DocketNumber: No. 12354
Citation Numbers: 88 Wash. 568, 153 P. 367, 1915 Wash. LEXIS 1159
Judges: Chadwick, Fullerton, Holcomb
Filed Date: 12/15/1915
Status: Precedential
Modified Date: 10/19/2024
Respondent brought two actions to foreclose liens for driving and booming logs on the Wishkah river, which actions were consolidated in the court below.
Appellant is engaged in logging on a branch of the Wishkah river, and respondent, by means of splash dams, drives appellant’s logs down the river to tide water, where respondent maintains and operates a boom wherein it booms and
I. The trial court erroneously concluded that it was without jurisdiction to entertain the question of the reasonableness or unreasonableness of the rates, for the reason that such jurisdiction exists in the public service commission. It is suggested by counsel for both parties that the public service commission disclaims any jurisdiction over driving and booming companies, and also that,' under the public service commission act (Laws of 1911, ch. 117, p. 538; 3 Rem. & Bal. Code, § 8626-1 et seq.), no such authority is conferred. Counsel agree that, “while the public service commission act directly repeals statutes relative to railroads, telephone companies, irrigation companies, and the like, the repealing section makes no reference to the existing booming and driving statutes, and that, since repeals by implication are not fa
The public service commission is a body with purely and expressly delegated legislative and political powers. It has no inherent power or authority other than that necessarily incidental to its express and delegated powers. The act creating and controlling it nowhere mentions in terms boom companies or driving companies, or their operations or rates. We conclude, therefore, that the commission has no jurisdiction over them.
II. We now consider the correctness in result of the refusal of the court below to entertain jurisdiction to determine the reasonableness of the rates for driving and booming. The question involves consideration of several distinct statutes, viz., the boom statute of 1890 (Laws 1889-90, p. 470), the driving statute of 1895, and the amendments thereto of 1901 and 1909. Rem. & Bal. Code, § 7128.
The driving act of 1895 authorized the improvement of rivers and streams to render them navigable for floating logs and timber products. Laws of 1895, p. 129, § 4. In consideration of such improvements, the improvers were authorized to render services in driving and “to charge and collect reasonable and uniform tolls for such service.” The act, (Laws of 1895, p. 180, § 5), further provides that
“Such tolls shall not exceed sixty cents per thousand feet, board measure, on logs, spars or other large timber, and reasonable compensation on all other products, as may be determined by the directors of said corporation; the amount of such logs and other products to be determined by the usual method of scaling, and such corporation shall have a lien upon all logs and other timber products handled for sluicing, sacking and driving thereof, to be enforced in any manner now or hereafter provided by law for the enforcement of lien for labor on logs.”
This statute was amended in 1901 (Laws of 1901, p. 295, § 1), so as to authorize driving companies, to establish, charge and collect reasonable and uniform tolls, not to ex
There is no contention of any discrimination by respondent in fixing and charging its rates. The appellant maintains that the legislature not merely fixed maximum rates, but further provided that whatever tolls and rates such boom and driving companies did establish should not only be uniform and non-discriminating but reasonable, and that, therefore, the court had jurisdiction to inquire into the question of
Appellant cites Beale and Wyman, Railroad Rate Regulation, § 1813, to this effect:
“To whatever body the power of fixing rates may be confided, it is the function of the regular courts to pass upon the reasonableness of the rates thus established; and the courts cannot be deprived of this power. The question of reasonableness cannot be so conclusively determined by the legislature of the state, or by regulations adopted under its authority, that the matter may not become the subject of judicial inquiry.”
And cites Reagan v. Farmers Loan & Trust Co., 154 U. S. 362, and Chicago, M. & St. Paul R. Co. v. Minnesota, 134 U. S. 418, to the effect that the question of the reasonableness of a rate charged for transportation by a railroad company is eminently a question for judicial investigation, requiring due process of law for its determination. But in the Reagan case the court say:
“The courts are not authorized to revise or change the body of rates imposed by a legislature or a commission; they do not determine whether one rate is preferable to another, or what under all circumstances would be fair and reasonable as between the carriers and the shippers; they do not engage in any mere administrative work; . . .”
Respondent, to the contrary, insists that the legislation in question is based upon the principle that the establishment of a rate is the making of a rule for the future, and therefore is an act legislative, not judicial, in kind. Prentis v. Atlantic
“It is competent for the state to authorize such parties to charge compensation at rates or within limitations fixed by the legislature, for the use of such improvements and for such services. Here the boom company was limited by the legislature in fixing its charges for such compensation, to a sum not exceeding fifty cents per thousand feet. We are constrained to think such amount was within the legislative discretion.” . '
But the decision seems to be rested upon the facts shown in the case to sustain the charge of forty cents per thousand. The courts seem to hold with great unanimity that'the maximum rates fixed by the legislature are conclusive and binding unless constitutional rights are invaded, and that, unless such rights are invaded, courts have no right to substitute their judgment as to what should or should not be a reasonable rate under the maximum established by the legislature. .Pingree v. Michigan Cent. R. Co., 118 Mich. 314, 76 N. W. 635, 53 L. R. A. 274; Brooklyn Union Gas. Co. v. New York, Detroit v. Citizens’ St. R. Co., and Winsor Coal Co. v. Chicago & A. R. Co., supra; Fisher v. New York Cent. & H. R. R. Co., 46 N. Y. 644; People v. Budd, 117 N. Y. 1, 22 N. E. 670, 682, 15 Am. St. 460, 5 L. R. A. 559.
The cases herein referred to and others cited by respondent are, in nearly every instance, cases where the legislature established a maximum rate, or a level of maximum rates, which, upon judicial inquiry, were determined within the legislative power, and to have been constitutionally considered and established, and not unreasonable; and in some of them, that, under such maximum rates prescribed by legislation, any rate not in excess of the maximum would be deemed
But statutes fixing one plane or maximum level of rates are unlike the statutes in question. Here the law-making power granted the right to improve and use natural highways, streams belonging to the state and the public. In consideration of such improvement for beneficial use, it further granted to the improvers the right to charge and collect tolls for their services to other concerns requiring the benefit of their improvements and services in and upon the streams. It gave to the improvers the primary right to fix the tolls therefor, first requiring that such tolls should be reasonable and uniform, and, next, in abundance of caution and restraint, that such tolls should not exceed certain sums, to be determined by the directors of the corporations so improving such streams. If we say that any such rate fixed by the board of directors of the improving corporation within the maximum prescribed by the legislature is ipso facto reasonable, we ignore the primary requirement that the rates or tolls charged shall be reasonable, and we allow to the boards of directors of such corporations not only the administrative power delegated to them to fix the rates or tolls, but also an arbitrary power to determine the reasonableness thereof, which the respondent would deny to the courts, and from which there is no appeal, and no recourse.
We cannot give our assent to that view. If the tolls charged are to be reasonable, somewhere lies the power to determine the reasonableness thereof. That the legislature intended to confer this power upon the improvers, after having granted them monopolistic or exclusive use of the public streams when improved by them, and the exclusive right to exact tolls even in invitvm from the persons benefited thereby, and to impress liens upon and distrain the property thereunder, is most improbable. The monopoly of the business of the improver of a public stream is affected by a public interest. It is more peculiarly a public interest than that of most
“The question of reasonableness cannot be so conclusively determined by the legislature of the state, or by regulations adopted under its authority, that the matter may not become the subject of judicial inquiry.” Beale and Wyman, Railroad Rate Regulation, § 1313.
See, also, In re Janvrin, 174 Mass. 514, 55 N. E. 381, 47 L. R. A. 319; Chicago, M. & St. P. R. Co. v. Minnesota, Reagan v. Farmers' Loan & Trust Co., and St. Louis & S. F. R. Co. v. Gill, supra.
The legislature did not here adopt a fixed forward rule and inflexible standard of measurement of the reasonableness of the tolls exacted, so as to cut off inquiry into the fact of the reasonableness of tolls established and exacted by the boards of directors of such driving and boom companies. It doubtless considered the necessity of correcting and preventing abuses by prescription of maximum tolls beyond which the boom and driving companies could not lawfully charge in any case. And we assume that it found circumstances and conditions obviously precluding any definite and inflexible standard of such tolls which would fit all cases and be just and reasonable. To improve some rivers in this state for booming and driving logs would cost great sums, while to improve others for the same purpose would require comparatively small expenditure of money and labor. On some streams booming and driving is no doubt comparatively easy, while
We come now to the consideration of the question of uniformity in applying rates for driving and booming as presented by respondent. It is asserted that the conditions met in improving and in driving and booming upon different streams, “render it all the more necessary that such companies be given, as they are given under the statute, certain discretion with reference to the fixing of their tolls, in connection with different operating conditions as they arise. Otherwise a court or jury would fix in one case tolls that would in no way be binding or conclusive in another, interminable litigation would follow, confusion would result, and different courts and juries would be fixing different rates and tolls for the same service. Manifestly, a litigant in one case would not be concluded by the findings of a court and jury in another, and the resulting confusion which would follow is apparent.”
We are not oblivious to these difficulties. The trouble is we must interpret the statute as we find it. Its first require
We conclude, therefore, that the motions to strike appellant’s affirmative answers should be denied, issues joined thereon, the cases tried on the facts, and decrees be entered according to the facts in issue.
The decrees of the court below are therefore reversed, and the causes are remanded for further proceedings in accordance with this opinion, with costs of appeal to appellants.
Parker, Ellis, and Main, JJ., concur.