DocketNumber: 07-588
Citation Numbers: 173 L. Ed. 2d 369, 129 S. Ct. 1498, 556 U.S. 208, 2009 U.S. LEXIS 2498
Judges: Breyer, Ginsburg, Scalia, Souter, Stevens
Filed Date: 4/1/2009
Status: Precedential
Modified Date: 11/15/2024
(Slip Opinion) OCTOBER TERM, 2008 1 Syllabus NOTE: Where it is feasible, a syllabus (headnote) will be released, as is being done in connection with this case, at the time the opinion is issued. The syllabus constitutes no part of the opinion of the Court but has been prepared by the Reporter of Decisions for the convenience of the reader. See United States v. Detroit Timber & Lumber Co.,200 U. S. 321
, 337. SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES Syllabus ENTERGY CORP. v. RIVERKEEPER, INC., ET AL. CERTIORARI TO THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE SECOND CIRCUIT No. 07–588. Argued December 2, 2008—Decided April 1, 2009* Petitioners’ powerplants have “cooling water intake structures” that threaten the environment by squashing against intake screens (“im pingement”) or suctioning into the cooling system (“entrainment”) aquatic organisms from the water sources tapped to cool the plants. Thus, the facilities are subject to regulation under the Clean Water Act, which mandates that “[a]ny standard established pursuant to section 1311 . . . or section 1316 . . . and applicable to a point source shall require that the location, design, construction, and capacity of cooling water intake structures reflect the best technology available for minimizing adverse environmental impact.”33 U. S. C. §1326
(b). Sections 1311 and 1316, in turn, employ a variety of “best technology” standards to regulate effluent discharge into the Nation’s waters. The Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) promulgated the §1326(b) regulations at issue after nearly three decades of making the “best technology available” determination on a case-by-case basis. Its “Phase I” regulations govern new cooling water intake structures, while the “Phase II” rules at issue apply to certain large existing fa cilities. In the latter rules, the EPA set “national performance stan dards,” requiring most Phase II facilities to reduce “impingement mortality for [aquatic organisms] by 80 to 95 percent from the calcu lation baseline,” and requiring a subset of facilities to reduce en trainment of such organisms by “60 to 90 percent from [that] base line.”40 CFR §125.94
(b)(1), (2). However, the EPA expressly declined to mandate closed-cycle cooling systems, or equivalent re —————— * Together with No. 07–589, PSEG Fossil LLC et al. v. Riverkeeper, Inc., et al., and No. 07–597, Utility Water Act Group v. Riverkeeper, Inc., et al., also on certiorari to the same court. 2 ENTERGY CORP. v. RIVERKEEPER, INC. Syllabus ductions in impingement and entrainment, as it had done in its Phase I rules, in part because the cost of rendering existing facilities closed-cycle compliant would be nine times the estimated cost of compliance with the Phase II performance standards, and because other technologies could approach the performance of closed-cycle op eration. The Phase II rules also permit site-specific variances from the national performance standards, provided that the permit-issuing authority imposes remedial measures that yield results “as close as practicable to the applicable performance standards.” §125.94(a)(5)(i), (ii). Respondents—environmental groups and vari ous States—challenged the Phase II regulations. Concluding that cost-benefit analysis is impermissible under33 U. S. C. §1326
(b), the Second Circuit found the site-specific cost-benefit variance provision unlawful and remanded the regulations to the EPA for it to clarify whether it had relied on cost-benefit analysis in setting the national performance standards. Held: The EPA permissibly relied on cost-benefit analysis in setting the national performance standards and in providing for cost-benefit variances from those standards as part of the Phase II regulations. Pp. 7–16. (a) The EPA’s view that §1326(b)’s “best technology available for minimizing adverse environmental impact” standard permits consid eration of the technology’s costs and of the relationship between those costs and the environmental benefits produced governs if it is a rea sonable interpretation of the statute—not necessarily the only possi ble interpretation, nor even the interpretation deemed most reason able by the courts. Chevron U. S. A. Inc. v. Natural Resources Defense Council, Inc.,467 U. S. 837
, 843–844. The Second Circuit took “best technology” to mean the technology that achieves the greatest reduction in adverse environmental impacts at a reasonable cost to the industry, but it may also describe the technology that most efficiently produces a good, even if it produces a lesser quantity of that good than other available technologies. This reading is not pre cluded by the phrase “for minimizing adverse environmental impact.” Minimizing admits of degree and is not necessarily used to refer ex clusively to the “greatest possible reduction.” Other Clean Water Act provisions show that when Congress wished to mandate the greatest feasible reduction in water pollution, it used plain language, e.g., “elimination of discharges of all pollutants,” §1311(b)(2)(A). Thus, §1326(b)’s use of the less ambitious goal of “minimizing adverse envi ronmental impact” suggests that the EPA has some discretion to de termine the extent of reduction warranted under the circumstances, plausibly involving a consideration of the benefits derived from re ductions and the costs of achieving them. Pp. 7–9. Cite as: 556 U. S. ____ (2009) 3 Syllabus (b) Considering §1326(b)’s text, and comparing it with the text and statutory factors applicable to parallel Clean Water Act provisions, prompts the conclusion that it was well within the bounds of reason able interpretation for the EPA to conclude that cost-benefit analysis is not categorically forbidden. In the Phase II rules the EPA sought only to avoid extreme disparities between costs and benefits, limiting variances from Phase II’s “national performance standards” to cir cumstances where the costs are “significantly greater than the bene fits” of compliance.40 CFR §125.94
(a)(5)(ii). In defining “national performance standards” the EPA assumed the application of tech nologies whose benefits approach those estimated for closed-cycle cooling systems at a fraction of the cost. That the EPA has for over thirty years interpreted §1326(b) to permit a comparison of costs and benefits, while not conclusive, also tends to show that its interpreta tion is reasonable and hence a legitimate exercise of its discretion. Even respondents and the Second Circuit ultimately recognize that some comparison of costs and benefits is permitted. The Second Cir cuit held that §1326(b) mandates only those technologies whose costs can be reasonably borne by the industry. But whether it is reason able to bear a particular cost can very well depend on the resulting benefits. Likewise, respondents concede that the EPA need not re quire that industry spend billions to save one more fish. This con cedes the principle, and there is no statutory basis for limiting the comparison of costs and benefits to situations where the benefits are de minimis rather than significantly disproportionate. Pp. 9–16.475 F. 3d 83
, reversed and remanded. SCALIA, J., delivered the opinion of the Court, in which ROBERTS, C. J., and KENNEDY, THOMAS, and ALITO, JJ., joined. BREYER, J., filed an opinion concurring in part and dissenting in part. STEVENS, J., filed a dissenting opinion, in which SOUTER and GINSBURG, JJ., joined. Cite as: 556 U. S. ____ (2009) 1 Opinion of the Court NOTICE: This opinion is subject to formal revision before publication in the preliminary print of the United States Reports. Readers are requested to notify the Reporter of Decisions, Supreme Court of the United States, Wash ington, D. C. 20543, of any typographical or other formal errors, in order that corrections may be made before the preliminary print goes to press. SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES _________________ Nos. 07–588, 07–589 and 07–597 _________________ ENTERGY CORPORATION, PETITIONER 07–588 v. RIVERKEEPER, INC., ET AL. PSEG FOSSIL LLC, ET AL., PETITIONERS 07–589 v. RIVERKEEPER, INC., ET AL. UTILITY WATER ACT GROUP, PETITIONER 07–597 v. RIVERKEEPER, INC., ET AL. ON WRITS OF CERTIORARI TO THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE SECOND CIRCUIT [April 1, 2009] JUSTICE SCALIA delivered the opinion of the Court. These cases concern a set of regulations adopted by the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA or agency) under §316(b) of the Clean Water Act,33 U. S. C. §1326
(b).69 Fed. Reg. 41576
(2004). Respondents—environmental groups and various States1—challenged those regulations, and the Second Circuit set them aside. Riverkeeper, Inc. v. —————— 1 The EPA and its Administrator appeared as respondents in support of petitioners. See Brief for Federal Parties as Respondents Supporting Petitioners. References to “respondents” throughout the opinion refer only to those parties challenging the EPA rules at issue in these cases. 2 ENTERGY CORP. v. RIVERKEEPER, INC. Opinion of the Court EPA,475 F. 3d 83
, 99–100 (2007). The issue for our deci sion is whether, as the Second Circuit held, the EPA is not permitted to use cost-benefit analysis in determining the content of regulations promulgated under §1326(b). I Petitioners operate—or represent those who operate— large powerplants. In the course of generating power, those plants also generate large amounts of heat. To cool their facilities, petitioners employ “cooling water intake structures” that extract water from nearby water sources. These structures pose various threats to the environment, chief among them the squashing against intake screens (elegantly called “impingement”) or suction into the cool ing system (“entrainment”) of aquatic organisms that live in the affected water sources. See69 Fed. Reg. 41586
. Accordingly, the facilities are subject to regulation under the Clean Water Act,33 U. S. C. §1251
et seq., which mandates: “Any standard established pursuant to section 1311 of this title or section 1316 of this title and applicable to a point source shall require that the location, de sign, construction, and capacity of cooling water in take structures reflect the best technology available for minimizing adverse environmental impact.” §1326(b). Sections 1311 and 1316, in turn, employ a variety of “best technology” standards to regulate the discharge of efflu ents into the Nation’s waters. The §1326(b) regulations at issue here were promul gated by the EPA after nearly three decades in which the determination of the “best technology available for mini mizing [cooling water intake structures’] adverse envi ronmental impact” was made by permit-issuing authori ties on a case-by-case basis, without benefit of a governing Cite as: 556 U. S. ____ (2009) 3 Opinion of the Court regulation. The EPA’s initial attempt at such a regulation came to nought when the Fourth Circuit determined that the agency had failed to adhere to the procedural require ments of the Administrative Procedure Act. Appalachian Power Co. v. Train,566 F. 2d 451
, 457 (1977). The EPA withdrew the regulation,44 Fed. Reg. 32956
(1979), and instead published “draft guidance” for use in implement ing §1326(b)’s requirements via site-specific permit deci sions under §1342. See EPA, Office of Water Enforcement Permits Div., {Draft} Guidance for Evaluating the Adverse Impact of Cooling Water Intake Structures on the Aquatic Environment: Section 316(b) P. L. 92–500, (May 1, 1977), at http://www.epa.gov/waterscience/316b/files/1977AEIguid.pdf, (all Internet materials as visited Mar. 30, 2009, and avail able in Clerk of Court’s case file);69 Fed. Reg. 41584
(describing system of case-by-case permits under the draft guidance). In 1995, the EPA entered into a consent decree which, as subsequently amended, set a multiphase timetable for the EPA to promulgate regulations under §1326(b). See Riverkeeper, Inc. v. Whitman, No. 93 Civ. 0314 (AGS),2001 WL 1505497
, *1 (SDNY, Nov. 27, 2001). In the first phase the EPA adopted regulations governing certain new, large cooling water intake structures.66 Fed. Reg. 65256
(2001) (Phase I rules); see40 CFR §§125.80
(a), 125.81(a) (2008). Those rules require new facilities with water intake flow greater than 10 million gallons per day to, among other things, restrict their inflow “to a level com mensurate with that which can be attained by a closed cycle recirculating cooling water system.”2 §125.84(b)(1). New facilities with water-intake flow between 2 million —————— 2 Closed-cycle cooling systems recirculate the water used to cool the facility, and consequently extract less water from the adjacent water way, proportionately reducing impingement and entrainment. Riverkeeper, Inc. v. EPA,358 F. 3d 174
, 182, n. 5 (CA2 2004);69 Fed. Reg. 41601
, and n. 44 (2004). 4 ENTERGY CORP. v. RIVERKEEPER, INC. Opinion of the Court and 10 million gallons per day may alternatively comply by, among other things, reducing the volume and velocity of water removal to certain levels. §125.84(c). And all facilities may alternatively comply by demonstrating, among other things, “that the technologies employed will reduce the level of adverse environmental impact . . . to a comparable level” to what would be achieved by using a closed-cycle cooling system. §125.84(d). These regulations were upheld in large part by the Second Circuit in Riverkeeper, Inc. v. EPA,358 F. 3d 174
(2004). The EPA then adopted the so-called “Phase II” rules at issue here.369 Fed. Reg. 41576
. They apply to existing facilities that are point sources, whose primary activity is the generation and transmission (or sale for transmission) of electricity, and whose water-intake flow is more than 50 million gallons of water per day, at least 25 percent of which is used for cooling purposes.Ibid.
Over 500 facili ties, accounting for approximately 53 percent of the Na tion’s electric-power generating capacity, fall within Phase II’s ambit. See EPA, Economic and Benefits Analysis for the Final Section 316(b) Phase II Existing Facilities Rule, A3–13, Table A3–4 (Feb. 2004), online at http://www. epa.gov/waterscience/316b/phase2/econbenefits/final/a3.pdf. Those facilities remove on average more than 214 billion gallons of water per day, causing impingement and en trainment of over 3.4 billion aquatic organisms per year.69 Fed. Reg. 41586
. To address those environmental impacts, the EPA set “national performance standards,” requiring Phase II facilities (with some exceptions) to reduce “impingement mortality for all life stages of fish and shellfish by 80 to 95 —————— 3 The EPA has also adopted Phase III rules for facilities not subject to the Phase I and Phase II regulations.71 Fed. Reg. 35006
(2006). A challenge to those regulations is currently before the Fifth Circuit, where proceedings have been stayed pending disposition of these cases. See ConocoPhillips Co. v. EPA, No. 06–60662. Cite as: 556 U. S. ____ (2009) 5 Opinion of the Court percent from the calculation baseline”; a subset of facilities must also reduce entrainment of such aquatic organisms by “60 to 90 percent from the calculation baseline.”40 CFR §125.94
(b)(1), (2); see §125.93 (defining “calculation baseline”). Those targets are based on the environmental improvements achievable through deployment of a mix of remedial technologies,69 Fed. Reg. 41599
, which the EPA determined were “commercially available and economi cally practicable,”id., at 41602
. In its Phase II rules, however, the EPA expressly de clined to mandate adoption of closed-cycle cooling systems or equivalent reductions in impingement and entrain ment, as it had done for new facilities subject to the Phase I rules.Id., at 41601
. It refused to take that step in part because of the “generally high costs” of converting existing facilities to closed-cycle operation, and because “other technologies approach the performance of this option.”Id., at 41605
. Thus, while closed-cycle cooling systems could reduce impingement and entrainment mortality by up to 98 percent,id., at 41601
, (compared to the Phase II targets of 80 to 95 percent impingement reduction), the cost of rendering all Phase II facilities closed-cycle-compliant would be approximately $3.5 billion per year,id., at 41605
, nine times the estimated cost of compliance with the Phase II performance standards,id., at 41666
. More over, Phase II facilities compelled to convert to closed-cycle cooling systems “would produce 2.4 percent to 4.0 percent less electricity even while burning the same amount of coal,” possibly requiring the construction of “20 additional 400–MW plants . . . to replace the generating capacity lost.”Id., at 41605
. The EPA thus concluded that “[a]l though not identical, the ranges of impingement and entrainment reduction are similar under both options. . . . [Benefits of compliance with the Phase II rules] can ap proach those of closed-cycle recirculating at less cost with fewer implementation problems.”Id., at 41606
. 6 ENTERGY CORP. v. RIVERKEEPER, INC. Opinion of the Court The regulations permit the issuance of site-specific variances from the national performance standards if a facility can demonstrate either that the costs of compli ance are “significantly greater than” the costs considered by the agency in setting the standards,40 CFR §125.94
(a)(5)(i), or that the costs of compliance “would be significantly greater than the benefits of complying with the applicable performance standards,” §125.94(a)(5)(ii). Where a variance is warranted, the permit-issuing author ity must impose remedial measures that yield results “as close as practicable to the applicable performance stan dards.” §125.94(a)(5)(i), (ii). Respondents challenged the EPA’s Phase II regulations, and the Second Circuit granted their petition for review and remanded the regulations to the EPA. The Second Circuit identified two ways in which the EPA could per missibly consider costs under33 U. S. C. §1326
(b): (1) in determining whether the costs of remediation “can be ‘reasonably borne’ by the industry,” and (2) in determining which remedial technologies are the most cost-effective, that is, the technologies that reach a specified level of benefit at the lowest cost.475 F. 3d, at
99–100. See alsoid., at 98
, and n. 10. It concluded, however, that cost benefit analysis, which “compares the costs and benefits of various ends, and chooses the end with the best net bene fits,”id., at 98
, is impermissible under §1326(b), id., at 100. The Court of Appeals held the site-specific cost-benefit variance provision to be unlawful. Id., at 114. Finding it unclear whether the EPA had relied on cost-benefit analy sis in setting the national performance standards, or had only used cost-effectiveness analysis, it remanded to the agency for clarification of that point. Id., at 104–105. (The remand was also based on other grounds which are not at issue here.) The EPA suspended operation of the Phase II rules pending further rulemaking. 72 Fed. Reg. Cite as: 556 U. S. ____ (2009) 7 Opinion of the Court 37107 (2007). We then granted certiorari limited to the following question: “Whether [§1326(b)] . . . authorizes the [EPA] to compare costs with benefits in determining ‘the best technology available for minimizing adverse envi ronmental impact’ at cooling water intake structures.” 552 U. S. ___ (2008). II In setting the Phase II national performance standards and providing for site-specific cost-benefit variances, the EPA relied on its view that §1326(b)’s “best technology available” standard permits consideration of the technol ogy’s costs,69 Fed. Reg. 41626
, and of the relationship between those costs and the environmental benefits pro duced,id., at 41603
. That view governs if it is a reason able interpretation of the statute—not necessarily the only possible interpretation, nor even the interpretation deemed most reasonable by the courts. Chevron U. S. A. Inc. v. Natural Resources Defense Council, Inc.,467 U. S. 837
, 843–844 (1984).4 As we have described, §1326(b) instructs the EPA to set standards for cooling water intake structures that reflect “the best technology available for minimizing adverse environmental impact.” The Second Circuit took that —————— 4 The dissent finds it “puzzling” that we invoke this proposition (that a reasonable agency interpretation prevails) at the “outset,” omitting the supposedly prior inquiry of “ ‘whether Congress has directly spoken to the precise question at issue.’ ” Post, at 6, n. 5 (opinion of STEVENS, J.) (quoting Chevron,467 U. S., at 842
). But surely if Congress has directly spoken to an issue then any agency interpretation contradict ing what Congress has said would be unreasonable. What is truly “puzzling” is the dissent’s accompanying charge that the Court’s failure to conduct the Chevron step-one inquiry at the outset “reflects [its] reluctance to consider the possibility . . . that Congress’ silence may have meant to foreclose cost-benefit analysis.” Post, at 6, n. 5. Our discussion of that issue, infra, at 11, speaks for itself. 8 ENTERGY CORP. v. RIVERKEEPER, INC. Opinion of the Court language to mean the technology that achieves the great est reduction in adverse environmental impacts at a cost that can reasonably be borne by the industry.475 F. 3d, at
99–100. That is certainly a plausible interpretation of the statute. The “best” technology—that which is “most advantageous,” Webster’s New International Dictionary 258 (2d ed. 1953)—may well be the one that produces the most of some good, here a reduction in adverse environ mental impact. But “best technology” may also describe the technology that most efficiently produces some good. In common parlance one could certainly use the phrase “best technology” to refer to that which produces a good at the lowest per-unit cost, even if it produces a lesser quan tity of that good than other available technologies. Respondents contend that this latter reading is pre cluded by the statute’s use of the phrase “for minimizing adverse environmental impact.” Minimizing, they argue, means reducing to the smallest amount possible, and the “best technology available for minimizing adverse envi ronmental impacts,” must be the economically feasible technology that achieves the greatest possible reduction in environmental harm. Brief for Respondents Riverkeeper, Inc. et al. 25–26. But “minimize” is a term that admits of degree and is not necessarily used to refer exclusively to the “greatest possible reduction.” For example, elsewhere in the Clean Water Act, Congress declared that the proce dures implementing the Act “shall encourage the drastic minimization of paperwork and interagency decision procedures.”33 U. S. C. §1251
(f). If respondents’ defini tion of the term “minimize” is correct, the statute’s use of the modifier “drastic” is superfluous. Other provisions in the Clean Water Act also suggest the agency’s interpretation. When Congress wished to mandate the greatest feasible reduction in water pollution, it did so in plain language: The provision governing the discharge of toxic pollutants into the Nation’s waters Cite as: 556 U. S. ____ (2009) 9 Opinion of the Court requires the EPA to set “effluent limitations [which] shall require the elimination of discharges of all pollutants if the Administrator finds . . . that such elimination is tech nologically and economically achievable,” §1311(b)(2)(A) (emphasis added). See also §1316(a)(1) (mandating “where practicable, a standard [for new point sources] permitting no discharge of pollutants” (emphasis added)). Section 1326(b)’s use of the less ambitious goal of “mini mizing adverse environmental impact” suggests, we think, that the agency retains some discretion to determine the extent of reduction that is warranted under the circum stances. That determination could plausibly involve a consideration of the benefits derived from reductions and the costs of achieving them. Cf.40 CFR §125.83
(defining “minimize” for purposes of the Phase I regulations as “reduc[ing] to the smallest amount, extent, or degree reasonably possible”). It seems to us, therefore, that the phrase “best technology available,” even with the added specification “for minimizing adverse environmental im pact,” does not unambiguously preclude cost-benefit analysis.5 Respondents’ alternative (and, alas, also more complex) argument rests upon the structure of the Clean Water Act. The Act provided that during its initial implementation period existing “point sources”—discrete conveyances from which pollutants are or may be discharged,33 U. S. C. §1362
(14)—were subject to “effluent limitations . . . which shall require the application of the best practicable control technology currently available.” §1311(b)(1)(A) (emphasis —————— 5 Respondents concede that the term “available” is ambiguous, as it could mean either technologically feasible or economically feasible. But any ambiguity in the term “available” is largely irrelevant. Regardless of the criteria that render a technology “available,” the EPA would still have to determine which available technology is the “best” one. And as discussed above, that determination may well involve consideration of the technology’s relative costs and benefits. 10 ENTERGY CORP. v. RIVERKEEPER, INC. Opinion of the Court added). (We shall call this the “BPT” test.) Following that transition period, the Act initially mandated adoption, by July 1, 1983 (later extended to March 31, 1989), of stricter effluent limitations requiring “application of the best available technology economically achievable for such category or class, which will result in reasonable further progress toward the national goal of eliminating the dis charge of all pollutants.” §1311(b)(2)(A) (emphasis added); see EPA v. National Crushed Stone Assn.,449 U. S. 64
, 69–70 (1980). (We shall call this the “BATEA” test.) Sub sequent amendment limited application of this standard to toxic and nonconventional pollutants, and for the remain der established a (presumably laxer) test of “best conven tional-pollutant control technology.” §1311(b)(2)(E).6 (We shall call this “BCT.”) Finally, §1316 subjected certain categories of new point sources to “the greatest degree of effluent reduction which the Administrator determines to be achievable through application of the best available demonstrated control technology.” §1316(a)(1) (emphasis added); §1316(b)(1)(B). (We shall call this the “BADT” test.) The provision at issue here, applicable not to efflu ents but to cooling water intake structures, requires, as we have described, “the best technology available for minimiz ing adverse environmental impact,” §1326(b) (emphasis added). (We shall call this the “BTA” test.) The first four of these tests are elucidated by statutory factor lists that guide their implementation. To take the standards in (presumed) order of increasing stringency, see Crushed Stone,supra,
at 69–70: In applying the BPT test the EPA is instructed to consider, among other fac tors, “the total cost of application of technology in relation —————— 6 The statute does not contain a hyphen between the words “conven tional” and “pollutant.” “Conventional pollutant” is a statutory term, however, see33 U. S. C. §1314
(a)(4), and it is clear that in §1311(b)(2)(E) the adjective modifies “pollutant” rather than “control technology.” The hyphen makes that clear. Cite as: 556 U. S. ____ (2009) 11 Opinion of the Court to the effluent reduction benefits to be achieved.” §1314(b)(1)(B). In applying the BCT test it is instructed to consider “the reasonableness of the relationship between the costs of attaining a reduction in effluents and the effluent reduction benefits derived.” §1314(b)(4)(B) (emphasis added). And in applying the BATEA and BADT tests the EPA is instructed to consider the “cost of achieving such effluent reduction.” §§1314(b)(2)(B), 1316(b)(1)(B). There is no such elucidating language applicable to the BTA test at issue here. To facilitate comparison, the texts of these five tests, the clarifying factors applicable to them, and the entities to which they apply are set forth in the Appendix, infra. The Second Circuit, in rejecting the EPA’s use of cost benefit analysis, relied in part on the propositions that (1) cost-benefit analysis is precluded under the BATEA and BADT tests; and (2) that, insofar as the permissibility of cost-benefit analysis is concerned, the BTA test (the one at issue here) is to be treated the same as those two. See475 F. 3d, at 98
. It is not obvious to us that the first of these propositions is correct, but we need not pursue that point, since we assuredly do not agree with the second. It is certainly reasonable for the agency to conclude that the BTA test need not be interpreted to permit only what those other two tests permit. Its text is not identical to theirs. It has the relatively modest goal of “minimizing adverse environmental impact” as compared with the BATEA’s goal of “eliminating the discharge of all pollut ants.” And it is unencumbered by specified statutory factors of the sort provided for those other two tests, which omission can reasonably be interpreted to suggest that the EPA is accorded greater discretion in determining its precise content. Respondents and the dissent argue that the mere fact that §1326(b) does not expressly authorize cost-benefit analysis for the BTA test, though it does so for two of the 12 ENTERGY CORP. v. RIVERKEEPER, INC. Opinion of the Court other tests, displays an intent to forbid its use. This surely proves too much. For while it is true that two of the other tests authorize cost-benefit analysis, it is also true that all four of the other tests expressly authorize some consideration of costs. Thus, if respondents’ and the dis sent’s conclusion regarding the import of §1326(b)’s silence is correct, it is a fortiori true that the BTA test permits no consideration of cost whatsoever, not even the “cost effectiveness” and “feasibility” analysis that the Second Circuit approved, see supra, at 6, that the dissent would approve, post, at 1–2, and that respondents acknowledge. The inference that respondents and the dissent would draw from the silence is, in any event, implausible, as §1326(b) is silent not only with respect to cost-benefit analysis but with respect to all potentially relevant fac tors. If silence here implies prohibition, then the EPA could not consider any factors in implementing §1326(b)— an obvious logical impossibility. It is eminently reason able to conclude that §1326(b)’s silence is meant to convey nothing more than a refusal to tie the agency’s hands as to whether cost-benefit analysis should be used, and if so to what degree. Contrary to the dissent’s suggestion, see post, at 3–4, our decisions in Whitman v. American Trucking Assns., Inc.,531 U. S. 457
(2001), and American Textile Mfrs. Institute, Inc. v. Donovan,452 U. S. 490
(1981), do not undermine this conclusion. In American Trucking, we held that the text of §109 of the Clean Air Act, “inter preted in its statutory and historical context . . . unambi guously bars cost considerations” in setting air quality standards under that provision.531 U. S., at 471
. The relevant “statutory context” included other provisions in the Clean Air Act that expressly authorized consideration of costs, whereas §109 did not. Id., at 467–468. American Trucking thus stands for the rather unremarkable propo sition that sometimes statutory silence, when viewed in Cite as: 556 U. S. ____ (2009) 13 Opinion of the Court context, is best interpreted as limiting agency discretion. For the reasons discussed earlier, §1326(b)’s silence cannot bear that interpretation. In American Textile, the Court relied in part on a stat ute’s failure to mention cost-benefit analysis in holding that the relevant agency was not required to engage in cost-benefit analysis in setting certain health and safety standards.452 U. S., at
510–512. But under Chevron, that an agency is not required to do so does not mean that an agency is not permitted to do so. This extended consideration of the text of §1326(b), and comparison of that with the text and statutory factors applicable to four parallel provisions of the Clean Water Act, lead us to the conclusion that it was well within the bounds of reasonable interpretation for the EPA to con clude that cost-benefit analysis is not categorically forbid den. Other arguments may be available to preclude such a rigorous form of cost-benefit analysis as that which was prescribed under the statute’s former BPT standard, which required weighing “the total cost of application of technology” against “the . . . benefits to be achieved.” See, supra, at 10. But that question is not before us. In the Phase II requirements challenged here the EPA sought only to avoid extreme disparities between costs and benefits. The agency limited variances from the Phase II “national performance standards” to circumstances where the costs are “significantly greater than the benefits” of compliance.40 CFR §125.94
(a)(5)(ii). In defining the “national performance standards” themselves the EPA assumed the application of technologies whose benefits “approach those estimated” for closed-cycle cooling sys tems at a fraction of the cost: $389 million per year,69 Fed. Reg. 41666
, as compared with (1) at least $3.5 billion per year to operate compliant closed-cycle cooling systems,id., at 41605
(or $1 billion per year to impose similar requirements on a subset of Phase II facilities,id.,
at 14 ENTERGY CORP. v. RIVERKEEPER, INC. Opinion of the Court 41606), and (2) significant reduction in the energy output of the altered facilities,id., at 41605
. And finally, EPA’s assessment of the relatively meager financial benefits of the Phase II regulations that it adopted—reduced im pingement and entrainment of 1.4 billion aquatic organ isms,id., at 41661
, Exh. XII–6, with annualized use benefits of $83 million,id., at 41662
, and non-use benefits of indeterminate value,id.,
at 41660–41661—when com pared to annual costs of $389 million, demonstrates quite clearly that the agency did not select the Phase II regula tory requirements because their benefits equaled their costs. While not conclusive, it surely tends to show that the EPA’s current practice is a reasonable and hence legiti mate exercise of its discretion to weigh benefits against costs that the agency has been proceeding in essentially this fashion for over 30 years. See Alaska Dept. of Envi ronmental Conservation v. EPA,540 U. S. 461
, 487 (2004); Barnhart v. Walton,535 U. S. 212
, 219–220 (2002). As early as 1977, the agency determined that, while §1326(b) does not require cost-benefit analysis, it is also not reason able to “interpret Section [1326(b)] as requiring use of technology whose cost is wholly disproportionate to the environmental benefit to be gained.” In re Public Service Co. of New Hampshire, 1 E. A. D. 332, 340 (1977). See also In re Central Hudson Gas and Electric Corp., EPA Decision of the General Counsel, NPDES Permits, No. 63, pp. 371, 381 (July 29, 1977) (“EPA ultimately must dem onstrate that the present value of the cumulative annual cost of modifications to cooling water intake structures is not wholly out of proportion to the magnitude of the esti mated environmental gains”); Seacoast Anti-Pollution League v. Costle,597 F. 2d 306
, 311 (CA1 1979) (rejecting challenge to an EPA permit decision that was based in part on the agency’s determination that further restric tions would be “ ‘wholly disproportionate to any environ mental benefit’ ”). While the EPA’s prior “wholly dispro Cite as: 556 U. S. ____ (2009) 15 Opinion of the Court portionate” standard may be somewhat different from its current “significantly greater than” standard, there is nothing in the statute that would indicate that the former is a permissible interpretation while the latter is not. Indeed, in its review of the EPA’s Phase I regulations, the Second Circuit seemed to recognize that §1326(b) permits some form of cost-benefit analysis. In considering a challenge to the EPA’s rejection of dry cooling systems7 as the “best technology available” for Phase I facilities the Second Circuit noted that “while it certainly sounds sub stantial that dry cooling is 95 percent more effective than closed-cycle cooling, it is undeniably relevant that that difference represents a relatively small improvement over closed-cycle cooling at a very significant cost.” Riverkeeper,358 F. 3d, at 194, n. 22
. And in the decision below rejecting the use of cost-benefit analysis in the Phase II regulations, the Second Circuit nonetheless interpreted “best technology available” as mandating only those technologies that can “be reasonably borne by the industry.”475 F. 3d, at 99
. But whether it is “reasonable” to bear a particular cost may well depend on the resulting benefits; if the only relevant factor was the feasibility of the costs, their reasonableness would be irrelevant. In the last analysis, even respondents ultimately recog nize that some form of cost-benefit analysis is permissible. They acknowledge that the statute’s language is “plainly not so constricted as to require EPA to require industry petitioners to spend billions to save one more fish or plankton.” Brief for Respondents Riverkeeper, Inc. et al. 29. This concedes the principle—the permissibility of at least some cost-benefit analysis—and we see no statutory basis for limiting its use to situations where the benefits —————— 7 Dry cooling systems use air drafts to remove heat, and accordingly remove little or no water from surrounding water sources. See66 Fed. Reg. 65282
(2001). 16 ENTERGY CORP. v. RIVERKEEPER, INC. Opinion of the Court are de minimis rather than significantly disproportionate. * * * We conclude that the EPA permissibly relied on cost benefit analysis in setting the national performance stan dards and in providing for cost-benefit variances from those standards as part of the Phase II regulations. The Court of Appeals’ reliance in part on the agency’s use of cost-benefit analysis in invalidating the site-specific cost benefit variance provision,475 F. 3d, at 114
, was therefore in error, as was its remand of the national performance standards for clarification of whether cost-benefit analysis was impermissibly used,id.,
at 104–105. We of course express no view on the remaining bases for the Second Circuit’s remand which did not depend on the permissibil ity of cost-benefit analysis. Seeid., at 108, 110, 113, 115, 117, 120
.8 The judgment of the Court of Appeals is re versed, and the cases are remanded for further proceed ings consistent with this opinion. It is so ordered. —————— 8 JUSTICE BREYER would remand for the additional reason of what he regards as the agency’s inadequate explanation of the change in its criterion for variances—from a relationship of costs to benefits that is “ ‘wholly disproportionate’ ” to one that is “ ‘significantly greater.’ ” Post, at 7–8 (opinion concurring in part and dissenting in part). That ques tion can have no bearing upon whether the EPA can use cost-benefit analysis, which is the only question presented here. It seems to us, in any case, that the EPA’s explanation was ample. It explained that the “wholly out of proportion” standard was inappropriate for the existing facilities subject to the Phase II rules because those facilities lack “the greater flexibility available to new facilities for selecting the location of their intakes and installing technologies at lower costs relative to the costs associated with retrofitting existing facilities,” and because “economically impracticable impacts on energy prices, production costs, and energy production . . . could occur if large numbers of Phase II existing facilities incurred costs that were more than ‘significantly greater’ than but not ‘wholly out of proportion’ to the costs in the EPA’s record.”68 Fed. Reg. 13541
(2003). Cite as: 556 U. S. ____ (2009) 17 Opinion of the Court Appendix to opinion of the Court APPENDIX TO OPINION OF THE COURT Entities Statutory Statutorily Mandated Subject to Standard Factors Regulation BPT: “Factors relating to the Existing point “[E]ffluent limitations assessment of best practicable sources during . . . which shall require control technology currently the Clean Water the application of the available . . . shall include Act’s initial best practicable control consideration of the total cost implementation technology currently of application of technology in phase. available.” 33 U. S. C. relation to the effluent §1311(b)(1)(A) (empha reduction benefits to be sis added). achieved.”33 U. S. C. §1314
(b)(1)(B). BCT: “Factors relating to the Existing point “[E]ffluent limitations assessment of best conven sources that . . . which shall require tional pollutant control discharge application of the best technology . . . shall include “conventional conventional pollutant consideration of the reason pollutants” as control technology.” 33 ableness of the relationship defined by the U. S. C. §1311(b)(2)(E) between the costs of attaining EPA under 33 (emphasis added). a reduction in effluents and U. S. C. the effluent reduction benefits §1314(a)(4). derived.”33 U. S. C. §1314
(b)(4)(B). BATEA: “Factors relating to the Existing point “[E]ffluent limitations assessment of best available sources that . . . which . . . shall technology shall take into discharge toxic require application of account . . . the cost of achiev pollutants and the best available ing such effluent reduction.” non technology economically33 U. S. C. §1314
(b)(2)(B). conventional achievable . . . which pollutants. will result in reasonable further progress toward the national goal of eliminating the dis charge of all pollut ants.”33 U. S. C. §1311
(b)(2)(A) (empha sis added). 18 ENTERGY CORP. v. RIVERKEEPER, INC. Opinion of the Court Appendix to opinion of the Court Entities Statutory Statutorily Mandated Subject to Standard Factors Regulation BADT: “[T]he Administrator shall New point “[A] standard for the take into consideration the sources within control of the discharge cost of achieving such effluent the categories of of pollutants which reduction, and any non-water sources identi reflects the greatest quality environmental impact fied by the EPA degree of effluent and energy requirements.” 33 under 33 reduction with the U. S. C. §1316(b)(1)(B). U. S. C. Administrator deter §1316(b)(1)(A). mines to be achievable through application of the best available demonstrated control technology.”33 U. S. C. §1316
(a)(1) (emphasis added). BTA: N/A Point sources “Any standard . . . that operate applicable to a point cooling water source shall require intake struc that the location, tures. design, construction, and capacity of cooling water intake structures reflect the best technol ogy available for minimizing adverse environmental impact.”33 U. S. C. §1326
(b). Cite as: 556 U. S. ____ (2009) 1 Opinion of BREYER, J. SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES _________________ Nos. 07–588, 07–589 and 07–597 _________________ ENTERGY CORPORATION, PETITIONER 07–588 v. RIVERKEEPER, INC., ET AL. PSEG FOSSIL LLC, ET AL., PETITIONERS 07–589 v. RIVERKEEPER, INC., ET AL. UTILITY WATER ACT GROUP, PETITIONER 07–597 v. RIVERKEEPER, INC., ET AL. ON WRITS OF CERTIORARI TO THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE SECOND CIRCUIT [April 1, 2009] JUSTICE BREYER, concurring in part and dissenting in part. I agree with the Court that the relevant statutory lan guage authorizes the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) to compare costs and benefits. Ante, at 7–13. None theless the drafting history and legislative history of related provisions, Pub. L. 92–500, §§301, 304,86 Stat. 844
, 850, as amended,33 U. S. C. §§1311
, 1314, make clear that those who sponsored the legislation intended the law’s text to be read as restricting, though not forbid ding, the use of cost-benefit comparisons. And I would apply that text accordingly. I Section 301 provides that, not later than 1977, effluent 2 ENTERGY CORP. v. RIVERKEEPER, INC. Opinion of BREYER, J. limitations for point sources shall require the application of “best practicable control technology,” §301(b)(1)(A),86 Stat. 845
(emphasis added); and that, not later than 1983 (later extended to 1989), effluent limitations for categories and classes of point sources shall require application of the “best available technology economically achievable,” §301(b)(2)(A), ibid. (emphasis added). Section 304(b), in turn, identifies the factors that the Agency shall take into account in determining (1) “best practicable control tech nology” and (2) “best available technology.”86 Stat. 851
(emphasis added). With respect to the first, the statute provides that the factors taken into account by the Agency “shall include consideration of the total cost of application of technology in relation to the effluent reduction benefits to be achieved from such application . . . and such other factors as the Administrator deems appropriate.” §304(b)(1)(B), ibid. With respect to the second, the statute says that the Agency “shall take into account . . . the cost of achieving such effluent reduction” and “such other factors as the Administrator deems appropriate.” §304(b)(2)(B), ibid. The drafting history makes clear that the statute re flects a compromise. In the House version of the legisla tion, the Agency was to consider “the cost and the eco nomic, social, and environmental impact of achieving such effluent reduction” when determining both “best practica ble” and “best available” technology. H. R. 11896, 92d Cong., 2d Sess., §§304(b)(1)(B), (b)(2)(B) (1972) (as re ported from committee). The House Report explained that the “best available technology” standard was needed—as opposed to mandating the elimination of discharge of pollutants—because “the difference in the cost of 100 percent elimination of pollutants as compared to the cost of removal of 97–99 percent of the pollutants in an effluent can far exceed any reasonable benefit to be achieved. In most cases, the cost of removal of the last few percentage Cite as: 556 U. S. ____ (2009) 3 Opinion of BREYER, J. points increases expo[n]entially.” H. R. Rep. No. 92–911, p. 103 (1972). In the Senate version, the Agency was to consider “the cost of achieving such effluent reduction” when determin ing both “best practicable” and “best available” technology. S. 2770, 92d Cong., 1st Sess., §§304(b)(1)(B), (b)(2)(B) (1971) (as reported from committee). The Senate Report explains that “the technology must be available at a cost . . . which the Administrator determines to be reasonable.” S. Rep. No. 92–414, p. 52 (1971) (hereinafter S. Rep.). But it said nothing about comparing costs and benefits. The final statute reflects a modification of the House’s language with respect to “best practicable,” and an adop tion of the Senate’s language with respect to “best avail able.” S. Conf. Rep. No. 92–1236, pp. 124–125 (1972). The final statute does not require the Agency to compare costs to benefits when determining “best available technology,” but neither does it expressly forbid such a comparison. The strongest evidence in the legislative history sup porting the respondents’ position—namely, that Congress intended to forbid comparisons of costs and benefits when determining the “best available technology”—can be found in a written discussion of the Act’s provisions distributed to the Senate by Senator Edmund Muskie, the Act’s prin cipal sponsor, when he submitted the Conference Report for the Senate’s consideration. 118 Cong. Rec. 33693 (1972). The relevant part of that discussion points out that, as to “best practicable technology,” the statute re quires application of a “balancing test between total cost and effluent reduction benefits.” Id., at 33696; see §304(b)(1)(B). But as to “best available technology,” it states: “While cost should be a factor in the Administra tor’s judgment, no balancing test will be required.” Ibid.; see §304(b)(2)(B). And Senator Muskie’s discussion later speaks of the agency “evaluat[ing] . . . what needs to be done” to eliminate pollutant discharge and “what is 4 ENTERGY CORP. v. RIVERKEEPER, INC. Opinion of BREYER, J. achievable,” both “without regard to cost.” Ibid. As this language suggests, the Act’s sponsors had rea sons for minimizing the EPA’s investigation of, and reli ance upon, cost-benefit comparisons. The preparation of formal cost-benefit analyses can take too much time, thereby delaying regulation. And the sponsors feared that such analyses would emphasize easily quantifiable factors over more qualitative factors (particularly environmental factors, for example, the value of preserving non marketable species of fish). See S. Rep., at 47. Above all, they hoped that minimizing the use of cost-benefit com parisons would force the development of cheaper control technologies; and doing so, whatever the initial inefficien cies, would eventually mean cheaper, more effective cleanup. See id., at 50–51. Nonetheless, neither the sponsors’ language nor the underlying rationale requires the Act to be read in a way that would forbid cost-benefit comparisons. Any such total prohibition would be difficult to enforce, for every real choice requires a decisionmaker to weigh advantages against disadvantages, and disadvantages can be seen in terms of (often quantifiable) costs. Moreover, an absolute prohibition would bring about irrational results. As the respondents themselves say, it would make no sense to require plants to “spend billions to save one more fish or plankton.” Brief for Respondents Riverkeeper, Inc., et al. 29. That is so even if the industry might somehow afford those billions. And it is particularly so in an age of limited resources available to deal with grave environmental problems, where too much wasteful expenditure devoted to one problem may well mean considerably fewer resources available to deal effectively with other (perhaps more serious) problems. Thus Senator Muskie used nuanced language, which one can read as leaving to the Agency a degree of author ity to make cost-benefit comparisons in a manner that is Cite as: 556 U. S. ____ (2009) 5 Opinion of BREYER, J. sensitive both to the need for such comparisons and to the concerns that the law’s sponsors expressed. The relevant statement begins by listing various factors that the statute requires the Administrator to take into account when applying the phrase “practicable” to “classes and catego ries.” 118 Cong. Rec. 33696. It states that, when doing so, the Administrator must apply (as the statute specifies) a “balancing test between total cost and effluent reduction benefits.” Ibid. At the same time, it seeks to reduce the likelihood that the Administrator will place too much weight upon high costs by adding that the balancing test “is intended to limit the application of technology only where the additional degree of effluent reduction is wholly out of proportion to the costs of achieving” a “marginal level of reduction.” Ibid. Senator Muskie’s statement then considers the “differ ent test” that the statute requires the Administrator to apply when determining the “ ‘best available’ ” technology. Ibid. (emphasis added). Under that test, the Administra tor “may consider a broader range of technological alterna tives.” Ibid. And in determining what is “ ‘best available’ for a category or class, the Administrator is expected to apply the same principles involved in making the deter mination of ‘best practicable’ . . . except as to cost-benefit analysis.” Ibid. (emphasis added). That is, “[w]hile cost should be a factor . . . no balancing test will be required.” Ibid. (emphasis added). Rather, “[t]he Administrator will be bound by a test of reasonableness.” Ibid. (emphasis added). The statement adds that the “ ‘best available’ ” standard “is intended to reflect the need to press toward increasingly higher levels of control.” Ibid. (emphasis added). And “the reasonableness of what is ‘economically achievable’ should reflect an evaluation of what needs to be done to move toward the elimination of the discharge of pollutants and what is achievable through the application of available technology—without regard to cost.” Ibid. 6 ENTERGY CORP. v. RIVERKEEPER, INC. Opinion of BREYER, J. (emphasis added). I believe, as I said, that this language is deliberately nuanced. The statement says that where the statute uses the term “best practicable,” the statute requires compari sons of costs and benefits; but where the statute uses the term “best available,” such comparisons are not “required.” Ibid. (emphasis added). Senator Muskie does not say that all efforts to compare costs and benefits are forbidden. Moreover, the statement points out that where the statute uses the term “best available,” the Administrator “will be bound by a test of reasonableness.” Ibid. (empha sis added). It adds that the Administrator should apply this test in a way that reflects its ideal objective, moving as closely as is technologically possible to the elimination of pollution. It thereby says the Administrator should consider, i.e., take into account, how much pollution would still remain if the best available technology were to be applied everywhere—“without regard to cost.” Ibid. It does not say that the Administrator must set the standard based solely on the result of that determination. (It would be difficult to reconcile the alternative, more absolute reading of this language with the Senator’s earlier “test of reasonableness.”) I say that one may, not that one must, read Senator Muskie’s statement this way. But to read it differently would put the Agency in conflict with the test of reason ableness by threatening to impose massive costs far in excess of any benefit. For 30 years the EPA has read the statute and its history in this way. The EPA has thought that it would not be “reasonable to interpret Section 316(b) as requiring use of technology whose cost is wholly dispro portionate to the environmental benefit to be gained.” In re Pub. Serv. Co. of N. H. (Seabrook Station, Units 1 and 2), 1 E. A. D. 332, 340 (1977), remanded on other grounds, Seacoast Anti-Pollution League v. Costle,572 F. 2d 872
(CA1 1978) (emphasis added); see also In re Cite as: 556 U. S. ____ (2009) 7 Opinion of BREYER, J. Central Hudson Gas & Elec. Corp., EPA Decision of the General Counsel, NPDES Permits, No. 63, p. 371 (July 29, 1977) (also applying a “wholly disproportionate” test); In re Pub. Serv. Co. of N. H., 1 E. A. D. 455 (1978) (same). “[T]his Court will normally accord particular deference to an agency interpretation of ‘longstanding’ duration.” Barnhart v. Walton,535 U. S. 212
, 220 (2002). And for the last 30 years, the EPA has given the statute a permissive reading without suggesting that in doing so it was ignor ing or thwarting the intent of the Congress that wrote the statute. The EPA’s reading of the statute would seem to permit it to describe environmental benefits in non-monetized terms and to evaluate both costs and benefits in accor dance with its expert judgment and scientific knowledge. The Agency can thereby avoid lengthy formal cost-benefit proceedings and futile attempts at comprehensive moneti zation, see69 Fed. Reg. 41661
–41662; take account of Congress’ technology-forcing objectives; and still prevent results that are absurd or unreasonable in light of extreme disparities between costs and benefits. This approach, in my view, rests upon a “reasonable interpretation” of the statute—legislative history included. Hence it is lawful. Chevron U. S. A. Inc. v. Natural Resources Defense Coun cil, Inc.,467 U. S. 837
, 844 (1984). Most of what the ma jority says is consistent with this view, and to that extent I agree with its opinion. II The cases before us, however, present an additional problem. We here consider a rule that permits variances from national standards if a facility demonstrates that its costs would be “significantly greater than the benefits of complying.”40 CFR §125.94
(a)(5)(ii) (2008). The words “significantly greater” differ from the words the EPA has traditionally used to describe its standard, namely, 8 ENTERGY CORP. v. RIVERKEEPER, INC. Opinion of BREYER, J. “wholly disproportionate.” Perhaps the EPA does not mean to make much of that difference. But if it means the new words to set forth a new and different test, the EPA must adequately explain why it has changed its standard. Motor Vehicle Mfrs. Assn. of United States, Inc. v. State Farm Mut. Automobile Ins. Co.,463 U. S. 29
, 42–43 (1983); National Cable & Telecommunications Assn. v. Brand X Internet,545 U. S. 967
, 981 (2005); Thomas Jefferson Univ. v. Shalala,512 U. S. 504
, 524, n. 3 (1994) (THOMAS, J., dissenting). I am not convinced the EPA has successfully explained the basis for the change. It has referred to the fact that existing facilities have less flexibility than new facilities with respect to installing new technologies, and it has pointed to special, energy-related impacts of regulation.68 Fed. Reg. 13541
(2003) (proposed rule). But it has not explained why the traditional “wholly disproportionate” standard cannot do the job now, when the EPA has used that standard (for existing facilities and otherwise) with apparent success in the past. See, e.g., Central Hudson, supra. Consequently, like the majority, I would remand these cases to the Court of Appeals. But unlike the majority I would permit that court to remand the cases to the EPA so that the EPA can either apply its traditional “wholly disproportionate” standard or provide an adequately reasoned explanation for the change. Cite as: 556 U. S. ____ (2009) 1 STEVENS, J., dissenting SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES _________________ Nos. 07–588, 07–589 and 07–597 _________________ ENTERGY CORPORATION, PETITIONER 07–588 v. RIVERKEEPER, INC., ET AL. PSEG FOSSIL LLC, ET AL., PETITIONERS 07–589 v. RIVERKEEPER, INC., ET AL. UTILITY WATER ACT GROUP, PETITIONER 07–597 v. RIVERKEEPER, INC., ET AL. ON WRITS OF CERTIORARI TO THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE SECOND CIRCUIT [April 1, 2009] JUSTICE STEVENS, with whom JUSTICE SOUTER and JUSTICE GINSBURG join, dissenting. Section 316(b) of the Clean Water Act (CWA),33 U. S. C. §1326
(b), which governs industrial powerplant water intake structures, provides that the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA or Agency) “shall require” that such structures “reflect the best technology available for minimizing adverse environmental impact.” The EPA has interpreted that mandate to authorize the use of cost benefit analysis in promulgating regulations under §316(b). For instance, under the Agency’s interpretation, technology that would otherwise qualify as the best avail able need not be used if its costs are “significantly greater than the benefits” of compliance.40 CFR §125.94
(a)(5)(ii) (2008). 2 ENTERGY CORP. v. RIVERKEEPER, INC. STEVENS, J., dissenting Like the Court of Appeals, I am convinced that the EPA has misinterpreted the plain text of §316(b). Unless costs are so high that the best technology is not “available,” Congress has decided that they are outweighed by the benefits of minimizing adverse environmental impact. Section 316(b) neither expressly nor implicitly authorizes the EPA to use cost-benefit analysis when setting regula tory standards; fairly read, it prohibits such use. I As typically performed by the EPA, cost-benefit analysis requires the Agency to first monetize the costs and bene fits of a regulation, balance the results, and then choose the regulation with the greatest net benefits. The process is particularly controversial in the environmental context in which a regulation’s financial costs are often more obvious and easier to quantify than its environmental benefits. And cost-benefit analysis often, if not always, yields a result that does not maximize environmental protection. For instance, although the EPA estimated that water intake structures kill 3.4 billion fish and shellfish each year,1 see69 Fed. Reg. 41586
, the Agency struggled to calculate the value of the aquatic life that would be pro —————— 1 To produce energy, industrial powerplants withdraw billions of gallons of water daily from our Nation’s waterways. Thermo electric powerplants alone demand 39 percent of all freshwater with drawn nationwide. See Dept. of Energy, Addressing the Critical Link Between Fossil Energy and Water 2 (Oct. 2005), http:// www.netl.doe.gov/technologies/coalpower/ewr/pubs/NETL_Water_Paper _Final_Oct.2005.pdf (all Internet materials as visited Mar. 18, 2009, and available in Clerk of Court’s case file). The fish and shellfish are killed by “impingement” or “entrainment.” Impingement occurs when aquatic organisms are trapped against the screens and grills of water intake structures. Entrainment occurs when these organisms are drawn into the intake structures. See Riverkeeper, Inc. v. EPA,475 F. 3d 83
, 89 (CA2 2007);69 Fed. Reg. 41586
(2004). Cite as: 556 U. S. ____ (2009) 3 STEVENS, J., dissenting tected under its §316(b) regulations, id., at 41661. To compensate, the EPA took a shortcut: Instead of monetiz ing all aquatic life, the Agency counted only those species that are commercially or recreationally harvested, a tiny slice (1.8 percent to be precise) of all impacted fish and shellfish. This narrow focus in turn skewed the Agency’s calculation of benefits. When the EPA attempted to value all aquatic life, the benefits measured $735 million.2 But when the EPA decided to give zero value to the 98.2 per cent of fish not commercially or recreationally harvested, the benefits calculation dropped dramatically—to $83 million. Id., at 41666. The Agency acknowledged that its failure to monetize the other 98.2 percent of affected spe cies “ ‘could result in serious misallocation of resources,’ ” id., at 41660, because its “comparison of complete costs and incomplete benefits does not provide an accurate picture of net benefits to society.”3 Because benefits can be more accurately monetized in some industries than in others, Congress typically decides whether it is appropriate for an agency to use cost-benefit analysis in crafting regulations. Indeed, this Court has recognized that “[w]hen Congress has intended that an agency engage in cost-benefit analysis, it has clearly indi cated such intent on the face of the statute.” American Textile Mfrs. Institute, Inc. v. Donovan,452 U. S. 490
, 510 (1981). Accordingly, we should not treat a provision’s silence as an implicit source of cost-benefit authority, particularly when such authority is elsewhere expressly granted and it has the potential to fundamentally alter an —————— 2 EPA, Economic and Benefits Analysis for the Proposed Section 316(b) Phase II Existing Facilities Rule, p. D1–4 (EPA–821–R–02–001, Feb. 2002), http://www.epa.gov/waterscience/316b/phase2/econbenefits. 3 EPA, Economic and Benefits Analysis for the Final Section 316(b) Phase II Existing Facilities Rule, p. D1–5 (EPA–821–R–04–005, Feb. 2004), http://www.epa.gov/waterscience/316b/phase2/econbenefits/final. htm. 4 ENTERGY CORP. v. RIVERKEEPER, INC. STEVENS, J., dissenting agency’s approach to regulation. Congress, we have noted, “does not alter the fundamental details of a regulatory scheme in vague terms or ancillary provisions—it does not, one might say, hide elephants in mouseholes.” Whit man v. American Trucking Assns., Inc.,531 U. S. 457
, 467–468 (2001). When interpreting statutory silence in the past, we have sought guidance from a statute’s other provisions. Evi dence that Congress confronted an issue in some parts of a statute, while leaving it unaddressed in others, can dem onstrate that Congress meant its silence to be decisive. We concluded as much in American Trucking. In that case, the Court reviewed the EPA’s claim that §109 of the Clean Air Act (CAA),42 U. S. C. §7409
(a) (2000 ed.), au thorized the Agency to consider implementation costs in setting ambient air quality standards. We read §109, which was silent on the matter, to prohibit Agency reli ance on cost considerations. After examining other provi sions in which Congress had given the Agency authority to consider costs, the Court “refused to find implicit in am biguous sections of the CAA an authorization to consider costs that has elsewhere, and so often, been expressly granted.”531 U. S., at 467
. Studied silence, we thus concluded, can be as much a prohibition as an explicit “no.” Further motivating the Court in American Trucking was the fact that incorporating implementation costs into the Agency’s calculus risked countermanding Congress’ deci sion to protect public health. The cost of implementation, we said, “is both so indirectly related to public health and so full of potential for canceling the conclusions drawn from direct health effects that it would surely have been expressly mentioned in [the text] had Congress meant it to be considered.”Id., at 469
. American Trucking’s approach should have guided the Court’s reading of §316(b). Nowhere in the text of §316(b) Cite as: 556 U. S. ____ (2009) 5 STEVENS, J., dissenting does Congress explicitly authorize the use of cost-benefit analysis as it does elsewhere in the CWA. And the use of cost-benefit analysis, like the consideration of implemen tation costs in American Trucking, “pad[s]” §316(b)’s environmental mandate with tangential economic effi ciency concerns. Id., at 468. Yet the majority fails to follow American Trucking despite that case’s obvious relevance to our inquiry. II In 1972, Congress amended the CWA to strike a careful balance between the country’s energy demands and its desire to protect the environment. The Act required in dustry to adopt increasingly advanced technology capable of mitigating its detrimental environmental impact. Not all point sources were subject to strict rules at once. Ex isting plants were granted time to retrofit with the best technology while new plants were required to incorporate such technology as a matter of design. Although Congress realized that technology standards would necessarily put some firms out of business, see EPA v. National Crushed Stone Assn.,449 U. S. 64
, 79 (1980), the statute’s steady march was toward stricter rules and potentially higher costs. Section §316(b) was an integral part of the statutory scheme. The provision instructs that “[a]ny standard established pursuant to section 1311 of this title or section 1316 of this title and applicable to a point source shall require that the location, design, construction, and capac ity of cooling water intake structures reflect the best tech nology available for minimizing adverse environmental impact.”33 U. S. C. §1326
(b) (2006 ed.) (emphasis added).4 The “best technology available,” or “BTA,” stan —————— 4 The two cross-referenced provisions, §§1311 and 1316, also establish “best technology” standards, the first applicable to existing point sources and the second to new facilities. The reference to these provi 6 ENTERGY CORP. v. RIVERKEEPER, INC. STEVENS, J., dissenting dard delivers a clear command: To minimize the adverse environmental impact of water intake structures, the EPA must require industry to adopt the best technology available. Based largely on the observation that §316(b)’s text offers little guidance and therefore delegates some amount of gap-filling authority to the EPA, the Court concludes that the Agency has discretion to rely on cost-benefit analysis. See ante, at 11–12. The Court assumes that, by not specifying how the EPA is to determine BTA, Congress intended to give considerable discretion to the EPA to decide how to proceed. Silence, in the majority’s view, represents ambiguity and an invitation for the Agency to decide for itself which factors should govern its regulatory approach. The appropriate analysis requires full consideration of the CWA’s structure and legislative history to determine whether Congress contemplated cost-benefit analysis and, if so, under what circumstances it directed the EPA to utilize it. This approach reveals that Congress granted the EPA authority to use cost-benefit analysis in some contexts but not others, and that Congress intend to con trol, not delegate, when cost-benefit analysis should be used. See Chevron U. S. A. Inc. v. Natural Resources Defense Council, Inc.,467 U. S. 837
, 842–843 (1984).5 —————— sions in §316(b) merely requires any rule promulgated under those provisions, when applied to a point source with a water intake struc ture, to incorporate §316(b) standards. 5 The majority announces at the outset that the EPA’s reading of the BTA standard “governs if it is a reasonable interpretation of the stat ute—not necessarily the only possible interpretation, nor even the interpretation deemed most reasonable by the courts.” Ante, at 7. This observation is puzzling in light of the commonly understood practice that, as a first step, we ask “whether Congress has directly spoken to the precise question at issue.” Chevron,467 U. S., at 842
. Only later, if Congress’ intent is not clear, do we consider the reasonableness of the agency’s action.Id., at 843
. Assuming ambiguity and moving to the Cite as: 556 U. S. ____ (2009) 7 STEVENS, J., dissenting Powerful evidence of Congress’ decision not to authorize cost-benefit analysis in the BTA standard lies in the series of standards adopted to regulate the outflow, or effluent, from industrial powerplants. Passed at the same time as the BTA standard at issue here, the effluent limitation standards imposed increasingly strict technology require ments on industry. In each effluent limitation provision, Congress distinguished its willingness to allow the EPA to consider costs from its willingness to allow the Agency to conduct a cost-benefit analysis. And to the extent Con gress permitted cost-benefit analysis, its use was intended to be temporary and exceptional. The first tier of technology standards applied to existing plants—facilities for which retrofitting would be particu larly costly. Congress required these plants to adopt “effluent limitations . . . which shall require the applica tion of the best practicable control technology currently available.”33 U. S. C. §1311
(b)(1)(A). Because this “best practicable,” or “BPT,” standard was meant to ease indus try’s transition to the new technology-based regime, Con gress gave BPT two unique features: First, it would be temporary, remaining in effect only until July 1, 1983.6 Second, it specified that the EPA was to conduct a cost benefit analysis in setting BPT requirements by consider ing “the total cost of application of technology in relation to the effluent reduction benefits to be achieved from such application.”7 §1314(b)(1)(B). Permitting cost-benefit —————— second step reflects the Court’s reluctance to consider the possibility, which it later laments is “more complex,” ante, at 9, that Congress’ silence may have meant to foreclose cost-benefit analysis. 6 Congress later extended the deadline to March 31, 1989. 7 Senator Muskie, the Senate sponsor of the legislation, described the cost-benefit analysis permitted under BPT as decidedly narrow, assert ing that “[t]he balancing test between total cost and effluent reduction benefits is intended to limit the application of technology only where the additional degree of effluent reduction is wholly out of proportion to the costs of achieving such marginal level of reduction for any class or 8 ENTERGY CORP. v. RIVERKEEPER, INC. STEVENS, J., dissenting analysis in BPT gave the EPA the ability to cushion the new technology requirement. For a limited time, a tech nology with costs that exceeded its benefits would not be considered “best.” The second tier of technology standards required exist ing powerplants to adopt the “best available technology economically achievable” to advance “the national goal of eliminating the discharge of all pollutants.” §1311(b)(2)(A). In setting this “best available technology,” or “BAT,”8 standard, Congress gave the EPA a notably different command for deciding what technology would qualify as “best”: The EPA was to consider, among other factors, “the cost of achieving such effluent reduction,” but Congress did not grant it authority to balance costs with the benefits of stricter regulation. §1314(b)(2)(B). Indeed, in Crushed Stone this Court explained that the difference between BPT and BAT was the existence of cost-benefit authority in the first and the absence of that authority in the second. See449 U. S., at 71
(“Similar directions are given the Administrator for determining effluent reduc tions attainable from the BAT except that in assessing BAT total cost is no longer to be considered in comparison to effluent reduction benefits”). The BAT standard’s legislative history strongly supports the view that Congress purposefully withheld cost-benefit authority for this tier of regulation. See ibid., n. 10. The House of Representatives and the Senate split over the role cost-benefit analysis would play in the BAT provision. The House favored the tool, see H. R. Rep. No. 92–911, p. 107 (1972), 1 Leg. Hist. 794, while the Senate rejected it, —————— category of sources.” 1 Legislative History of the Water Pollution Control Act Amendments of 1972 (Committee Print compiled for the Senate Committee on Public Works by the Library of Congress), Ser. No. 93–1, p. 170 (1973) (hereinafter Leg. Hist.) 8 Although the majority calls this “BATEA,” the parties refer to the provision as “BAT,” and for simplicity, so will I. Cite as: 556 U. S. ____ (2009) 9 STEVENS, J., dissenting see 2 id., at 1183; id., at 1132. The Senate view ultimately prevailed in the final legislation, resulting in a BAT stan dard that was “not subject to any test of cost in relation to effluent reduction benefits or any form of cost/benefit analysis.” 3 Legislative History of the Clean Water Act of 1977: A Continuation of the Legislative History of the Federal Water Pollution Control Act (Committee Print compiled for the Senate Committee on Environment and Public Works by the Library of Congress), Ser. No. 95–14, p. 427 (1978). The third and strictest regulatory tier was reserved for new point sources—facilities that could incorporate tech nology improvements into their initial design. These new facilities were required to adopt “the best available dem onstrated control technology,” or “BADT,” which Congress described as “a standard . . . which reflect[s] the greatest degree of effluent reduction.” §1316(a)(1). In administer ing BADT, Congress directed the EPA to consider “the cost of achieving such effluent reduction.” §1316(b)(1)(B). But because BADT was meant to be the most stringent stan dard of all, Congress made no mention of cost-benefit analysis. Again, the silence was intentional. The House’s version of BADT originally contained an exemption for point sources for which “the economic, social, and envi ronmental costs bear no reasonable relationship to the economic, social, and environmental benefit to be ob tained.” 1 Leg. Hist. 798. That this exemption did not appear in the final legislation demonstrates that Congress considered, and rejected, reliance on cost-benefit analysis for BADT. It is in this light that the BTA standard regulating water intake structures must be viewed. The use of cost benefit analysis was a critical component of the CWA’s structure and a key concern in the legislative process. We should therefore conclude that Congress intended to forbid cost-benefit analysis in one provision of the Act in which it 10 ENTERGY CORP. v. RIVERKEEPER, INC. STEVENS, J., dissenting was silent on the matter when it expressly authorized its use in another.9 See, e.g., Allison Engine Co. v. United States ex rel. Sanders, 553 U. S. ___, ___ (2008) (slip op., at 7–8); Russello v. United States,464 U. S. 16
, 23 (1983) (“[W]here Congress includes particular language in one section of a statute but omits it in another . . . , it is gener ally presumed that Congress acts intentionally and pur posely in the disparate inclusion or exclusion” (internal quotation marks omitted)). This is particularly true given Congress’ decision that cost-benefit analysis would play a temporary and exceptional role in the CWA to help exist ing plants transition to the Act’s ambitious environmental standards.10 Allowing cost-benefit analysis in the BTA standard, a permanent mandate applicable to all power plants, serves no such purpose and instead fundamentally —————— 9 The Court argues that, if silence in §316(b) signals the prohibition of cost-benefit analysis, it must also foreclose the consideration of all other potentially relevant discretionary factors in setting BTA stan dards. Ante, at 12. This all-or-nothing reasoning rests on the deeply flawed assumption that Congress treated cost-benefit analysis as just one among many factors upon which the EPA could potentially rely to establish BTA. Yet, as explained above, the structure and legislative history of the CWA demonstrate that Congress viewed cost-benefit analysis with special skepticism and controlled its use accordingly. The Court’s assumption of equivalence is thus plainly incorrect. Properly read, Congress’ silence in §316(b) forbids reliance on the cost-benefit tool but does not foreclose reliance on all other considerations, such as a determination whether a technology is so costly that it is not “avail able” for industry to adopt. 10 In 1977, Congress established an additional technology-based stan dard, commonly referred to as “best conventional pollutant control technology,” or “BCT,” to govern conventional pollutants previously covered by the BAT standard. See33 U. S. C. §1311
(b)(2)(E). The BCT standard required the EPA to consider, among other factors, “the relationship between the costs of attaining a reduction in effluents and the effluent reduction benefits derived.” §1314(b)(4)(B). That Congress expressly authorized cost-benefit analysis in BCT further confirms that Congress treated cost-benefit analysis as exceptional and reserved for itself the authority to decide when it would be used in the Act. Cite as: 556 U. S. ____ (2009) 11 STEVENS, J., dissenting weakens the provision’s mandate.11 Accordingly, I would hold that the EPA is without au thority to perform cost-benefit analysis in setting BTA standards. To the extent the EPA relied on cost-benefit analysis in establishing its BTA regulations,12 that action was contrary to law, for Congress directly foreclosed such reliance in the statute itself.13 Chevron,467 U. S., at 843
. —————— 11 The Court attempts to cabin its holding by suggesting that a “rigor ous form of cost-benefit analysis,” such as the form “prescribed under the statute’s former BPT standard,” may not be permitted for setting BTA regulations. Ante, at 13. Thus the Court has effectively in structed the Agency that it can perform a cost-benefit analysis so long as it does not resemble the kind of cost-benefit analysis Congress elsewhere authorized in the CWA. The majority’s suggested limit on the Agency’s discretion can only be read as a concession that cost benefit analysis, as typically performed, may be inconsistent with the BTA mandate. 12 The “national performance standards” the EPA adopted were shaped by economic efficiency concerns at the expense of finding the technology that best minimizes adverse environmental impact. In its final rulemaking, the Agency declined to require industrial plants to adopt closed-cycle cooling technology, which by recirculating cooling water requires less water to be withdrawn and thus fewer aquatic organisms to be killed. Riverkeeper, Inc. v. EPA,358 F. 3d 174
, 182, n. 5 (CA2 2004);69 Fed. Reg. 41601
, and n. 44. This the Agency de cided despite its acknowledgment that “closed-cycle, recirculating cooling systems . . . can reduce mortality from impingement by up to 98 percent and entrainment by up to 98 percent.”Id., at 41601
. The EPA instead permitted individual plants to resort to a “suite” of options so long as the method used reduced impingement and entrainment by the more modest amount of 80 and 60 percent, respectively. See40 CFR §125.94
(b). The Agency also permitted individual plants to obtain a site-specific variance from the national performance standards if they could prove (1) that compliance costs would be “significantly greater than” those the Agency considered when establishing the standards, or (2) that compliance costs “would be significantly greater than the benefits of complying with the applicable performance standards,” §125.94(a)(5). 13 Thus, the Agency’s past reliance on a “wholly disproportionate” standard, a mild variant of cost-benefit analysis, is irrelevant. See ante, at 14. Because “Congress has directly spoken to the precise 12 ENTERGY CORP. v. RIVERKEEPER, INC. STEVENS, J., dissenting Because we granted certiorari to decide only whether the EPA has authority to conduct cost-benefit analysis, there is no need to define the universe of considerations upon which the EPA can properly rely in administering the BTA standard. I would leave it to the Agency to decide how to proceed in the first instance. III Because the Court unsettles the scheme Congress estab lished, I respectfully dissent. —————— question at issue,” Chevron,467 U. S., at 842
, longstanding yet imper missible agency practice cannot ripen into permissible agency practice.
riverkeeper-inc-natural-resources-defense-council-waterkeeper-alliance , 475 F.3d 83 ( 2007 )
American Textile Manufacturers Institute, Inc. v. Donovan , 101 S. Ct. 2478 ( 1981 )
riverkeeper-inc-natural-resources-defense-council-waterkeeper-alliance , 358 F.3d 174 ( 2004 )
Thomas Jefferson University v. Shalala , 114 S. Ct. 2381 ( 1994 )
Whitman v. American Trucking Assns., Inc. , 121 S. Ct. 903 ( 2001 )
Russello v. United States , 104 S. Ct. 296 ( 1983 )
seacoast-anti-pollution-league-v-douglas-m-costle-as-administrator-of , 597 F.2d 306 ( 1979 )
United States v. Detroit Timber & Lumber Co. , 26 S. Ct. 282 ( 1906 )
Motor Vehicle Mfrs. Assn. of United States, Inc. v. State ... , 103 S. Ct. 2856 ( 1983 )
appalachian-power-company-baltimore-gas-and-electric-company-carolina , 566 F.2d 451 ( 1977 )
Environmental Protection Agency v. National Crushed Stone ... , 101 S. Ct. 295 ( 1980 )
Barnhart v. Walton , 122 S. Ct. 1265 ( 2002 )
National Cable & Telecommunications Assn. v. Brand X ... , 125 S. Ct. 2688 ( 2005 )
Chevron U. S. A. Inc. v. Natural Resources Defense Council, ... , 104 S. Ct. 2778 ( 1984 )
seacoast-anti-pollution-league-v-douglas-m-costle-as-administrator-of , 572 F.2d 872 ( 1978 )
Alaska Department of Environmental Conservation v. ... , 124 S. Ct. 983 ( 2004 )
Spencer Neal Steinmetz v. Department of the Army ( 2015 )
Cal. Manufacturers & Tech. etc. v. State Water Resources ... ( 2021 )
Guam v. United States ( 2021 )
Burton v. Dept. of Environmental Protection ( 2021 )
American Meat Institute v. United States Department of ... , 746 F.3d 1065 ( 2014 )
White Stallion Energy Center, LLC v. Environmental ... , 748 F.3d 1222 ( 2014 )
Oregon Restaurant and Lodging v. Thomas Perez , 816 F.3d 1080 ( 2016 )
Airlines for America v. Transportation Security ... , 780 F.3d 409 ( 2015 )
Upper Missouri Waterkeeper v. Usepa ( 2021 )
Marlow v. The New Food Guy, Inc. , 861 F.3d 1157 ( 2017 )
Guedes v. Bureau of Alcohol, Tobacco, Firearms , 920 F.3d 1 ( 2019 )
Small MS4 Coalition v. Dept. of Environment , 479 Md. 1 ( 2022 )
Woodstream Corporation v. Jackson , 845 F. Supp. 2d 174 ( 2012 )
Council for Urological Interests v. Sebelius , 946 F. Supp. 2d 91 ( 2013 )
Aarp v. United States Equal Employment Opportunity ... , 267 F. Supp. 3d 14 ( 2017 )
Department of Transportation v. Association of American ... , 135 S. Ct. 1225 ( 2015 )
Affinity Healthcare Services, Inc. v. Sebelius , 746 F. Supp. 2d 106 ( 2010 )
State Procedures for Appointment of Competent Counsel in ... ( 2009 )
Matter of Sierra Club v. Martens , 2018 NY Slip Op 153 ( 2018 )