DocketNumber: [No. 52, April Term, 1928.]
Judges: Akkiks, Ankixs, Bond, Bonn, Digges, Oeetjtt, Offutt, Pabke, Parke, Pattisoh, Sloak, Ureter
Filed Date: 7/16/1928
Status: Precedential
Modified Date: 10/19/2024
The United Railways Electric Company of Baltimore came into existence on the fourth day of March, 1899, as the result of a merger of all the street railway lines operating in and near Baltimore, with a total authorized capitalization of $76,000,000, of which $38,000,000 was in bonds, $14,000,000 in preferred stock, and $24,000,000 in common stock. The base fare at that time charged by its several constituent companies within the city limits was five cents, and by chapter 313 of the Acts of 1900, the consolidated corporation, hereinafter called the company, was specifically limited to a fare of five cents for the transportation of adults, and three cents for children, from any point on its lines within said city to any other point thereon which could be reached directly or by transfer at intersecting points, and that schedule it maintained until 1918.
In the meantime, the State, moving with a growing trend throughout the country, had abandoned its traditional policy of regulating public service corporations by direct legislative action, and had by chapter 180 of the Acts of 1910 created the Public Service Commission of Maryland, hereinafter called the commission, to which it had committed plenary powers in respect to regulating the rates and service of public utilities, and had repealed existing legislation fixing rates for service furnished by such utilities, such repeal to become effective when and as the commission determined in accordance with the law that such rates should be superseded by others. Gregg v. Public Serv.Commn.,
And on July 19th, 1918, the company for the first time applied to the commission for its approval of a schedule of rates under which it would receive six cents for adults, and a uniform increase of one cent from children between four and twelve years of age and riders using commutation tickets. The commission was unable to hear the application immediately, and the company, on August 28th, 1918, with the assent of the commission, filed a revised schedule, which took effect October 1st, 1918, and remained in effect until January 7th, 1919, when it was formerly approved by the commission.
On May 23rd, 1919, the company applied for a further increase from six to seven cents for cash fares, with four tokens for twenty-five cents, which it subsequently changed to a request that it be permitted to collect a cash fare of ten cents with two tokens for fifteen cents, and on September 30th, 1919, it was permitted to charge a cash fare of seven cents or six and one-half cents when tickets or other tokens were purchased. On December 26th, 1919, it again applied for an increase in its rate schedule, and the commission advanced the base fare from six and one-half cents to seven cents flat. On March 31st, 1924, at the company's request, the commission authorized a further increase of the base fare to seven and one-half cents, and, on August 1st, 1927, it filed an application for permission to increase its base fare to ten cents, which was 100 per cent. more than it had charged prior to October 1st, 1918, and 33 1/3 per cent. more than it had been allowed to charge from March 31st, 1924, until it filed that application; and, in connection with that request, it alleged an apprehended financial crisis, and urged that it be allowed to put the increase in effect immediately as an emergency measure, pending any hearing that might be had on its application for a permanent increase of its base fare to ten cents. The application for an emergency rate was denied but, on February 10th, 1928, the commission passed an order which denied the application for an increase of the base fare to ten cents, but which permitted the company "to charge and *Page 577 collect for the transportation of persons over its several street railway lines, in Baltimore City and vicinity, a base rate fare of eight and one-third cents when tickets or fare checks are purchased, or nine cents cash, for the conveyance of each passenger over twelve years of age, and five cents for each child between the ages of four and twelve years, between any of the points designated in the schedule of the said company filed with the commission pursuant to the requirements of the commission's Order No. 8240 entered in Case No. 1682 on May 26th, 1924, or between intermediate points, in either direction, on any of such lines, except in so far as the zones on any of the said lines are hereinafter modified or changed. That the first fare zone on the Halethorpe line be and it is hereby extended to the terminus of the said line at Halethorpe, effective from and after midnight of February 12th, 1928."
The company, being dissatisfied with that order, on March 13th, 1928, filed, in Circuit Court No. 2 of Baltimore City, a bill of complaint, in which it asked that that order be nullified in so far as it or any previous order of the commission prevented it from charging a flat ten cent fare, or from continuing the first and second Halethorpe zones, and it further asked that the commission be enjoined from enforcing that order or any prior order limiting the company's rates. The commission answered, the case was set down, evidence offered by the commission, the company, and intervening persons interested in the matter, and after argument submitted for decree, and on May 11th, 1928, a decree was filed vacating the order in so far as the same purports to limit the rates of the plaintiff; except, however, as to that portion of said order which extended the first fare zone on the Halethorpe line to the terminus of said line at Halethorpe, as to which latter provision in said order "the bill of complaint is hereby dismissed," and enjoining the defendants from enforcing that or any other orders of the commission in so far as they limit or purport to limit the rates of fare to be charged by the company. From that decree the company and the commission *Page 578 appealed, the company on the ground that the court erred in abolishing the second zone on the Halethorpe line, and the commission on the ground that the court erred in vacating so much of its order as affected the rate of fare to be charged by the company, and in enjoining it from enforcing such order.
It may be noted that the relief granted in the decree is not precisely that prayed in the bill. The commission by its order did three things, it refused the company's application for a ten cent fare, it fixed an eight and one-third cents fare, and it consolidated the two Halethorpe zones in one. The appellee, in its bill, asks that all orders of the commission which limit its rates or prevent it from charging a ten cent fare be set aside, and that the commission be enjoined from enforcing any such orders. The decree does not refer to a ten cent fare at all, but vacates all orders of the commission, so far as they purport to limit the "rates of the plaintiff," and it based that ruling upon the commission's "election" not to have the case remanded to them. But the court clearly had no right to fix the company's rates, since its function was judicial and confined to determining whether the order of the commission was valid or invalid, and, if in its judgment the action of the commission was unlawful, it should have remanded the case to the commission for such further action as might be appropriate, for even if in fact the eight and one-third cent rate allowed was inadequate to allow the company a fair return on the value of its property, that fact did not oust the jurisdiction of the commission to fix the company's rates, nor did it authorize the court or the company to fix them, for under the statute the power to do that is in the commission alone. Gregg v. Pub. Serv. Comm., supra; Chenoweth v.Pub. Serv. Comm.,
The central dominating question presented by the appeal is whether the schedule of rates promulgated by the commission is insufficient to yield such an income as will give to the company a fair return on the value of its property. In the argument of the case it was said that the commission had limited the company to a return of 6.26 per cent. on the value of its property, but the order did not so state. What it did do, was to fix a schedule of rates which, after deducting the allowances approved by the commission for maintenance, replacement, operation, financing, and other expenses, would yield that return, but, if more efficient or economical management resulted in a larger net return, there was nothing in the order to prevent the company from retaining the benefit of that saving, even though it increased its net earnings to more than 6.26 per cent. of the value of its property. So that the question actually is whether a schedule of fares which, after deducting all reasonable and proper expenses for the management and operation of the company, permits it to earn a net return of 6.26 per cent. on the value of its property, is confiscatory within the meaning of the state and federal constitutions, or unlawful and unreasonable within the meaning of the statute creating the commission. To that question there are various approaches, all differing in some degree in the effect they have upon the meaning and weight of the facts of the case.
It may be approached from the company's point of view, in which case the commission's function would be largely administrative, and the ultimate determination of the propriety *Page 580 of its rates would rest with the company, and the sole test of the lawfulness of such rates would be whether they were fair to it, and would yield what in its judgment was a proper return on the valuation of its property.
It may be approached from the standpoint of the patrons of the service, in which event the power of the commission to fix the rates would be bounded on one side by the rule that the rates must in no event exceed the value of the service, and on the other by the rule that, so long as the rates did not exceed the value of the service, the company was entitled to a fair return on the value of its property. Then there is a third approach, in which the question is viewed from the standpoint of the State, in which case, factors which from the standpoint of the public or the corporation have varying weights, such as the nature and necessity of the service, the effect of its continuance or withdrawal, both upon the security holders of the corporation, and upon property values, and the welfare of the people in the territory served by it, the extent to which the State itself is a partner in the enterprise, and the circumstances and conditions under which the company acquired and exercises its franchises and privileges, may become of paramount and controlling importance, and in our judgment the question must be approached from that direction.
Before dealing specifically with it, however, we will refer briefly and generally to the powers, functions and duties of the commission, to the extent of its jurisdiction, and to the weight to be given its decisions. That the power committed to the commission is legislative in character, notwithstanding that the manner in which it is exercised is forensic, is no longer open to question (Gregg v. Pub. Serv. Commn., supra, Chenoweth v. Pub.Serv. Commn., supra), and, except where limited by the statute itself or some constitutional provision, the acts of the commission, done in the exercise of its statutory powers, are entitled to the same weight which would be given a direct act of the legislature. Knoxville v. Knoxville Water Co.,
There has been and is some uncertainty as to the extent to which courts will go in reviewing the conclusions and decisions of such administrative agencies as the appellant. In InterstateCommerce Commn. v. Union Pac. R.R. Co.,
"There has been no attempt to make an exhaustive statement of the principle involved, but in cases thus far decided, it has been settled that the orders of the commission are final unless (1) beyond the power which it could constitutionally exercise; or (2) beyond its statutory power, or (3) based upon a mistake of law. But questions of fact may be involved in the determination of questions of law, so that an order, regular on its face, may be set aside if it appears that (4) the rate is so low as to be confiscatory and in violation of the constitutional prohibition against taking property without due process of law; or (5) if the commission acted so arbitrarily and unjustly as to fix rates contrary to evidence, or without evidence to support it; or (6) if the authority therein involved has been exercised in such an unreasonable manner as to cause it to be within the elementary rule that the substance, and not the shadow, determines the validity of the exercise of the power. * * *
"In determining these mixed questions of law and fact, the court confines itself to the ultimate question as to whether the commission acted within its power. It will not consider the expediency or wisdom of the order, or whether, on like testimony, it would have made a similar ruling. ``The findings of the commission are made by law prima facie true, and this court has ascribed to them the strength due to the judgments of a tribunal appointed by law and informed by experience.' Illinois C.R. Co.v. Interstate Commerce Commission,
While in the later case of the Ohio Valley Water Co. v. BenAvon Borough,
The question came before this court and was decided in PublicServ. Commn. v. Byron, supra, in accordance with the views expressed in Interstate Commerce Commn. v. Union Pac. R.R. Co.,supra. In that case, speaking through Judge Parke, it was said: "The first rule is that the order will not be disturbed except upon clear and satisfactory evidence that it is unreasonable or unlawful. This is a legislative mandate which is reinforced by the fact that the commission is a tribunal erected by law, informed by experience, and assisted by a trained corps of subordinates. Code, art. 23, sec. 408; Public Serv. Commn. v.North. Cent. Ry. Co.,
Reverting now to the main question presented by the appeal, the first inquiry is whether a schedule of rates which permits the appellee to earn 6.26 per cent. on the fair value of its property can be said to be confiscatory within the meaning of that clause of the Fourteenth Amendment of the Federal Constitution, which denies to the states the power of *Page 584
depriving any person of his property without due process of law. Confiscation, in that sense, is essentially a relative, and not an absolute, term, and it does not exist apart from the facts which are said to occasion it. No fixed or general rule can be announced by which it can be determined whether it exists in any given case, because whether it exists or not must be determined from factors which vary with the facts of each case, since rate cases, like wills, seldom have "twin brothers." Covington L.Turnpike Co. v. Sandford,
To attempt to analyze in detail the mass of factual and opinion evidence adduced before the commission is neither practicable or necessary, since such facts as are relevant to the question before us rest for the most part in records of the company or the commission, and are not in dispute, and we will at this time only refer to such as are necessary to indicate the contentions of the parties.
The total value of the company's property, including easements, may be placed at $75,000,000. That was the valuation placed upon it by the commission in 1924, and while there was some dispute as to whether that figure should not be increased to include additions since the valuation, that contention was not stressed in this court, but was treated as a matter of detail which could be adjusted to fit the facts at *Page 585 some future time, so that the figure of $75,000,000 may be treated as the true value of the company's property for all the purposes of this case.
The financial structure of the company appears from the following tabulation, in which the "basic value" of its property is assumed to be $70,000,000, the value placed upon it by the commission exclusive of the value of the easements, which has been fixed at $5,000,000:
Per Cent. Per Cent. Class of Outstanding of Basic Outstanding of Basic Securities 12/31/1926 Value 6/30/1927 ValueAnd it appears that the company has for some time past been paying, and still pays, dividends on its common stock at the rate of four per cent., and that that stock, having a par value of fifty dollars per share, has in late years sold on the Baltimore Stock Exchange at prices ranging from sixteen dollars to twenty-one dollars per share, and it further appears that its mortgage bonds bought at current market prices yield the purchaser a return of about six per cent. From time to time, since 1911, the company has had occasion to borrow for varying periods, and the rates at which this money was bought, as shown by the following tabulation, throws some light upon the changes in its credit: *Page 586Mortgage Bonds . $47,405,000 67.7 $47,405,000 67.7 Miscellaneous Obligations .. 6,392,700 9.1 7,664,200 10.9 Income Bonds ... 13,977,000 20.0 13,977,000 20.0 Total Bonds and Miscellaneous Obligations .. 67,774,700 96.7 69,046,200 98.7 Stocks ......... 20,461,200 29.2 20,461,200 29.2 ___________ _______ ___________ _______ Grand Total .. $88,235,900 126.0 $89,508,400 127.9
Issued Description Amount Proceeds*Page 5871911, 2nd Half. 3-Year Notes ..................... $3,125,000 $3,046,876 1914, 2nd Half. 10-Year Car Trust Certificate .... 153,000 153,000 1914, 2nd Half. 2-Year 5% Collateral Trust Notes . 1,000,000 995,000 1914, 2nd Half. 1st Mtge. Gold Sinking Fund Bonds (Md. Elec. Rys.) ......... 489,000 469,440 1916, Feb. ....... 5-Year 5% Gold Notes .......... 2,750,000 2,695,000 1917, Oct. ....... 6% Convertible Gold Notes ..... 3,000,000 2,850,000 1919 ......... 5-Year Convertible Notes ......... 1,528,000 * 1917 ......... 1st Mtge. Gold Bonds (Md. Elec. Rys.) .......................... 457,000 447,860 1920, 2nd Half. Car Trust Certificates — Series 1920 (10 Yrs.) ................. 875,000 831,250 1921, Feb. ....... 7 1/2% Coupons Gold Notes ..... 1,500,000 1,383,750 1922, Apr. ....... 1st Consol. Mort. 50-Year Gold Bonds .......................... 6,000,000 5,550,000 1922 ......... 1st Consol. Mort. 50-Year 6% Gold Bonds .......................... 6,000,000 5,500,000 In lieu of 4% Bonds ($2,684,000 at $250 per Bond ............... 671,000 1922, July. ..... 5-Year 6% Gold Notes ........... 2,500,000 2,375,000 1924, 1st Half. 1st and Refunding Gold Bonds, Ser. A. (Md. Elec. Rys.) ....... 4,000,000 3,790,000 1927, July. ..... 3-Year Notes ................... 2,500,000 2,412,000
Rate Interest Issued Description Received Rate
1911, 2nd Half. 3-Year Notes ..................... 97 1/2 5% 1914, 2nd Half. 10-Year Car Trust Certificate .... 100 6% 1914, 2nd Half. 2-Year 5% Collateral Trust Notes . 99 1/2 5% 1914, 2nd Half. 1st Mtge. Gold Sinking Fund Bonds (Md. Elec. Rys.) ......... 96 5% 1916, Feb. ....... 5-Year 5% Gold Notes .......... 98 5% 1917, Oct. ....... 6% Convertible Gold Notes ..... 95 6% 1919 ......... 5-Year Convertible Notes ......... * 5% 1917 ......... 1st Mtge. Gold Bonds (Md. Elec. Rys.) .......................... 98 5% 1920, 2nd Half. Car Trust Certificates — Series 1920 (10 Yrs.) ................. 95 8% 1921, Feb. ....... 7 1/2% Coupons Gold Notes ..... 92 1/4 7 1/2% 1922, Apr. ....... 1st Consol. Mort. 50-Year Gold Bonds .......................... 92 1/2 6% 1922 ......... 1st Consol. Mort. 50-Year 6% Gold Bonds .......................... 92 1/2 6% In lieu of 4% Bonds ($2,684,000 at $250 per Bond ............... 6% 1922, July. ..... 5-Year 6% Gold Notes ........... 95 6% 1924, 1st Half. 1st and Refunding Gold Bonds, Ser. A. (Md. Elec. Rys.) ....... 94 3/4 6 1/2% 1927, July. ..... 3-Year Notes ................... 96 1/2 6%
From another table, filed by people's counsel, it appears that the net income of the company, for the years from 1920 to 1926, inclusive, was as follows: 1920, $1,043,599.21; 1921, $735,230.58; 1922, $799,268.99; 1923, $976,266.38; 1924, $976,068.39; 1925, $980,609.53; 1926, $1,010,054.41; and that for the same period the operating income was: 1920, $17,313,589.84; 1921, $16,332,865.34; 1922, $16,122,592.02; 1923, $16,461,798.86; 1924, $16,453,254.31; 1925, $16,621,220.20; 1926, $16,715,709.07.
Another tabulation filed on behalf of the people indicated the following ratio of funded debt to track operation per mile, and gross revenue per dollar in a number of American cities:
Funded Debt Funded Debt per Mile of Funded Debt and Income Track per Dollar Bonds Operation Gross RevenueStill another table showed the current rates of fare, rate of return, and base, in twelve representative American cities comparable in size to Baltimore, to be as follows: *Page 588Baltimore ............ $67,774,700 $164,000 4.05 Without Income Bonds ............ 53,797,700 130,000 3.22 Detroit .............. 35,155,000 88,000 1.63 Los Angeles .......... 19,852,000 ....... 1.64 San Francisco ........ 11,695,000 42,600 1.19 Pittsburg ............ 34,215,000 57,700 1.57 Boston ............... 49,819,000 100,200 1.41 Cleveland ............ 5,495,000 13,310 .30 St. Louis ............ 52,590,000 120,900 2.80 St. Paul, Minn ....... 19,478,000 38,700 1.40 Buffalo .............. 25,392,782 62,200 2.47 Providence ........... 13,714,000 47,200 1.61 Washington ........... 5,606,000 77,000 1.21 Cincinnati ........... 5,288,400 19,840 .65 Indianapolis ......... 13,497,517 56,300 2.35 Denver ............... 10,863,500 48,900 2.38
Rate of Return Base FareAnd another table lists seventy-nine American cities, each having a population of over 100,000, and shows the population of each city, the rate of fare charged on the street railways, and commutation privileges, established in connection with such fares in each city. In analyzing that table Mr. H. Carl Wolf, engineer for the commission, testified:Baltimore (New Fare) .. 6.26 $75,000,000 9c — 3 for 25c Boston ................ 4.64 159,025,142 10c — 4 for 25c (limited) Chicago Surface Lines . 6.27 164,600,000 7c — 3 for 20c Cincinnati ............ 4.16 36,381,017 10c — 3 for 25c Cleveland ............. 4.35 37,106,506 7c — 8 for 50c Kansas City ........... 1.82 23,300,000 8c — 15 for $1.00 Los Angeles ........... 3.06 54,000,000 5c Philadelphia .......... 5.07 216,000,000 8c — 2 for 15c Pittsburg ............. 5.85 68,170,000 10c — 3 for 25c St. Louis ............. 4.66 52,024,192 8c — 2 for 15c San Francisco ......... 5.37 35,000,000 5c Washington ............ 4.69 50,000,000 8c — 6 for 40c
"Of the 81 cities listed as having a population of 100,000 or more, only nineteen of them have a fare higher than Baltimore. There are thirty cities with a ten cent fare. Only one of these has a straight ten cent fare with no tokens. Ten of them, or one-third the number, have an eight and one-third cent token fare, six of them have an eight and one-third cent token fare, plus a pass system, one of them has a seven and a half cent token fare, plus a pass system, and when the commission recalls that at the present time ninety-seven per cent. of the full fare passengers in Baltimore are using the token fare, they will see that the ten cent — seven and a half cent fare, plus a weekly pass, if applied to Baltimore, would cause practically no increase in fare, and probably a decrease.
There is one of these thirty cities with a ten cent fare which has not a token fare but which does have a pass, and eleven of them with ten cent fares charge seven and one-half cents or lower for tokens with no passes." *Page 589
And in criticising that analysis Mr. C.D. Emmons, president of the company, said:
"I have this from the late bulletin: that the trend of fares over the United States has been upward since July 1st, 1923, and is continuing upward. On October 1st, 1927, the average fare of 272 cities reporting was 7.9516 cents and November 1st, 1927, the average fare was 7.9846 cents, which is the highest average fare that the street railway industry has ever had, not excluding the war period.
"There are at the present time, or since the November bulletin, there have been twelve different cities that have changed the rate of fare. There are three interurban roads that have changed the rate of fare. At the present time there are fourteen fare cases pending.
"Q. What are the direction of those changes? A. The changes are all up with the exception of a municipal city which has put in a weekly pass, and the information here does not say about the flat fare. I presume it's the same, a flat fare with a weekly pass. I think they give a statement that there are only, I have forgotten, of basic ten cent fare cities, but my statement here is that there are — I got this morning, dated November 26th, from New York — this gives 219 United States cities. Q. Having a basic fare of ten cent? A. That's right, yes. (Mr. Tingley): Those are not cities of over 100,000? (The Witness): No; but I counted the cities of over 100,000 in this and there are thirty-one cities of over 100,000 that have a basic ten cent fare. * * * (The Witness): Cicero, Illinois, 65,400; Forest Park, Illinois, 10,768; Maywood, Illinois, 12,072; Oak Park, Illinois, 53,500; Auburn, Maine, 16,985; Bangor, Maine, 25,978; Bath, Maine, 14,731; Lewiston, Maine, 35,500; Villercia, Massachusetts, 3,646; Boston, Massachusetts, 787,000; Braintree, Massachusetts, 10,580; Concord, Massachusetts, 6,461; Framingham, Massachusetts, 17,033; Holyoke, Massachusetts, 60,400; Lexington, Massachusetts, 6,350; Natick, Massachusetts, 10,907; Needham, Massachusetts, 7,012; Newburyport, Massachusetts, 15,618; Newtonville, Massachusetts, *Page 590 5,700; Wakefield, Massachusetts, 13,025; Waltham, Massachusetts, 35,700; Wellesly, Massachusetts, 6,224; Woburn, Massachusetts, 16,574; Worcester, Massachusetts, 193,300; Morristown, New Jersey, 12,548; Ocean City, New Jersey, 3,721; Lackawanna, New York, 17,918; Mauchnuck, Pennsylvania, 3,666; West Chester, Pennsylvania, 11,717. * * * (Mr. Clark): How many states now have you cited there? (The Witness): Six states."
From other tables it appears that the wages of "platform" men have increased from a maximum of twenty-two cents an hour in 1913 to a maximum of fifty-three cents an hour in 1926, that other wages showed an approximately similar increase, and that during the same period the general cost of living showed an increase from a base index of 100 to an index of 173.
Perhaps the most significant fact connected with the question before us is the decline in the number of revenue passengers carried by the company, from 253,834,179 in 1919, to 225,225,633 in 1926, and 145,256,760 (August approximated) for eight months of 1927. Coincident with that decline was a gradual increase in the rates of fare from five cents prior to 1919 to seven and one-half cents in 1927, and an increase in the registration of automobiles from 85,430 in 1919 to 267,649 in 1926.
In connection with those figures a further fact appears, which is that, while the total number of revenue passengers is decreasing, the peak load of passengers, that is, the greatest number of passengers carried during the "rush hours" each day, has increased, and, to accommodate that increasing demand, it has become necessary for the company to maintain an increased equipment, which is to some degree idle during a part of the day.
One of the contentions made by the company was that the existing rates so affect its credit that it is compelled to pay unreasonably high rates for money, and in connection with that contention it filed a table showing the rates it has paid since 1920, which in part shows: *Page 591
Less Cost of Date Issue Amount of Banker's Money to Market Issue Commission Company PriceThese facts are but a small part of those to be found in the mass of evidence contained in the record, but they are sufficient to indicate the grounds for the conflicting contentions of the parties to this appeal, which, as we understand them, are in substance as follows:July 1, 1920 — Car Trust 8% Gold Certificates ........... $875,000 $43,750 9.3/8% 100 Jan. 15, 1921 — Ten Year 7 1/2% Gold Notes .............. 1,500,000 90,000 8.70% 98 1/4 Mar. 1, 1922 — First Consolidated Mortgage 6's, due March 1, 1949 6,000,000 270,000 6.75% 97 A.K. Marsh. 1, 1922 — Deposit of $250 per $1,000 bond by holders of $2,684,000, first consolidated mortgage 4's to secure additional 2% interest coupons ........................ 671,000 28,903 6.60% .. Aug. 1, 1928 — Five Year 6% Gold Notes .................. 2,500,000 75,000 7.27% 98 Jan. 1, 1928 — Maryland Electric Rwys. Co. First and Refunding Mortgage Gold Bonds, Series "A"-6 1/2%, due Jan. 1, 1957 ................... 4,000,000 210,000 6.93% 100 A.K. Marsh. 1, 1927 — Three year 6% Gold Notes .................. 2,500,000 62,500 7.32% 99 1/4
In respect to the main question, the appellant appears to contend that the schedule of fares promulgated by the commission is, under existing conditions, all that the service is worth, and fair alike to the company and the public, but that, whether fair to the company or not, no higher rates should be allowed, because the company is only entitled to collect from the public the value of the service it renders.
The contention of the company, on the other hand, seems to be that it is entitled to earn a fair return on the value of *Page 592 its property, that "fair return" means a return of at least eight per cent. on the value thereof, and that it is entitled to a schedule of rates high enough to insure that return regardless of the value of its service to the public. Or reduced to its lowest terms, and quoting its own language, the company's proposition is that "compulsory limitation of the company's rates to yield a maximum of less than eight per cent. is confiscatory and unlawful," while the commission contends that "rates must in no event exceed the value of the service, regardless of return or confiscation"; and somewhere between those extreme theories lies the law.
Manifestly the proposition submitted by the company is broader than the law, while that of the commission is too indefinite and vague to be of much aid in settling the question before us. There is, so far as we know, no rule of law which guarantees to public service corporations the right to earn eight per cent. on the value of their properties, regardless of the fairness of their rates to the public or of any other fact or circumstance, but the law, as stated in Covington L. Turnpike Co. v. Sandford,supra, is to the contrary There it is said (page 596): "It is proper to say that if the answer had not alleged, in substance, that the tolls prescribed by the act of 1890 were wholly inadequate for keeping the road in proper repair and for earning dividends, we could not say that the act was unconstitutional merely because the company (as was alleged and as the demurrer admitted) could not earn more than four per cent. upon its capital stock. It cannot be said that a corporation operating a public highway is entitled, as of right, and without reference to the interests of the public, to realize a given per cent. upon its capital stock. When the question arises whether the legislature has exceeded its constitutional power in prescribing rates to be charged by a corporation controlling a public highway, stockholders are not the only persons whose rights or interests are to be considered. The rights of the public are not to be ignored. It is alleged here that the rates prescribed are unreasonable and unjust to the company and its stockholders. But that involves an inquiry as to what is *Page 593 reasonable and just for the public. If the establishing of new lines of transportation should cause a diminution in the number of those who need to use a turnpike road, and, consequently, a diminution in the tolls collected, that is not, in itself, a sufficient reason why the corporation, operating the road, should be allowed to maintain rates that would be unjust to those who must or do use the property. The public cannot properly be subjected to unreasonable rates in order simply that stockholders may earn dividends." Nor is there any rule by which we may precisely determine what is the actual value to the public of such service as that which the company sells.
When the company speaks of a "return of not less than eight per cent." on its property, it must be remembered that nearly $68,000,000 of its actual value is covered by bonded indebtedness or other obligations bearing a fixed rate of interest far below that rate, and that the balance of the eight per cent. return remaining after paying that interest would go to the holders of stock having a par value of $20,461,200, the real value of which is $7,000,000, if the easements are valued at $5,000,000, or $2,000,000, if they are excluded, which would necessarily be greater than an eight per cent. return on the value of that stock. But aside from that, and assuming that the rate schedule will yield less than eight per cent. on the actual value of all the company's property, or even less than eight per cent. on the actual value of the stock, that fact alone cannot characterize it as confiscatory, but other factors must be considered.
It is argued that an eight per cent. return is necessary to enable the company to borrow money at reasonable rates, and that the fact that it is limited to a rate schedule which will yield a return of only 6.26 per cent. puts it at a disadvantage as a borrower and weakens its credit. But the evidence fails to support that contention. It is true that there is in the record a mass of subjective and highly conjectural testimony pro andcon relating to it, much of which tends to support the company's contention, but, whilst its usefulness may be conceded, the speculative opinions of experts *Page 594 who are themselves interested in increasing the rate of return on similar utilities cannot be substituted for the judgment of the commission, and accepted as a conclusive determination of the question, at least where the judgment of the commission is based upon substantive evidence.
The value of such securities as the obligations of public utility companies depends in the main upon the security they offer, as well as the rate of return which they will pay the investor. And it is quite as reasonable to assume that the fact that the ratio of the company's funded debt to the value of its property is, as the commission found, approximately ninety per cent., affects its credit, as the fact that it can only earn 6.26 on the value of its property.
In connection with that contention, the company asserts that the use of the automobile for the transportation of those who otherwise would use its lines has increased to such extent that it has reduced its net revenue to such a point, that any rate schedule indicating a return of less than eight per cent. on the value of its property impairs the security offered investors, and lessens the confidence of the public in its financial stability, and that therefore it is entitled as of right to a schedule which will insure such a rate of return regardless of its effect on that part of the public who for one reason or other are obliged to use its lines. But if, as the company contends, it is required to pay more for its money because of the risk resulting from the increasing competition of the private automobile, it certainly cannot expect to correct that condition by raising its rates to such a point that investors will purchase its stock as a gambling or speculative venture. Nor in fact do we see any occasion for the gloomy outlook of the company's witnesses. It appears to be well and economically managed, and the market price of its securities indicates continued public confidence in its stability, as well as in its ability to liquidate its obligations, when and as they accrue, and from the volume of its business there is little likelihood that it will cease to be a highly productive property, not only useful but essential to the city's welfare and the public convenience, and profitable to its owners, provided *Page 595 sufficient allowance is made for keeping its property from depreciating..
There seems to be no question but that the private automobile is a serious competitor of the company, and it is estimated that it carries about twenty-five per cent. of those who would but for it use the street cars, and it is possible that it may make further inroads on its business, regardless of rates. In fact, the company rather repudiates the idea that rates have any substantial effect upon the volume of its traffic, but attributes its decline almost entirely to the automobile, although as a matter of common sense there must be some substantial relation between transportation rates and the volume of traffic. But, irrespective of that, the company's contention ignores one very important if not controlling consideration, and that is that it is a "public" service company, and that practically speaking the substantial value of all of its property is due primarily to franchises and privileges which it has secured from the state, upon the condition, express or implied, but always present, that it will give in return adequate service at reasonable rates. Those privileges include not only the right to do business and operate its lines over public highways, but also protection against any other agency offering to perform the same service in the same territory. So that when the company contends that since conditions, which neither it nor any one else can control, increase the expense of its service, that it should be permitted not only to transfer that entire burden to that part of the public who must of necessity use its lines, but to also increase its net earnings beyond a point they have ever reached, it ignores the very patent fact that if the State withdrew from it the protection from competition by other public service companies offering the same service which it now enjoys, its very existence would be threatened. The mere fact therefore that increasing automobile competition has made it more expensive for the company to serve those who do use its lines, while it justifies increasing its rates to a point which will absorb the increased expense, affords no excuse for still further increasing them to a point which will not only be burdensome to the *Page 596 traveling public, but will at the same time yield to the company a greater return than it has ever received, and greater than that usually received by others operating in the same field elsewhere under substantially the same conditions.
Whether a given rate is burdensome to the public, involves the question of the value of the service, and presents an extremely difficult and troublesome question, the answer to which, except in extreme cases, can only rest in the judgment of the commission, operating upon varying factors, each of which is entitled to some weight, but no one of which ordinarily is controlling.
One consideration suggested is the diminished purchasing value of the dollar, the increase in wages, and the fact that wages have risen higher than the cost of living, on the theory that, as the public has more money to spend, it suffers no hardship if it is required to spend more, and that by judicious management it may for that reason be brought from a five cent to a ten cent state of mind without any serious physical or mental disturbance or inconvenience. But while that theory may have a certain appeal for the company, it is too refined and delicate for general and practical use, and although it might have a material and substantial relation to the operating expenses of the company, it has no apparent relation to the value of its service. The fact that it cost one man three dollars to grow a bushel of wheat is no reason why a purchaser should be compelled to pay him three dollars for it, if in fact, measured by the market, it is only worth two, and ordinarily the affluence of the buyer has no perceptible relation to the value of the product of the seller. Whilst not strictly analogous, recent developments in the ice business tend to illustrate the fallacy of that contention. It is a matter of general knowledge that the manufacture and sale of machines for artificial refrigeration, and the manufacture of ice in homes, has had a serious effect on the artificial and natural ice business as formerly conducted. But assuming that the ice business is a public utility and its rates subject to regulation, it would be manifestly unreasonable to allow an ice company to charge to its patrons the losses it *Page 597 had suffered from the inroads of competitors, by requiring them to pay rates high enough to absorb these losses.
Another factor suggested is that a decrease in the volume of traffic indicates that the rates are burdensome, and there is some force in that suggestion, but the difficulty in this case lies in attributing the decline to the increase of fares. So far as the facts go, it may be due either to that or to the increasing use of the automobile. Whether it is due to one or the other is a matter of unguided conjecture. For while there is in the record a confused mass of contradictory figures relating to the effect of increased rates on the volume of traffic, it is impossible to deduce from them any definite or sound conclusion.
Nor can the value be determined by comparison, by the market, or by what it would cost an individual to obtain by a privately owned agency the same service. There is no other public agency rendering the same service with which the company can be compared, for it is protected in a monopoly, and for the same reason there is no general market by which the value of its service can be ascertained, nor would it be reasonable to measure its value by what it costs the owner of an automobile to operate it so as to give like service, because of the difference in machines and in the expense incident to their operation, and because there is no fair comparison between the operation of a private automobile and a public service corporation operated as a monopoly and for profit. So that, in determining whether the rates fixed by the commission are confiscatory, we are finally remitted to a few simple realities, such as the past earnings of the company, the returns usually received by other companies engaged in the same business in other fields under somewhat similar conditions, the rates which the company has voluntarily fixed for its service in the past, the decrease in the purchasing power of the dollar, and the effect which other orders of the commission have had upon the earning power of the company.
It may be assumed that the base fare prior to the formation of the commission was reasonable, because up to that time no complaint had been made of it by the company, and *Page 598 in 1900 it was fixed by an act of the Legislature, which has never been challenged. The fare then was five cents, which would be approximately equal to eight and one-third cents today, when the decreased purchasing value of the dollar is considered, and, if that were all, the question would be free from difficulty, for if five cents was fair, then the equivalent of the value which five cents had then should be fair now. But there are other factors which affect it, such as the extension of the city fare zone, so as to embrace all the new territory brought into the city by the annexation of 1918, the effect of which was to relieve a part of the public of the burden of an extra fare, possibly at the expense of the company, and certainly of the remaining part of the public, and also the fact that certain of the operating expenses of the company, such as the cost of labor, increased in a ratio greater than that in which the purchasing power of the dollar declined, for, although speaking generally the dollar now will purchase perhaps sixty per cent. of what it would in 1913, it will not purchase as much as fifty per cent. of the labor which the company could have bought with it then.
But these factors were considered fully by the commission when it fixed the base fare at seven and one-half cents in 1924, and in view of that finding, and of the further fact that the record does not disclose any data sufficiently specific to enable us to say that it was unlawful, we are not inclined to give them any controlling weight now, especially as the schedule fixed by the order in this case is designed to give the company a higher return on its property than it received prior to the extensions.
It also appears that, if the schedule produces the results anticipated by the commission, that the net earnings of the company in comparison with the value of its property will be as great as, if not greater than, at any time in so much of its history as has been called to our attention, and that it will yield a return thereon, with one possible exception, higher than that now received by any company engaged in the same business under conditions at all comparable to those obtaining in Baltimore and its environs, and higher than the interest *Page 599
rate allowed by statute in this state. Code, art. 49, sec. 1. After giving due consideration to these several factors, and to Code, art. 23, sec. 408, we are unable to say that the schedule of fares promulgated by the order appealed from was unlawful, unreasonable, or confiscatory, which permits a return of 6.26 on the value of the company's property, and it follows that so much of the opinion of the trial court as set aside that part of the order and enjoined its enforcement was in error. And that conclusion seems to be in accord with such authority as there is on the subject. In the case of Smyth v. Ames,
There is certainly nothing in these cases, nor in any other decision of the Supreme Court, which is the final authority upon the question involved in this appeal, which is in any way inconsistent with the decision of that court in Dayton-GooseCreek R.R. Co. v. United States,
The allowance made for current repairs under the head of maintenance does not appear to be questioned, so that the only inquiry is whether the allowance for depreciation is adequate. The commission, in fixing the fare schedule, allowed five per cent. on the gross revenue of the company for depreciation, and estimated that that allowance would yield $883,544 in 1928, allowing for a decrease in the volume of traffic, and its opinion indicates that in reaching that conclusion it considered the cost, and not the present value, of the company's depreciable property. Unquestionably there is authority for that method of calculating a proper depreciation reserve, but in our opinion it is artificial, *Page 602 illogical, and unsound, and ought not to be approved, and, since we cannot say that proper methods would not have produced a result which would have affected the rate schedule adopted, the case should be remanded to the commission, in order that it may consider and determine the proper allowance for depreciation in accordance with rules hereinafter stated, and if necessary readjust the rate schedule to cover any changes it may make in that allowance.
The allowance of a given percentage on the gross income of the company as a method for computing depreciation is said to be justified by accounting usages, but in such a case as this we are not dealing with bookkeeping customs, but with substantive rights protected by constitutional guaranties, and there seems to be no logical reason why the depreciation should not be based upon the actual value of the property itself, rather than upon vague and conjectural inferences drawn from the money the property earns. The accuracy of such a method must be largely subjective, since there is no apparent connection or relation between the income which property yields and the depreciation resulting from its use in earning that income. It is true that it is said to have been tested by more direct and intelligible methods, but, if that is so, such methods should have been used in the first place, and not as mere checks upon a method not justified either by law or logic. But even so, if the conclusion actually reached was proper, the fact that it was reached by improper methods would not justify us in disturbing it, so that the more important question is whether the base of the calculations by which it was tested was itself lawful. And that depends upon whether the commission should have based its allowance for depreciation upon the original cost of the property, or upon its present value. It actually did use cost and not present value as the basis of its conclusion, and here again it must be said that there is authority for its procedure. But in our opinion it is justified by neither law nor right reason.
In valuing the property for rate making purposes, the commission based its conclusion upon its present value and not upon its original cost, and in fact the case of Havre de *Page 603 Grace Bridge Co. v. Pub. Serv. Commn., supra, left it no alternative. But if it was essential to adopt that method for ascertaining the value of the property to which the rates were applied, it is not easy to see why it should not be adopted in estimating the amount needed to replace that property when it is worn out or becomes obsolete and worthless. If the company paid $100,000 for property now only worth $10,000, it would be grossly unfair to the public to base its annual depreciation on its cost, and if on the other hand the company paid $10,000 for property now worth $100,000, it would be equally unfair to it to compel it to sell that property to the public at ten per cent. of its real value. These conclusions seem to be self evident, and, while there is authority to the contrary, they are supported by the reasoning in such cases as the Havre de Grace Bridge Co. v. Pub.Serv. Commn., supra; Knoxville v. Knoxville Water Co., supra,
and Michigan Pub. Util. Commn. v. Mich. St. Tel. Co.,
Counsel for the commission suggest that to restore value would be to "require the financing of additions to plant, to the extent of the excess of replacement over original cost of property replaced, by the public, which would in turn have to pay a return on the capital thus required." The meaning of that suggestion is not altogether clear, but if it is that the company is entitled to the return of anything less than the value of its property, it cannot be sustained. Money deducted from earnings to replace equipment, which has become worn out or obsolete, by other equipment of the same character and the same value, adds nothing to the company's resources but merely keeps them at the same level. *Page 604
In testing the result arrived at by allowing a depreciation reserve of five per cent. on the gross income of the company, the commission appears to have been largely influenced by the history of the company during the last few years. That is, it appears to have concluded that, since the company had not actually expended its entire depreciation reserve in replacement, that it must have been sufficient. But that does not follow. The mere fact that it did not spend its entire reserve on replacements is not conclusive evidence that replacements which were not made were not needed. For the company may have been influenced by such considerations as the condition of the money and supply markets, whether the replacements should be postponed to harmonize with contemplated changes in equipment, or whether the maintenance of a substantial reserve was necessary to financial stability, and we do not regard that as an adequate test. But in our opinion there should have been some physical inspection of the property and investigation of the probable useful life of the property, as shown by the experience of this company and other companies using similar property in the same way, and an estimate made based in part at least upon such an investigation of the probable annual depreciation. The commission suggests that such a test could only be properly applied to accrued depreciation, but we see no force in that argument. If an inspection of equipment shows it to be in a fair condition of repair, and experience and judgment indicate that with reasonable care it should last for a reasonably certain time before becoming worthless, that would certainly seem to be a more reliable guide in determining its annual depreciation than the amount of money it earned, or the fact that, when similar equipment became worthless, the company did not see fit to replace it.
The company also takes sharp issue with the commission on its policy in respect to obsolescence as an element of depreciation. It is difficult, because of the method of calculation adopted, to determine to what extent the commission did consider that question, except that it is clear that it did *Page 605 not allow for extraordinary obsolescence, and in that conclusion we are in complete accord. But ordinary obsolescence is a tangible and concrete thing, for which some allowance should be made in any estimate of depreciation in such property as that operated by the company. Experience infallibly indicates that, as a result of social or economic changes, or the progress of science and the improvement of mechanical and electrical equipment, some part of the company's property will from time to time become out of date, and unsuited to its present needs, and should be retired. Such obsolescence is really depreciation, and should be considered in any fair or reasonable estimate of the probable annual depreciation of the company's property. Extraordinary obsolescence, however, is quite another thing, and by extraordinary obsolescence we mean an extensive supersession of property used for the transmission or the generation of power, or instrumentalities used for the transportation of passengers. Such obsolescence has seldom occurred in the past and whether it will occur in the future at all, or, if it does, when it will occur, and how extensive it will be, are all matters of unrestrained speculation and conjecture, and we know of no theory upon which any depreciation allowance could be made to cover it. If it ever does occur, it can be considered by the commission in the light of actual facts, and such allowance and adjustments made as may be proper under the circumstances, but until it does occur it is entirely irrelevant to any consideration of the proper allowance to be made to cover the anticipated annual depreciation in the company's property.
The last question raised by the appeal is whether the action of the commission in abolishing the second fare zone on the Halethorpe line was unlawful, or unreasonable. In objecting to that action the company has used the term "confiscation" with considerable freedom and some looseness. If, as we have held, rates yielding a return of 6.26 are not confiscatory in law, then it is difficult to see how extending the city fare zone to include Halethorpe is confiscatory, for *Page 606 any loss occasioned by the extension is absorbed by the increased fares and does not in theory affect the rate of return, and if in fact it does affect that rate, such adjustment may be made by the commission as actual experience shows to be necessary to enable the company to earn a fair return on its whole property. Naturally some parts of the company's system are more profitable than others, but that does not make it necessary to establish different fares for the different lines, varying in amount with the prosperity of the several lines. Some reliance was placed upon a supposed "city line standard," but the city line is a mere arbitrary invisible line of separation between political units, and the "standard" was established apparently with the consent of the company, that there might be a single fare within the city limits, and has certainly been disregarded in at least several instances. The extension to Halethorpe is not profitable, was built at a loss at the request of the inhabitants of the territory served by it, and, it is intimated, upon their assurance that they would not ask that it be included in the city fare zone. It is nevertheless a part of the entire system, and the rates charged on it should be measured to some extent at least by the standards applied to other parts of the system.
The commission found as a matter of fact that "the total distance from the center of the city that may be traveled on the Halethorpe line is a fraction more than five miles, while the single fare zones on nine other lines extending into the suburbs are longer than the two zones to Halethorpe. As pointed out by counsel, the first fare zones of six of these nine lines extend a substantial distance beyond the Baltimore City limits. Five of them have no second fare zones whatever." That finding was based upon undisputed evidence, and in our judgment afforded a substantial basis for the action of the commission in including the entire Halethorpe line within a single fare zone, and we cannot say that it was either unlawful or unreasonable, and we will not therefore disturb that part of its order which deals with that question. North. Cent. Rwy. Co. v. Pub. Serv. Commn.,
For reasons already stated, it follows that so much of the decree from which this appeal was taken as vacates that part of the order of the commission which fixes the schedule of fares to be charged by the company, and so much of said decree as enjoins the enforcement of that part of said order, was erroneous, but because that schedule was in part based upon an allowance for annual depreciation arrived at by unlawful and unreasonable methods and by the use of an unlawful and unreasonable basis, that part of the decree will neither be affirmed nor reversed, but the case will be remanded, in order that the commission may further consider the question of depreciation, and make any changes in the rate schedule which may be necessary and requisite to yield to the company a fair and reasonable return upon the fair value of its property. And so much of the decree as affirms that part of the order which extends the first fare zone of the Halethorpe line to the terminus thereof will be affirmed.
Decree affirmed in part and reversed in part and case remandedfor further proceedings in accordance with the views expressed inthis opinion, each party to pay one-half the costs.
Cedar Rapids Gas Light Co. v. City of Cedar Rapids ( 1912 )
Willcox v. Consolidated Gas Co. ( 1909 )
Interstate Commerce Commission v. Union Pacific Railroad ( 1912 )
Dayton-Goose Creek Railway Co. v. United States, Interstate ... ( 1924 )
Railroad and Warehouse Commission of Minnesota v. Duluth ... ( 1926 )
Public Service Commission v. Byron ( 1927 )
Bluefield Water Works & Improvement Co. v. Public Service ... ( 1923 )
Des Moines Gas Co. v. City of Des Moines ( 1915 )
ILLINOIS CENT. & C. RR v. Inter. Com. Comm. ( 1907 )
Havre De Grace & Perryville Bridge Co. v. Towers ( 1918 )
Pub. S. Com. v. N.C. Rwy. Co. ( 1914 )