc. v. Texaco Co., 240 F.2d 457 (2d Cir.), cert. denied, 353 U.S. 965, 77 S.Ct. 1049, 16 L.Ed.2d 914 (1957). We adopted the analysis of Enterprise in Freedman v. Philadelphia Terminals Auction Co., 301 F.2d 830, 833-34 (3d Cir.), cert. denied, 371 U.S. 829, 83 S.Ct. 40, 9 L.Ed.2d 67 (1962). We agree with the district court that the amount of the illegal discrimination can only be used to quantify damages if the plaintiff demonstrates that the favored purchasers lowered their prices in an amount equivalent to the illegal benefit they received. See Enterprise, 240 F.2d at 459-60. Sweeney
. The court explicitly noted that it was not addressing, nor had Texaco submitted, a cost justification defense. 478 F.Supp. at 283 n.3. It relied on facts on which the parties were in substantial agreement, /. e., that Texaco chose the distribution point pursuant to a contractual provision allowing use of the point most economical to Texaco, App. at 158a, and that Texaco realized a cost savings by changing Sweeney’s point from Westville to Macungie. Other issues relating to the switch, such as conspiracy with Sweeney’s competitors and predatory intent, are considered in relation to the Sherman Act claims, supra, and fail for lack of sufficient evidence.
. In Anheuser-Busch, the Court addressed a problem known as “primary-line price discrimination,” in which Anheuser-Busch, a beer manufacturer, sold its beer at a lower price in the St. Louis market than it sold it in other places in the country. The FTC alleged price discrimination to the detriment of other beer manufacturers selling in the St. Louis market, and the Supreme Court agreed. The allegedly harmed parties in Anheuser-Busch were competitors of Anheuser-Busch, who would be affected regardless of whether Anheuser-Busch charged equal prices to all its customers in St. Louis. In this case, equal treatment of customers is the only issue because other gasoline refiners, competitors of Texaco, are not before the court.
. Congress rejected an amendment to the Robinson-Patman Act that would have required f. o. b. shipping point pricing. See Corn Products Refining Co. v. FTC, 324 U.S. 726, 737, 65 S.Ct. 961, 966, 89 L.Ed. 1320 (1945).
. Undisputed evidence at trial indicated that Texaco increased Farm & Home Oil Company’s hauling allowance after Sun Oil Company tried to induce Farm & Home to cease distributing Texaco gasoline and instead to distribute Sun gasoline. Even assuming a jury could reject Texaco’s meeting competition defense under § 2(b), 15 U.S.C. § 13(b), with respect to this transaction, Sweeney neither alleged nor proved that it was harmed by this particular event.
. See note 6, supra.
. We specifically reject appellants’ assertion of error based on the district court’s refusal to admit evidence of Temporary Voluntary Allowances (TVA’s). Texaco gave its wholesalers these allowances in order to assist Texaco retailers in meeting price competition from other retailers. Prior to trial, Sweeney conceded TVA’s had nothing to do with the case. The district court correctly excluded TVA evidence.