DocketNumber: No. 24,645.
Judges: Wilson
Filed Date: 4/9/1925
Status: Precedential
Modified Date: 10/19/2024
It is claimed by the appellant as follows: (a) That the contract between appellant and the association is void and unenforceable for want of mutuality; (b) that it is designed to create a monopoly and is a combination in restraint of trade; and that plaintiff is a combination of persons to monopolize the markets for food products contrary to section 34, article 4 of our state Constitution; (c) that plaintiff's organization is in contravention of the provisions of the Fourteenth Amendment to the Constitution of the United States in that it denies the equal protection of the laws to persons other than those named and therein referred to and deprives appellant of his property without due process of law; (d) that it contravenes the provisions of sections 2, 5, and 8 of article 1 of our Constitution; (e) that said statute is unconstitutional for the reason that it has the effect of controlling and burdening interstate commerce and regulates and restricts the freedom of the market in interstate commerce; (f) that said statute is unconstitutional wherein it provides for the infliction of penalties upon the appellant and that said contract is contrary to the established public policy of this state; (g) that plaintiff is not entitled to equitable relief and has an adequate remedy at law.
1. The statute is an enabling act authorizing the formation of associations to carry out the purposes expressed in the statute. Its language must be liberally construed for the purpose of promoting its object. Its provisions should not receive a strained and technical interpretation for the purpose of defeating its manifest purposes. Kansas W.G. Assn. v. Schulte,
(a) 2. The assertion is made that this contract is lacking in mutuality of obligation and is unilateral in character. The statute authorizes the contract. The contract expresses mutual obligations. The consideration is obvious. A contract is not unilateral where it contains mutual obligations binding on both parties. It *Page 474
is also supported by the obligation of third persons. Texas Farm Bureau Cotton Assn. v. Stovall,
(b) 3. Defendant says the association is a monopoly and that its manner of doing business constitutes a restraint of trade. If this statute will permit the association to have control of the wheat market so that it may at pleasure raise the price of wheat above its real value or above what it would bring under competition, it would be a monopoly. If it may lower or raise prices at will, it is a monopoly. Pulp Wood Co. v. Green Bay Paper Fiber Co.
"FREEDOM OF MARKETS — MONOPOLIES — Any combination of persons, either as individuals or as members or officers of any corporation, to monopolize the markets for food products in this state, or to interfere with, or restrict the freedom of such markets, is hereby declared to be a criminal conspiracy, and shall be punished in such manner as the legislature may provide."
This provision of the Constitution is restrictive only. It says that persons must not monopolize the markets for food products, or interfere with or restrict the freedom of such markets.
The association handles only the products of its own members. It does so without profit. There is no capital stock. The law authorizes the making of membership contracts and specifies remedies for breach thereof. One of the main features of this law is to minimize the expense of the middleman. It also tends to protect the farmer against alleged unscrupulous conduct of others in the market. The sole purpose of this law is, by an economical marketing of the crop owned by its members, to obtain to them a fair and reasonable price, without useless expense, and without necessarily increasing the cost to the consumer. The association advances money to the members for their immediate needs, protecting them from having to sell on an unsatisfactory market. *Page 475
No one can join the association but a producer. He is not forced to join. He does so voluntarily. It is entirely optional with every producer. Each member has but one vote. It is an organization of farmers, and farmers are characteristically meticulous. The citizendom of the state is not complaining. In fact, this law puts the association under the supervision of the public examiner who is authorized to take possession of its property, if he is of the opinion that its further operation is hazardous to the public interest. This gives assurance that the public will learn at all times how the business is being conducted and will know that it is not being conducted in a manner detrimental to the public welfare. Any of the officers are subject to removal by the Governor.
Subsequent to the World War the returns to the farmer were pitifully inadequate. His lands depreciated in value. The things he had to buy did not depreciate proportionately. His condition was critical. The state, and in fact the government, responded to a sympathetic cooperation in an economic rehabilitation of the stability of the agricultural interest. The policy of our nation is apparent in exempting agricultural organization, instituted for the purpose of mutual help, and not having capital stock or conducted for profit, from the operation of the Sherman Anti-Trust Act. Section 8835 of U.S. Comp. St. vol. 8, p. 9686. Also by 42 U.S. St. at large, c. 57, adopted February 18, 1922, p. 388, which act, like the one under consideration, provides for government supervision. It is for the interest of our social, moral and financial welfare that the producers in our state be able to materially succeed so that they may enjoy and be inspired by reasonable success and achievements and thereby be the better enabled to properly carry on the duties of citizenship. It was clearly to this end that this law was enacted. About three-fourths of our states have now enacted such laws. Cooperative associations are favored by our laws. Such associations cannot live in the absence of harmony within.
Section 35, article 4, of our Constitution does not say how marketing shall be done; nor does it preclude the regulation thereof. As indicated above, the legislature has surrounded this law with every safeguard against it possibly resulting in a monopoly and if its *Page 476 declared lawful purposes should, by unscrupulous officials, be diverted into those illegal transactions, which would subject it to the assault now made upon it, its immediate death would be certain. The law is purely one of expediency and to better the economic condition of the producer. This statute makes the association possible. The association frees the market, makes it more open, less one-sided, less subject to manipulation and monopoly control on the part of those who deal in the commodities. It aids and harmonizes with this constitutional provision which is aimed at those who hoard and speculate in food products and who interfere arbitrarily and artificially with the natural flow of commerce in such products. It offers a plan as a basis for hope that the market may be stabilized and protected from fluctuation incident to an entire year's crop being dumped upon the market within a period of 60 days and thereby demoralizing the market in the consequent fluctuation, in price, which, in practice, is detrimental to the producer and of little benefit to the public.
There is nothing in the organic law of the association that indicates that its purposes are in any way antagonistic to the Constitution or to section 10463, G.S. 1923, enacted pursuant thereto, or to the spirit and intent of the Co-operative Marketing Act. In fact, all the wheat owned by the members is sold upon the markets in open competition with dealers. The wheat is delivered to local elevators. The same agencies and instrumentalities are used to put the wheat on the market. It reaches the same terminals, and is sold to the same millers. The association is merely a selling agency. As such agency it carries on the marketing for its members who pool the price in grain from time to time. The agency can do little more than a businesslike farmer who is financially able to choose his market. By reason of having credit, it may do more than a farmer whose finances will not permit him to wait for a satisfactory market. It may perhaps by selling in large quantities sell to better advantage, but no better than any other dealer or sales agency with ample capital. The association makes no effort to do anything that the individual member might not legally do for himself. We see nothing in the organization, if carried out in the *Page 477 spirit and intent in which the law was passed, to infringe upon the constitutional provisions. The legislature has surrounded the organization scheme with every protection, so that if any attempt is made to violate the spirit and intent of the statute the parties are subjected to the restrictions of the law.
We do not say that this organization like any other corporation, association or individual may not violate the law. It may. If so, it may be punished the same as all other persons or corporations who transgress. These persons come both in the name and intent of an open, free and unrestricted market. They seek the privileges of such in equal competition with dealers. They ask for nothing more. The articles of association, by-laws and the statute under which it is organized proclaim its legality. Every provision of the contract which is pointed to as an element of the alleged act constituting a restraint of trade is authorized by the statute. The statute does not authorize anything forbidden by the Constitution. The element that puts a monopoly under the ban of the law is that it tends to prevent competition and enhances the price of the commodity involved or deteriorates quality or service and impoverishes the competitor, and these characteristics are absent in plaintiff's scheme of organization. The divergent opinion in this difficult field of legislative action should admonish us that we must not close the door to experiment within a law so surrounded by governmental watchfulness and control. Under similar statutes where questions have been raised it has been generally held that an organization of this character is not an unreasonable combination in restraint of trade, nor a monopoly in the sale of such products. Kansas W.G. Assn. v. Schulte,
The object of such a co-operative marketing agency is to serve the financially weaker and more scattered members of society and *Page 478
this is on the theory that by giving such aid to such persons it enures to the public welfare. Obviously there is a great difference with reference to the effect upon society between a combination of a few or many financially powerful men or corporations who are able to get together and dominate and control a particular industry and the prices of its products, and a combination of farmers each weak in his individual strength and financial power numbering into thousands and located here and there over a large territory. The most that can be expected from co-operative marketing organizations is an improvement in the condition of the agricultural classes. There is nothing in this arrangement relative to the price at which wheat shall be sold by the association. It has power and discretion to sell to best advantage. But it is not given all the power at the end of the bargain. A steady market and a reasonable price are the prominent features of the plan. The association is also ambitious to have a continuous market for the producer for 12 months in the year instead of two or three. It is difficult to understand how a steady market and a reasonable and profitable price to the producer would be inimical to the public welfare of the state. Such would be beneficial, not only to the producer, but to every person engaged in any business in the state. It is certain that those who might wish to monopolize the market would never adopt this law for their instrumentality. Financial discouragement from what is believed to be unfair dealing, like idleness, tends toward degeneracy. We see no opportunity in the lawful performance of the corporate duties of the association to interfere with or restrict the freedom of the markets, unless it may be said that this results from holding wheat to sell on a satisfactory market. Each farmer has this privilege. We see no reason why, under the restrictions imposed by the law, this association as a selling agency should not have the same privilege in this respect. If, technically, there is any such interference or restriction in this conduct, it is insignificant and no such interference or restriction resulting from a law of this character should have judicial recognition, unless the result thereof is detrimental to the public interests. Interested parties are entitled to fair protection. Wash. Cran. G. Assn. v. Moore,
There is no justification for the suggestion that an orderly, systematized, cooperative marketing authorized by law to prevent a sacrifice of the farmers' products and to realize a reasonable profit has any analogy to financial combinations in restraint of trade which have at times tended to prevent the farmer from realizing a fair profit and a decent living. In fact, this cooperative measure may have more tendency to avoid monopolies by others than it does to create a monopoly by the limited number of farmers who will join it. This court is justified in taking judicial knowledge, as it does, of the economic conditions of the farmer in our country because they are matters of general knowledge, history and of public interest. In re Cons. Ditch No. 1,
We are of the opinion that this statute does not offend section 35, article 4, of the state Constitution.
(c) 4. The defendant asserts that this statute denies him the equal protection of the laws and deprives him of his property without due process of law. The Fourteenth Amendment was designed not only to avoid arbitrary spoilation of property, but that equal protection and security should be given to all under like circumstances in the enjoyment of their personal and civil rights; and that no restriction should be imposed to the pursuit of any one, except if applied to the same pursuits by others under like circumstances; and, that no person should be subjected to greater burdens than any other person in the same calling and conditions and that all persons should be treated alike, under like circumstances, and considering both the privileges conferred and the limitations imposed. And as said in Duncan v. Missouri,
The purposes of the Minnesota Co-operating Marketing Act are disclosed by section 6082, G.S. 1923, as follows:
"An association may be organized to engage in any activity in connection with the marketing or selling of the agricultural products of its members, or with the harvesting, preserving, drying, processing, canning, packing, grading, storing, handling, shipping, or the manufacturing or the by-products thereof, or in connection with the manufacturing, selling or supplying to its members of machinery, equipment or supplies; or in the financing of the above enumerated activities; or in any one or more of the activities specified therein."
By section 18, article
Much emphasis has been given the case of Connolly v. U.S. Pipe Co.
"Looking specially at its provisions, it will be seen that, so far as the statute is concerned, two or more agriculturalists or two or more live stock raisers may, in respect of their products or live stock in hand, combine their capital, skill or acts for the purpose of creating or carrying out restrictions in the sale of such products or live stock; or limiting, increasing or reducing their price; or preventing competition in their sale or purchase; or fixing a standard or figure whereby the price thereof to the public may be controlled; or making contracts whereby they would become bound not to sell or dispose of such agricultural products or live stock below a common standard figure or card or list price; or establishing the price of such products or stock in hand, so as to preclude free and unrestricted competition among themselves or others; or by agreeing to pool, combine or unite any interest they may have in connection with the sale or transportation of their products or live stock that the price might be affected. All this, so far as the statute is concerned, may be done by agriculturists or live stock raisers in Illinois without subjecting them to the fine imposed by the statute. But exactly the same things, if done by two or more persons, firms, corporations or associations of persons, who shall have combined their capital, skill or acts, in respect of their property, merchandise or commodities held for sale or exchange, are made by the statute a public offense, and every principal, manager, director, agent, servant or employe knowingly carrying out the purposes, stipulations and orders of such combination is punishable by a fine of not less than two thousand nor more than five thousand dollars."
If the Minnesota Co-operative Marketing Law may be read or construed to authorize the producers to carry out a common plan of restriction in the sale of agricultural products; limiting, increasing, or reducing the price; preventing competition in their sale or purchase; fixing a standard or figure whereby the price thereof to the public may be controlled; making contracts whereby they would become bound not to sell or dispose of such products below a common standard figure or card or list price; or establishing the price of such products so as to preclude free and unrestricted competition *Page 482
among themselves or others; or by agreeing to pool, combine or unite their interest in connection with the sale and transportation of such products that the price might be affected, then the Connolly case would be authority in support of the assertion that such marketing act would be in contravention of the Fourteenth Amendment. In discussing the application of section 35, article
In any event, the propriety of the classification for the purpose of legislation is primarily for the legislature. We assume that the legislature makes the necessary inquiry and rightly determines the propriety of the classification which it adopts, and we will disturb the legislative determination only when the classification is arbitrary and without reasonable basis. Seamer v. G.N. Ry. Co.
(d) 5. Sections 2, 5 and 8, article 1, of our Constitution have been called to the support of defendant, but we find them without application.
(e) 6. Since we find that the statute does not restrict the freedom of the market in violation of section 35, article 4, of our Constitution, it necessarily follows that the statute does not control or burden interstate commerce nor restrict the freedom of the market in interstate commerce.
(f) 7. It is said that the statute must fall because it inflicts penalties upon defendant and is contrary to the public policy of the state. The public policy has been in the law itself adequately declared to the contrary. We cannot say that 25 cents per bushel is *Page 484
unjust or oppressive or out of all proportion to the damages which would result from a breach of the contract. We must, therefore, construe the amount as liquidated damages rather than a penalty. Potter v. Dark T.G. Coop. Assn.
(g) 8. Is the plaintiff entitled to equitable relief? The contract provides:
"20. Inasmuch as the remedy at law would be inadequate and inasmuch as it is now and ever will be impracticable and extremely difficult to determine the actual damage resulting to the Association, should the Grower fail to sell and deliver all of his wheat, the Grower hereby agrees to pay to the Association for all wheat delivered, sold, consigned or marketed by or for him other than in accordance with the terms hereof, the sum of twenty-five cents per bushel as liquidated damages for the breach of this contract, all parties agreeing that this contract is one of a series dependent for its true value upon the adherence of each and all of the contracting parties to each and all of the said contracts."
"21. The Grower agrees that in event of a breach by him of any material provision hereof, particularly as to delivery or marketing of any wheat other than to or through the Association, the association shall, upon further action instituted by it, be entitled to an injunction to prevent further breach thereof, and a decree for specific performance hereof, according to the terms of this agreement; and the Association and the Grower expressly agree that this agreement is not a contract for personal services or demanding exceptional capacity or talents; and that this is a contract for the purchase and sale of personal property under special circumstances and conditions and that the buyer cannot go into the open markets and buy wheat to replace any which the Grower may fail to deliver; and that this contract will be the proper subject for the remedy of specific performance in the event of a breach thereof. In the event of any breach or threatened breach of this contract any and all remedies provided for in the ``Co-operative Marketing Act' of this state shall be available." *Page 485
The parties have thus provided for liquidated damages, but does that damage give the plaintiff a full, complete and adequate remedy? It does not. Plaintiff is entitled to equitable redress. It is, as stated, a co-operative marketing association, conducted without profit, limited exclusively to its members. Each member has similar contract relations with it. Each depends upon the other. Its success depends entirely upon the performance by the members. It must, to carry out its purposes, make contract for the disposal of the products acquired by the membership contracts. In making such contracts of disposal, as well as contracts for necessary instrumentalities needed in conducting its business, it must know that it will get the products contracted for. From the very nature of the association it must have the wheat or it cannot exist. Wheat is the only commodity it can use as a going concern. It does not have power to go into the market and buy it. It must have this information in advance and prepare for the future. It must arrange for help, capital and perhaps storage. If one or more members may disregard their contracts with impunity and a loss occurs, there is no way to meet such loss, and if it may be said to be a loss that must be met by the members who remain, then it is obvious that few persons would join or remain members. The consequence would be so serious to plaintiff that the remedy at law is wholly inadequate, nor can it be said that the legal remedy is either full or complete. The only adequate remedy is an injunction preventing the members from breaching their contracts, and thus forcing the delivery of the wheat to the association. The members' breach of such a contract is so fraught with consequences to both the association and the individual members thereof that equity cheerfully puts out its restraining hand with the admonition that the member under such circumstances must not violate the covenants he has voluntarily assumed. He is not compelled to grow wheat, but as long as he produces within the period of the contract, he must not sell to anyone but plaintiff, and he is thus indirectly or negatively required to perform the obligation of his contract.
Oregon G. Coop. Assn. v. Lentz,
Such equitable redress is given regardless of the provision in the contract. Some authorities hold its incorporation, however, of significant importance. Potter v. Dark T.G. Assn. supra. Tobacco Growers Coop. Assn. v. Jones, supra. The statement of liquidated damages in the contract does not conclusively establish that the parties contemplated that upon breach thereof damages would be an adequate remedy. It is a question of intention in each case to be determined from the whole contract and surrounding circumstances. In this case it is expressly stated that equity may be invoked and it is the only adequate remedy. We must conclude that the parties intended that the contract would be enforced, and it will be.
Affirmed.
Hollingsworth v. Texas Hay Ass'n. ( 1922 )
Texas Farm Bureau Cotton Ass'n v. Stovall ( 1923 )
Malmquist v. Hellenic Community of Minneapolis, Inc. ( 1925 )
Magoun v. Illinois Trust & Savings Bank ( 1898 )
Connolly v. Union Sewer Pipe Co. ( 1902 )
Gulf, Colorado & Santa Fé Railway Co. v. Ellis ( 1897 )
American Sugar Refining Co. v. Louisiana ( 1900 )
International Harvester Co. of America v. Missouri ( 1914 )
Poultry Producers of Southern California, Inc. v. Barlow ( 1922 )
State v. Southern Cotton Oil Co. ( 1911 )
Cooperative Assn. v. . Jones ( 1923 )
Malmquist v. Hellenic Community of Minneapolis, Inc. ( 1925 )
Hoff v. First State Bank of Watson ( 1928 )
State Ex Rel. Dedina v. School Board of School District No. ... ( 1926 )
Gammon v. Federated Milk Producers Ass'n, Inc. ( 1961 )
Richard J. Bot Phyllis Bot v. Commissioner of Internal ... ( 2003 )
Travelers Insurance Co. v. Tufte ( 1989 )
Mesaba Loan Co. v. Sher ( 1938 )
United States v. Rock Royal Co-Operative, Inc. ( 1939 )
Thomas v. Housing & Redevelopment Authority of Duluth ( 1951 )